Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Social Indicators Research 1/2011

01.10.2011

Measuring Well-Being and Progress

verfasst von: Luca D’Acci

Erschienen in: Social Indicators Research | Ausgabe 1/2011

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Well-being is becoming a concept which is more and more involved in any world development consideration. A large amount of work is being carried out to study measurements of well-being, including a more holistic vision on the development and welfare of a country. This paper proposes an idea of well-being and progress being in equilibrium with each other. This is distant from the two extreme positions: poor but happy, and rich then happy; too romantic the first, and reductive the second. After a short explanation on the meaning of Objective and Subjective well-being, we show some interesting relations between economic and social variables, and we propose a new index to measure the well-being and progress of the countries: the Well-being & Progress Index (WIP). It includes several aspects of well-being and progress, like human rights, economic well-being, equality, education, research, quality of urban environment, ecological behaviours, subjective well-being, longevity, and violent crime. The most frequently used indexes usually only focus on some aspects, like ecology, or economy, or policy, or education, or happiness, and so forth. On the contrary, this new WIP index allows a global and well-balanced vision, thanks to the large range of indicators used, and how representative they are.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
Some economists had a more ethical orientation, such as Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill, Karl Marx, Francis Edgeworth; some others a more technical one, like William Petty, François Quesnay, David Ricardo, Augustin Cournot or Léon Walras.
 
2
Like the World Development Indicators and the World Development Report.
 
3
Joaquín Almunia, “Measuring progress, true wealth and well being”, Conference “beyond GDP”, Brussels, 19 November 2007.
 
4
José Manuel Durão Barroso, "Beyond GDP—Opening speech", Conference “beyond GDP”, Brussels, 19 November 2007.
 
5
In his first report to the US Congress in 1934: Simon Kuznets (1934), "National Income, 1929–1932". 73rd US Congress, 2d session, Senate document no. 124, p. 7.
 
6
Simon Kuznets (1962), "How To Judge Quality", The New Republic, October 20, 1962.
 
7
Kahneman (1994), Easterlin (2001) p. 465, Frey and Stutzer (2002), [it. tr. (2006), pp. 25–40].
 
8
Arrigo and Sordelli (2004). This separation is also close, although does not coincide, to the distinction between stimulation and comfort of Scitovsky in his well known The Joyless Economy (1976).
 
9
There is a vast quantity of literature and an important historic debate covering this subject, which is also very topical and relative to different concepts and evaluations of utility and well-being. We refer for example to Sen (1987) for a discussion about rationality, utility and well-being; Kahneman (1994, 2003) about the connections among utility, rationality and the surrounding situation; the research gathered in Frey and Stutzer (2002) show how happiness is dependent on the surrounding situation.
 
10
Independence from the reference (for example, how rich I am at this moment) is the base of the Theory of expected utility of Bernoulli, where the (rational) decider makes choices for the expected utility of future situations. However, in the model, the preferences of the decider remain identical, because the utility does not depend on the present situation. From this originated Bernoulli's model, the modern Theory of Decisions, that conserved the assumption of independence from the reference (so called by Tversky and Kahneman 1991) in all its future versions.
 
11
Kahneman (2006), Easterlin (2001), Easterling (1974), Frey and Stutzer (2002), Brickman (1978), Frank (1999). For further information about this idea read the first part of paragraph 4.
 
12
For the USA during the years 1946–1990 refer to Blanchflower and Oswald (2000), Lane (1998) p. 462; Myers (2000), p. 61; for Japan during the years 1958–1991 refer to Frey and Stutzer (2002) Fig. 1.3; for China during 1994–2005 refer to Kahneman (2006) Fig. 4.
 
13
Diener et al. (1995) shows a strong relation between richness and expressed happiness when comparing 55 countries; the same strong relation is showed by the research of Veenhoven (1991), of Inglearth (1990) and of Inkeles and Diamond (1986), comparing several countries. Many comparisons among different levels of people’s richness in the same country show an equally strong relation between richness and expressed happiness: Easterlin (2000) for the USA 1994; Diener et al. (1993) for USA 1981–84; data-base of Euro-Barometer Survey Series (1975–1991) for Europe (look at Di Tella et al. 1999.
 
15
Helson (1964), Brickman and Campbell (1971), Parducci (1995), Frederick and Loewenstein (1999). A different version of the adaptation theory is the idea of the “homeostatic process”: even after several modifications in our life condition, our happiness tends to go back to our original level of happiness. It is like our happiness derives more from our genetic predisposition than from events changing our life (Headey and Wearing 1992).
 
16
Irwin (1944), Michalos (1991), Inglearth (1990).
 
17
In Economy we can also find this theory, considering the changement of the preferences in the forming of habit (Marshall 1890; Duesenberry 1949; Modigliani 1949; Pollak 1970; Carroll and Weil 1994).
 
18
Diener et al. (1993), Fig. 2 for a comparison between income improvement and expressed happiness in the USA 1981–84; Frey and Stutzer (2002), Fig. 1.4, for a similar comparison in the USA 1995; and also Smith (1776) evidence showing how, beyond a certain level, an increase of income is not so useful.
 
19
Look also at the research carried out by the research group which has grown up by Bernard van Praag and Arie Kapteyn (1973): Kapteyn and Wansbeek (1982, 1985), van Praag and Frijters (1999). They show that the shift of preference toward the high (the more I have got the more I want), “deletes” around 60–80% of the real well-being coming from increased richness.
 
20
Frey and Stutzer (2002), Frey et al. (2002), Hanh (1984). The literature suggests calling procedural utility the well-being given by the process of reaching the goal (what I should do to achieve my goal of buying a bike), and calling the instrumental utility that one received when we reach the intended goal (buying a new bike). Then the psychological well-being concerns both the final state (how happy it makes me feel to own my new bike) and the procedure; the material well-being concerns only the final state.
 
21
Easterling (1974), Easterlin (1995), Veblen (1899), Becker (1974), Frank (1985), Pollak (1976), Duesenberry (1949), Russel (1930) p. 68–69, Kosicki (1987), Hirsch (1976).
 
22
We introduce this “or” just to remind the reader that money does not always mean happiness, even if we also show how strong their connection normally is. As we will illustrate later, the position of this paper does not want to be extreme, thus, we are distant from both the romantic idea of “poor but happy” and from the limited idea of “rich then happy”.
 
23
Even though the literature often uses the terms “happiness”, “well-being”, “life satisfaction” interchangeably, in this paper we prefer to use the term “well-being” in the context of global welfare (both objective and subjective well-being), reserving the use of the word “happiness” to emphasize only the psychological contribution in our well-being.
 
24
Especially the economists who followed the authority of Robbins (1932).
 
25
Allen and Hicks (1934) showed how the demand theory works, just using an ordinal scale; a few years later, Samuelson (1938) wrote the general behavioural base for the standard theory, in which is valid the axiom: utility means preference; while Houthakker (1950) and Uzawa (1960) provided the actual shape of the expressed preference theory.
 
26
The economic analysis is more connected to the preferences and wishes than to the hedonic experience.
 
27
We remind the reader (with Sen 1987 too), that sometimes people can have a goal that does not involve directly a traditional well-being (like more money or more material goods or more power), but that makes them feel happier.
 
28
Just as an example we remind the reader the success of the column “Anomalies”, present from 1987 in the prestigious Journal of Economic Perspectives, where are showed punctual examples of falsification of the consumer theory.
 
29
Look at for example Sen (1987), Kahneman (1994), Simon (1982).
 
30
But remember that this does not mean necessarily that it is possible to capture subjective wellbeing through a survey. In practice it is rather difficult for several reasons, such us difficulties of recollection by respondents on how happy they were at a certain time in the past, difficulties of comparing people, cultures etc.
 
31
“…direct subjective consequences from engaging in some activities to the exclusion of others… For instance, how much an individual likes or dislikes the activity ‘panting one’s house’, in conjunction with the amount of time one spends in painting the house, is as important a determinant of well-being independent of how satisfied one feels about having a freshly painted house” (Juster et al. 1985).
 
32
The respondents rate each episode of the previous day by replying to the question “how did you feel during this episode?”. In replying to this question he gives a score from 0 to 6 on some possible feelings (happy, frustrated/bored, depressed/sad, annoyed/frightened, tender/cordial, irritated/vexed, worried/anxious, amused, tired), where 0 indicates that the relative feeling was not felt at all, and 6 indicates that the respondents experienced that feeling very much. The Net Affect is the mean of the scores of the positive feelings minus the mean of the scores of the negative feelings.
 
33
Except the case of China, (for China during the period 1994–2005 look at Kahneman 2006, Fig. 4) and of others countries (Internet appendix to Inglehart, Foa and Welzel, “Social Change, Freedom and Rising Happiness,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology), that show a little decrease of expressed happiness.
 
34
It would be interesting to study these relations by means of multiple regression (or similar), to quantify the effect of each of these variables previously measured by a comparative scale, for example.
 
35
For instance in the USA, compared with others countries, the average longevity is not as high as the average richness, maybe also because of its not so healthy alimentary habit, or because of any other reasons too. However, its longevity is much higher than other poorer countries (even if in these countries the other variables, like climate, pollution, etc., are better).
 
36
Methodology proposed in D’Acci (2009a, b, 2008, 2007).
 
37
For a deep contribution to the Ethic and Economy debate look at Sen (1987).
 
38
Refer to Frey and Stutzer (2002), Paragraph 4, p. 108.
 
39
The HDI combines normalized measures of life expectancy, literacy, educational attainment, and GDP per capita. Life expectancy at birth, as an index of population health and longevity; knowledge and education, as measured by the adult literacy rate (with two-thirds weighting) and the combined primary, secondary, and tertiary gross enrollment ratio (with one-third weighting). Standard of living, as measured by the natural logarithm (to reduce the impact beyond a certain level) of gross domestic product per capita at purchasing power parity (GDPppp). Each of these 3 factors has the same weight.
 
40
The GPI indicator takes into account everything the GDP uses, but adding the cost of the negative effects related to economic activity (such as the cost of crime, cost of ozone depletion and cost of resource depletion, among others). Proposed in 1994 by Cliff Cobb.
 
41
ISEW = personal consumption + public non-defensive expenditures + capital formation + services from domestic labour–costs of environmental degradation–depreciation of natural capital–private defensive expenditures. The index is based on the ideas presented by William Nordhaus and James Tobin in their Measure of Economic Welfare (1972). It was first coined in 1989 by Herman Daly and John B. Cobb. They later went on to add several other "costs" to the definition of ISEW. In this later work they built the Genuine Progress Indicator.
 
42
It includes Psychological wellbeing indicators, Ecology indicators, Health indicators, Education indicators, Culture indicators, Living Standards indicators, Time Use indicators, Community Vitality indicators and Good Governance indicators. It was coined in 1972 by Bhutan's former King Jigme Singye Wangchuck.
 
43
The nine quality-of-life factors utilized and the indicators used to represent these factors are: Material wellbeing (GDP per person, at PPP in $), Health (Life expectancy at birth (in years), Political stability and security, Family life (Divorce rate per 1,000 of population), converted into an index with a value of 1 (for the lowest divorce rates) to 5 (the highest), Community life (a dummy variable taking value 1, if the country has either a high rate of church attendance or of trade-union membership, zero otherwise), Climate and geography (Latitude), Job security (Unemployment rate), Political freedom (The average indices of political and civil liberties. On a scale of 1 (completely free) to 7 (not free at all), Gender equality (Ratio of average male and female earnings). Developed by The Economist Intelligence Unit (http://​www.​eiu.​com) in 2005.
 
44
The mathematical expression for the Life-Quality Index, L, is: L = E K G where E is the expectancy of healthy life at birth, G is the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) per person, and the parameter K is a constant based on time budget studies which are available for many countries (K is approximately equal to 5.0 for developed nations). Defined by Nathwani in 1997.
 
45
It is a coefficient which measures the equality of income distribution, where value 0 represents absolute equality, and value 100 indicates absolute inequality.
 
46
“The rating process is based on a checklist of 10 politically correct questions and 15 civil liberty questions. The politically correct questions are grouped into three subcategories: Electoral Process (3 questions), Political Pluralism and Participation (4), and the Functioning of Government (3). The civil liberty questions are grouped into four subcategories: Freedom of Expression and Belief (4 questions), Associational and Organizational Rights (3), Rule of Law (4), and Personal Autonomy and Individual Rights (4)”. (from www.​freedomhouse.​org).
 
47
Life expectancy at birth, GDP per capita, Gini index, Unemploymenttotal, Education Index, Researchers in research and development, Women’s equality and Intentional homicides are calculated on the data set of the Human Development Report 2007/2008 and of the UNESCO Institute for Statistics 2007; Freedom is calculated on a data set and survey of Freedomhouse; Subjective Well-being comes from Marks, N., Abdallah, S., Simms, A, Thompson, S. (2006)Marks et al. 2006, The Happy Planet Index, New Economics Foundation, London.
 
48
In this figure Luxembourg does not appear.
 
49
This is a good question, but we like to point out that both, GDP and WIP*, may also improve independently or because they are driven by some other unobserved factor.
 
50
Although various aspects of people's lives have improved over history, they do not seem to have improved overall. It depends on the point of view, for example if we consider the risks to us and future generations from factors such as climate change and environmental degradation which may be irreversible. From an optimistic viewpoint we could think of these factors as part of the Negative Transitory Cycles, unless they become irreversible damages.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Allen, R. G. D., & Hicks, J. R. (1934). A reconsideration of the theory of value, I. Economica, 1, 52–75. Allen, R. G. D., & Hicks, J. R. (1934). A reconsideration of the theory of value, I. Economica, 1, 52–75.
Zurück zum Zitat Arrigo, U., & Sordelli, M. (2004). Alcuni aspetti problematici nel dibattito su “Happiness and Economics”. In XVI conference of “Società Italiana di Economica Pubblica”, Pavia. Arrigo, U., & Sordelli, M. (2004). Alcuni aspetti problematici nel dibattito su “Happiness and Economics”. In XVI conference of “Società Italiana di Economica Pubblica”, Pavia.
Zurück zum Zitat Becker, G. S. (1974). A theory of social interactions. Journal of Political Economy, 82(6), 1063–1093.CrossRef Becker, G. S. (1974). A theory of social interactions. Journal of Political Economy, 82(6), 1063–1093.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bentham, J. (1789). An introduction to the principles of morals and legislation. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1960. Bentham, J. (1789). An introduction to the principles of morals and legislation. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1960.
Zurück zum Zitat Blanchflower, D. G., & Oswald, A. J. (2000). Well-being over time in Britain and the USA. NBER working paper n. 7487, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Blanchflower, D. G., & Oswald, A. J. (2000). Well-being over time in Britain and the USA. NBER working paper n. 7487, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Zurück zum Zitat Brickman, P., & Cambell, D. T. (1971). Hedonic relativism and planning the good society. In M. H. Appely (Ed.), Adaptation level theory: A symposium. New York: Academic Press. Brickman, P., & Cambell, D. T. (1971). Hedonic relativism and planning the good society. In M. H. Appely (Ed.), Adaptation level theory: A symposium. New York: Academic Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Carrol, C. D., & Weil, D. N. (1994). Saving and growth: A reinterpretation. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series ono Public Policy, 40(0), 133–192.CrossRef Carrol, C. D., & Weil, D. N. (1994). Saving and growth: A reinterpretation. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series ono Public Policy, 40(0), 133–192.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat D’Acci, L. (2008). Grown, urban transformation, real estate value: Econometric cellular automata for the simulation of positional value. In Lecture Notes in Computer Science, LNCS 5072. Berlin: Springer. D’Acci, L. (2008). Grown, urban transformation, real estate value: Econometric cellular automata for the simulation of positional value. In Lecture Notes in Computer Science, LNCS 5072. Berlin: Springer.
Zurück zum Zitat D’Acci, L. (2009a). Spatial distribution of social benefit given by urban attractions: A test of UrAD model. In Lecture notes in computer science LNCS 5592 (pp. 237–252). Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer. D’Acci, L. (2009a). Spatial distribution of social benefit given by urban attractions: A test of UrAD model. In Lecture notes in computer science LNCS 5592 (pp. 237–252). Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer.
Zurück zum Zitat D’Acci, L. (2009b). A mathematical aid for efficient distribution of social benefit in urban planning. In F. Scarlatti & G. Rabino (Eds.), Advances in models and methods for planning. Bologna: Pitagora. D’Acci, L. (2009b). A mathematical aid for efficient distribution of social benefit in urban planning. In F. Scarlatti & G. Rabino (Eds.), Advances in models and methods for planning. Bologna: Pitagora.
Zurück zum Zitat D’Acci, L., & Zorzi, F. (2007). Un modello per la simulazione dei valori immobiliari. In E. Mollica (Ed.), Sistemi economici locali e mercati immobiliari. Gangemi. D’Acci, L., & Zorzi, F. (2007). Un modello per la simulazione dei valori immobiliari. In E. Mollica (Ed.), Sistemi economici locali e mercati immobiliari. Gangemi.
Zurück zum Zitat D’Acci, L., & Lombardi, P. (2010). MuSIC—a new multi-scalar index for evaluating sustainability in cities, Amman (Jordan). The second international conference on sustainable architecture and urban development, 12–14/7/2010. D’Acci, L., & Lombardi, P. (2010). MuSIC—a new multi-scalar index for evaluating sustainability in cities, Amman (Jordan). The second international conference on sustainable architecture and urban development, 12–14/7/2010.
Zurück zum Zitat Di Tella, R., MacCulloch, R. J., & Oswald, A. J. (1999). How do macroeconomic fluctuations affect happiness?. Mimeo, Boston: Harward Business School. Di Tella, R., MacCulloch, R. J., & Oswald, A. J. (1999). How do macroeconomic fluctuations affect happiness?. Mimeo, Boston: Harward Business School.
Zurück zum Zitat Diener, E., Diener, M., & Diener, C. (1995). Factors predicting the subjective well-being of nations. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 69(5), 851–864.CrossRef Diener, E., Diener, M., & Diener, C. (1995). Factors predicting the subjective well-being of nations. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 69(5), 851–864.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Diener, E., & Pavot, W. (1993). The affective and cognitive context of self-reported measures of subjective well-being. Social Indicators Research, 28(1), 1–20.CrossRef Diener, E., & Pavot, W. (1993). The affective and cognitive context of self-reported measures of subjective well-being. Social Indicators Research, 28(1), 1–20.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Diener, E., Sandvik, E., Seidlitz, L., & Diener, M. (1993). The Relationship between income and subjective well-being: Relative or absolute? Social Indicators Research, 28(3), 195–223.CrossRef Diener, E., Sandvik, E., Seidlitz, L., & Diener, M. (1993). The Relationship between income and subjective well-being: Relative or absolute? Social Indicators Research, 28(3), 195–223.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Duesenberry, J. (1949). Income, saving and the theory of consumer behavior. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Duesenberry, J. (1949). Income, saving and the theory of consumer behavior. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Easterlin, R. (1995). Will raising the incomes of all increase the happiness of all? Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 27(1), 35–48.CrossRef Easterlin, R. (1995). Will raising the incomes of all increase the happiness of all? Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 27(1), 35–48.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Easterlin, R. (2000). Income and happiness: Towards a unified theory. Mimeo: Oxford University. Easterlin, R. (2000). Income and happiness: Towards a unified theory. Mimeo: Oxford University.
Zurück zum Zitat Easterlin, R. (2001). Income and happiness: Towards a unified theory. Economic Journal, 111, 465–484. Easterlin, R. (2001). Income and happiness: Towards a unified theory. Economic Journal, 111, 465–484.
Zurück zum Zitat Easterling, R. (1974). Does economic growth improve the human lot? Some empirical evidence. In P. A. David & M. W. Reder (Eds.), Nations and households in economic growth: Essay in Honor of Moses Abroamowitz (pp. 89–125). New York: Academic Press. Easterling, R. (1974). Does economic growth improve the human lot? Some empirical evidence. In P. A. David & M. W. Reder (Eds.), Nations and households in economic growth: Essay in Honor of Moses Abroamowitz (pp. 89–125). New York: Academic Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Edgeworth, F. Y. (1967). Mathematical psychics: An essay on the application of mathematics to the moral sciences. In K. Paul (Ed.), London. (Reprinted by M. Kelly, Ed.,1881, New York). Edgeworth, F. Y. (1967). Mathematical psychics: An essay on the application of mathematics to the moral sciences. In K. Paul (Ed.), London. (Reprinted by M. Kelly, Ed.,1881, New York).
Zurück zum Zitat Frank, R. (1985). The demand for unobservable and other non-positional goods. American Economic Review, 75(1), 101–116. Frank, R. (1985). The demand for unobservable and other non-positional goods. American Economic Review, 75(1), 101–116.
Zurück zum Zitat Frank, R. (1999). Luxury fever. New York: Free Press. Frank, R. (1999). Luxury fever. New York: Free Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Frederick, S., & Loewenstein, G. (1999). Hedonic adaptation. In D. Kahneman, E. Diener, & N. Scwarz (Eds.), Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology (pp. 302–329). New York: Russel Sage Foudantions. Frederick, S., & Loewenstein, G. (1999). Hedonic adaptation. In D. Kahneman, E. Diener, & N. Scwarz (Eds.), Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology (pp. 302–329). New York: Russel Sage Foudantions.
Zurück zum Zitat Frey, B. S., Benz, M., & Stutzer, A. (2002). Introduction to procedural utility: Not only what, but also how matters. Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich, working papers series, n. 129, forthcoming in Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics. Frey, B. S., Benz, M., & Stutzer, A. (2002). Introduction to procedural utility: Not only what, but also how matters. Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich, working papers series, n. 129, forthcoming in Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics.
Zurück zum Zitat Frey, B. S., & Luechinger, S. (2007). Concepts of happiness and their measurement (pp. 219–237). Marburg: Metropolis Verlag. Frey, B. S., & Luechinger, S. (2007). Concepts of happiness and their measurement (pp. 219–237). Marburg: Metropolis Verlag.
Zurück zum Zitat Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2002). Happiness and economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press. [it. tr. (2006), Economia e felicità, Il Sole24ore, Milano]. Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2002). Happiness and economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press. [it. tr. (2006), Economia e felicità, Il Sole24ore, Milano].
Zurück zum Zitat Hanh, F. (1984). “Su alcune difficoltà dell’economista utilitarista”, it. tr. In A. Sen & B. Williams (Eds.), Utilitarismo e oltre. Milano: Il Saggiatore. Hanh, F. (1984). “Su alcune difficoltà dell’economista utilitarista”, it. tr. In A. Sen & B. Williams (Eds.), Utilitarismo e oltre. Milano: Il Saggiatore.
Zurück zum Zitat Headey, B., & Wearing, A. (1992). Understanding happiness. Melbourne, Australia: Longman Cheshire. Headey, B., & Wearing, A. (1992). Understanding happiness. Melbourne, Australia: Longman Cheshire.
Zurück zum Zitat Helson, H. (1964). Adaptation-level theory: An experimental and systematic approach to behaviour. New York: Harper & Row. Helson, H. (1964). Adaptation-level theory: An experimental and systematic approach to behaviour. New York: Harper & Row.
Zurück zum Zitat Houthakker, H. S. (1950). Revaled preference and the utility function. Economica, 17, 275–282. Houthakker, H. S. (1950). Revaled preference and the utility function. Economica, 17, 275–282.
Zurück zum Zitat Inglearth, R. F. (1990). Culture shift in advanced industrial society. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Inglearth, R. F. (1990). Culture shift in advanced industrial society. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Inglehart, R., Foa, R., Peterson, P., & Welzel, C. (2008). Development, freedom, and rising happiness. Perspectives on Psychological Science, 3(4), 264–285.CrossRef Inglehart, R., Foa, R., Peterson, P., & Welzel, C. (2008). Development, freedom, and rising happiness. Perspectives on Psychological Science, 3(4), 264–285.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Inkeles, A., & Diamond, L. (1986). Personal development and national development: A cross-cutlural perspective. In A. Szalai & F. M. Andrews (Eds.), The quality of life: Comparative studies (pp. 73–109). Ann Arbor, MI: Institute for Social Research, University of Michigan. Inkeles, A., & Diamond, L. (1986). Personal development and national development: A cross-cutlural perspective. In A. Szalai & F. M. Andrews (Eds.), The quality of life: Comparative studies (pp. 73–109). Ann Arbor, MI: Institute for Social Research, University of Michigan.
Zurück zum Zitat Irwin, F. W. (1944). The realism of expectations. Psychological Review, 51, 120–126.CrossRef Irwin, F. W. (1944). The realism of expectations. Psychological Review, 51, 120–126.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Juster, F. T., Courant, P. N., & Dow, G. K. (1985). A conceptual framework for the analysis of time allocation data. In F. T. Juster & F. P. Stafford (Eds.), Time, goods, and well-being (pp. 113–131). Ann Arbor, MI: Institute for Social Research, University of Michigan. Juster, F. T., Courant, P. N., & Dow, G. K. (1985). A conceptual framework for the analysis of time allocation data. In F. T. Juster & F. P. Stafford (Eds.), Time, goods, and well-being (pp. 113–131). Ann Arbor, MI: Institute for Social Research, University of Michigan.
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D. (1994). New challenges to the rationality assumption. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 150(1), 18–36. Kahneman, D. (1994). New challenges to the rationality assumption. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 150(1), 18–36.
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D. (2003). A psychological perspective on economics. The American Economic Review, 93(2), 162–168.CrossRef Kahneman, D. (2003). A psychological perspective on economics. The American Economic Review, 93(2), 162–168.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D. (2004). Toward national well-being accounts. The American Economic Review, 94(2), 429–434.CrossRef Kahneman, D. (2004). Toward national well-being accounts. The American Economic Review, 94(2), 429–434.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D. (2006). Developments in the measurement of subjective well-being. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20, 3–24.CrossRef Kahneman, D. (2006). Developments in the measurement of subjective well-being. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20, 3–24.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D., Krueger, A. B., Schkade, D. A., Scharw, N., & Stone, A. (2004). A survey method for characterizing daily life experience: The day reconstruction method (DRM). Science, 306(5702), 1776–1780.CrossRef Kahneman, D., Krueger, A. B., Schkade, D. A., Scharw, N., & Stone, A. (2004). A survey method for characterizing daily life experience: The day reconstruction method (DRM). Science, 306(5702), 1776–1780.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D., & Snell, J. (1990). Predicting utility. In R. M. Hogarth (Ed.), Insights in decision making. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Kahneman, D., & Snell, J. (1990). Predicting utility. In R. M. Hogarth (Ed.), Insights in decision making. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Kapteyn, A., & Wansbeek, T. (1982). Empirical evidence on preference formation. Journal of Economic Psychology, 2, 137–154. Kapteyn, A., & Wansbeek, T. (1982). Empirical evidence on preference formation. Journal of Economic Psychology, 2, 137–154.
Zurück zum Zitat Kapteyn, A., & Wansbeek, T. (1985). The individual welfare function a review. Journal of Economic Psychology, 2(2), 137–154.CrossRef Kapteyn, A., & Wansbeek, T. (1985). The individual welfare function a review. Journal of Economic Psychology, 2(2), 137–154.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kuznets, S. (1934). National income, 1929–1932. In 73rd US congress, 2nd session, Senate document no. 124, p. 7. Kuznets, S. (1934). National income, 1929–1932. In 73rd US congress, 2nd session, Senate document no. 124, p. 7.
Zurück zum Zitat Kuznets, S. (1962). How to judge quality. The New Republic, October 20. Kuznets, S. (1962). How to judge quality. The New Republic, October 20.
Zurück zum Zitat Lane, R. E. (1998). The joyless market economy. In A. Ben-Ner & L. Putterman (Eds.), Economics, values, and organization (pp. 461–488). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Lane, R. E. (1998). The joyless market economy. In A. Ben-Ner & L. Putterman (Eds.), Economics, values, and organization (pp. 461–488). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Leu, R. E., Burri, S., & Priester, T. (1997). Lebensqualitat und Armut in der Schweiz. Bern: Haupt. Leu, R. E., Burri, S., & Priester, T. (1997). Lebensqualitat und Armut in der Schweiz. Bern: Haupt.
Zurück zum Zitat Marks, N., Abdallah, S., Simms, A., & Thompson, S. (2006). The happy planet index. London: New Economics Foundation. Marks, N., Abdallah, S., Simms, A., & Thompson, S. (2006). The happy planet index. London: New Economics Foundation.
Zurück zum Zitat Marshall, A. (1890). Principles of economics, 8th ed. (1920). London: Macmillan. Marshall, A. (1890). Principles of economics, 8th ed. (1920). London: Macmillan.
Zurück zum Zitat Modigliani, F. (1949). Fluctuations in the saving-income ratio: A problem in economic forecasting. In Conference on research in income and wealth, New York. Modigliani, F. (1949). Fluctuations in the saving-income ratio: A problem in economic forecasting. In Conference on research in income and wealth, New York.
Zurück zum Zitat Myers, D. G. (2000). The funds, friends, and faith of happy people. American Psychologist, 55(1), 56–67.CrossRef Myers, D. G. (2000). The funds, friends, and faith of happy people. American Psychologist, 55(1), 56–67.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Parducci, A. (1995). Happiness, pleasure, and judgment: The contextual theory and its applications. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum. Parducci, A. (1995). Happiness, pleasure, and judgment: The contextual theory and its applications. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Zurück zum Zitat Pollak, R. A. (1970). Habit formation and dynamic demand functions. Journal of Political Economy, 78(4), 745–763.CrossRef Pollak, R. A. (1970). Habit formation and dynamic demand functions. Journal of Political Economy, 78(4), 745–763.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pollak, R. A. (1976). Interdependent preferences. American Economic Review, 66(3), 309–320. Pollak, R. A. (1976). Interdependent preferences. American Economic Review, 66(3), 309–320.
Zurück zum Zitat Robbins, L. (1932). An essay on the nature and significance of economic science, Macmillan, London. In D.M. Hausman (Ed.) (1984) The philosophy of economics: An anthology. New York: Cambridge University Press. Robbins, L. (1932). An essay on the nature and significance of economic science, Macmillan, London. In D.M. Hausman (Ed.) (1984) The philosophy of economics: An anthology. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Samuelson, P. A. (1938). A note of the pure theory of consumer’s behaviour. Economica, 5(17), 61–71.CrossRef Samuelson, P. A. (1938). A note of the pure theory of consumer’s behaviour. Economica, 5(17), 61–71.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Scitovsky, T. (1976). The joyless economy. New York: Oxford University Press. Scitovsky, T. (1976). The joyless economy. New York: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Sen, A. (1987). On ethics and economics. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. [it. tr. (2006), Etica ed economia, Laterza, Bari]. Sen, A. (1987). On ethics and economics. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. [it. tr. (2006), Etica ed economia, Laterza, Bari].
Zurück zum Zitat Simon, H. (1982). Model of bounded rationality. Cambridge: MIT Press. [it. tr. (2001), Scienza economica e comportamento umano, Edizioni di Comunità, Torino]. Simon, H. (1982). Model of bounded rationality. Cambridge: MIT Press. [it. tr. (2001), Scienza economica e comportamento umano, Edizioni di Comunità, Torino].
Zurück zum Zitat Smith, A. (1776). An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. (Reprinted 1980, Deut and Sane, London, [it. tr. (1977), Indagine sulla natura e le cause della ricchezza delle nazioni, Oscar Mondadori, Milano]). Smith, A. (1776). An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. (Reprinted 1980, Deut and Sane, London, [it. tr. (1977), Indagine sulla natura e le cause della ricchezza delle nazioni, Oscar Mondadori, Milano]).
Zurück zum Zitat Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1991). Loss aversion in risksless choice: A reference-dependent model. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(4), 1039–1061.CrossRef Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1991). Loss aversion in risksless choice: A reference-dependent model. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(4), 1039–1061.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Uzawa, H. (1960). Preference and rational choice in the theory of consumption. In J. K. Arrow, K. Simon, & P. Suppes (Eds.), Mathematical methods in the social sciences. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Uzawa, H. (1960). Preference and rational choice in the theory of consumption. In J. K. Arrow, K. Simon, & P. Suppes (Eds.), Mathematical methods in the social sciences. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Van Praag, B. M. S., & Frijters, P. (1999). The measurement of welfare and well-being: The Leyden approach. In D. Kahneman, E. Diener, & N. Schwarz (Eds.), Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology (pp. 413–433). New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Van Praag, B. M. S., & Frijters, P. (1999). The measurement of welfare and well-being: The Leyden approach. In D. Kahneman, E. Diener, & N. Schwarz (Eds.), Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology (pp. 413–433). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Zurück zum Zitat Van Praag, B. M. S., & Kapteyn, A. (1973). Further evidence on the individuai welfare function of income: An empirical investigation in the Netherlands. European Economie Review, 4(1), 33–62.CrossRef Van Praag, B. M. S., & Kapteyn, A. (1973). Further evidence on the individuai welfare function of income: An empirical investigation in the Netherlands. European Economie Review, 4(1), 33–62.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Veblen, T. (1899). The theory of leisure class. New York: Modern Library. Veblen, T. (1899). The theory of leisure class. New York: Modern Library.
Zurück zum Zitat Veenhoven, R. (1991). Is happiness relative? Social Indicators Research, 24(1), 1–34.CrossRef Veenhoven, R. (1991). Is happiness relative? Social Indicators Research, 24(1), 1–34.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Measuring Well-Being and Progress
verfasst von
Luca D’Acci
Publikationsdatum
01.10.2011
Verlag
Springer Netherlands
Erschienen in
Social Indicators Research / Ausgabe 1/2011
Print ISSN: 0303-8300
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-0921
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-010-9717-1

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1/2011

Social Indicators Research 1/2011 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner