Skip to main content
Erschienen in: The Review of International Organizations 2/2013

01.06.2013

Organization without delegation: Informal intergovernmental organizations (IIGOs) and the spectrum of intergovernmental arrangements

verfasst von: Felicity Vabulas, Duncan Snidal

Erschienen in: The Review of International Organizations | Ausgabe 2/2013

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

The renaissance in the theoretical analysis of intergovernmental organizations (IGOs) has focused on formal IGOs (FIGOs), but many IGOs are subject to no formal treaty and/or have no permanent secretariat. Important examples of informal IGOs (IIGOs) include the G-groups that are the locus of much high-level interaction among states. We develop the spectrum of intergovernmental arrangements to show the wide variation in the formalization of international institutions and theorize when states will choose informal arrangements such as an IIGO over (or in combination with) a FIGO. A paired case comparison illustrates our claims that states use IIGOs when they need flexibility, to protect their sovereignty, to maintain close control of information, to lower short term transaction costs for speed, to minimize bureaucracy and to manage uncertainty during times of crisis. Finally, we examine how institutional choice is influenced by power.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
We use the terminology intergovernmental organization (IGO) and international organization (IO) interchangeably throughout the paper.
 
2
For a conceptual discussion of FIGOs see Volgy et al. (2008). Below we use the more inclusive definition of FIGOs offered by Pevehouse et al. (2004). Volgy et al. point out the important implications of different conceptualizations – for example, on the growth rate of FIGOs and on their impact in diminishing conflict. Finally, their definition of FIGOs increases the analytic difference with Informal IGOs developed below.
 
3
“The International Nuclear Fuel Cycle Evaluation” by R. Skjoldebrand. Accessed at http://​www.​iaea.​org/​Publications/​Magazines/​Bulletin/​Bull222/​22204883033.​pdf
 
4
We thank Joseph Nye for pointing us towards this example. Note that the need for the INFCE was in part precipitated by the fact that the existing IIGO in the area – the Nuclear Suppliers Group -- had a too limited membership. See also Lellouch (1979).
 
5
Helmke and Levitsky (2004) highlight the dearth of comparative institutional research on informal institutions, which they define as “socially shared rules, usually unwritten, that are created, communicated, and enforced outside of officially sanctioned channels.” Informal institutions range from bureaucratic and legislative norms to more elaborate practices such as clientelism and patrimonialism. Informal organizations, however, are distinguished by a focus on the players (including clans and mafias in the comparative context).
 
6
The criteria for an IGO in the Yearbook of International Organizations dataset is more inclusive than the COW, but the self-submitted questionnaires should be used with caution because they lack the independent fact-checking of the COW.
 
7
The COW dataset does not include emanations—an increasingly important set of IGOs whose creators are IGOs, not states (Shanks et al. 1996). The United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) and the United Nations Environment Program (UNEP) are two important examples. Emanations are theoretically different from IIGOs although some emanations could be IIGOs.
 
8
The COW dataset excludes bilateral organizations but they offer no clear theoretical justification for doing so. We include bilateral arrangements in our set of feasible IIGOs.
 
9
A useful analogy is the comparison of public and private goods. While no good is perfectly private or perfectly public, many goods can be categorized as closer to one or the other and analyzed accordingly. Sometimes, it is also possible to use the different models to examine different aspects of the “same” good – education and defence spending are important examples (Snidal 1979).
 
10
http://​www.​bis.​org/​bcbs/​. The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision’s most important function remains its role as a forum for members and managing meetings among them.
 
11
IIGOs are less legalized and closer to soft law in terms of the relative imprecision of their institutional arrangements and also because they entail less delegation but they may engender fairly high levels of obligation among members. See Abbott et al. 2000 for a discussion of the dimensions of legalization.
 
12
Of course, there are informal international organizations (i.e., IOs not IGOs) whose membership is not dominated by states but by NGOs or firms. For example, the Informal Forum of International Student Organisations (IFISO) consists of a multi-disciplinary mix of 27 international student-run organizations with no by-laws, obligations, fees, official spokespersons or officers. (http://​ifiso.​org/​). We also do not include transgovernmental relations (Keohane and Nye 1974) or transgovernmental networks (Slaughter 2004) insofar as those emphasize sub-national connections, whereas IIGOs focus on interstate interactions.
 
13
Conference series between states (e.g., the Conference of African Ministers Responsible for Human Development) do not qualify as IIGOs. While a large purpose of these conferences is to allow a broader set of interlocutors—such as civil society organizations—to partake in discussions of global concern, attendees are not members of an organization but rather are invited guests to a discussion. Conferences might later become IIGOs as they gain organizational structure.
 
14
Meetings may not always reach a decision, but that is a prime purpose. For example, consider a monetary conference where the goal is to ask whether some macroeconomic policy needs to be adopted or changed: the group members may decide not to change anything.
 
16
All FIGO secretariats have a limited form of independence to, for example, make small budgetary decisions or call meetings, but some FIGO secretariats have significant independence as autonomous, permanent bodies.
 
17
Hawkins et al. (2006) offer a detailed analysis of delegation to IGOs.
 
18
See “The Anatomy of Informal Governance” workshop, Nuffield College, Oxford 14–15 September, 2007. http://​www.​esrcsocietytoday​.​ac.​uk/​ESRCInfoCentre/​minisite/​prantl/​page1.​html. Accessed July 1, 2011.
 
19
Alter and Meunier (2006) identify overlapping regimes when “multiple institutions have authority over an issue.” See also Kelley (2009).
 
20
Raustiala and Victor (2004) and Keohane and Victor (2011) define regime complexes as the existence of partially overlapping and nonhierarchical regimes.
 
21
This kind of organizational competition for resources and influence seems less likely to result from the overlap of FIGOs and IIGOs given that turf wars cannot arise where bureaucracies (in IIGOs) are kept to a minimum.
 
22
Custom is often taken as a basis for international law, and international lawyers often imbue it with a stronger normative sense of obligation as being “law.” Here we mean it in a pre-legal sense (as argued by Goldsmith and Posner 2005). Through codification and interpretation by courts such as the ICJ, custom may evolve into a more formalized institutional arrangement that would be located further down the table.
 
23
For example, Boehmer et al. (2004) emphasize the varying degrees to which FIGOs are “institutionalized.” Haftel and Thompson (2006) argue that RTAs vary according to their level of “independence.” Both points are indicative of the continuum of intergovernmental arrangements.
 
24
Discussions about the definition of a FIGO have focused on permanent, independent Secretariats, and this has usually been interpreted as something that is present or not. But formal institutionalization of an IGO’s Secretariat is a matter of degree. Even within the set of FIGOs, permanent, independent Secretariats vary considerably. Consider some of the less institutionalized FIGOs: the North Atlantic Fisheries Organization (NAFO) permanent Secretariat has nine full time workers while the International Commission for the Conservation of Atlantic Tuna employs 27 full time workers. This lies in sharp contrast to the highly institutionalized United Nations system, which employs thousands of full-time workers around the world. http://​www.​nafo.​int/​about/​frames/​about.​html and http://​www.​iccat.​es/​en/​introduction.​htm, both accessed on 8/1/2011.
 
26
See Hudec (1998) for a discussion of the evolution of dispute settlement in GATT/WTO and Jupille et.al. (2013) for an account of the evolution of the GATT into the WTO.
 
27
A special case of an IIGO is when states get together for regular meetings leading up to the establishment of a formal legal agreement or a FIGO (where the group of negotiating states/organization is not yet based on an international treaty). If, when the formal agreement/ FIGO is created, the negotiating group disbands, then we would consider the IIGO “dead” in the dataset. Additionally, we would document a follow-on FIGO organization.
 
28
We thank Jon Pevehouse and his research team for sharing their comparison of Correlates of War and the Union of International Associations’ Yearbook of International Organizations with us. Organizations whose members are IGOs and public-private organizations are listed in the Yearbook but not in COW. We excluded them because our IIGO definition requires that members are states.
 
29
The “soft” end date of the Concert of Europe is a case in point. The death date of the Concert of Europe is contentious in the historical literature, and different dates indicate different conceptions of it. Schroeder (1994) dates it at 1823, which is when he says the normative consensus behind the Congress of Vienna expired. A.J.P. Taylor (1954) favored 1848. Most observers would agree that the Concert lasted through the 1878 Congress of Berlin but its role was increasingly undercut as the European great powers organized themselves into the Triple Alliance (1882) and Triple Entente (1907). Nevertheless, partly to avoid defining IIGOs by their effectiveness, and especially since the Concert did serve as the vehicle for the 1912–13 London Conference on the Balkan Wars, we date its demise to the July crisis. (Note that the Triple Alliance and Triple Entente are themselves not IIGOs but agreements, involving neither regular meetings nor organizational structure.)
 
30
Slaughter (2004), for example, lists a wide range of international organizations in her analysis of transgovernmental networks—including the International Organization of Securities Commissioners (IOSCO), The International Association of Insurance Supervisors (IAIS), the International Network for Environmental Compliance and Enforcement (INECE), the Financial Crimes Enforcement Network (FINCEN), and the Egmont Group. Ultimately, we filtered out many of these because they did not meet one of our criteria (states as members).
 
31
Lipson focuses on informal international agreements (promises that fall short of treaty ratification) and asks why states would choose to rely on these unspoken understandings, oral bargains, and adhere to treaties even after they have expired. Informal international agreements are based on explicitly shared expectations like IIGOs, but they are not accompanied by regular meetings or an organizational structure. See also Aust (1986).
 
33
Barnett and Finnemore (1999) highlight that FIGOs can exercise autonomous power after their creation in ways that state founders did not intend and they can gain an insular culture that prides their own technical expertise and standard operating procedures over connections with the external world. States may try to reduce these costs of formal organization by working through IIGOs.
 
36
We thank an anonymous reviewer for emphasizing this point.
 
37
An excellent example of an IIGO acting as a potential building block is the use of the 2011 G8 meeting to build an interstate consensus on worldwide cyber security. At the time, there was no other focal institution for addressing this important new issue.
 
38
There is also little analysis of the interplay between informal and formal security IGOs whereas nascent work has probed the interrelations between IIGOs and FIGOs in trade and finance (Baker 2000; Alexandroff 2010).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Abbott, K., & Snidal, D. (2000). Hard and soft Law in international governance. International Organization, 54(3), 421–456.CrossRef Abbott, K., & Snidal, D. (2000). Hard and soft Law in international governance. International Organization, 54(3), 421–456.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Abbott, K., Keohane, R., Moravcsik, A., Slaughter, A.-M., & Snidal, D. (2000). The concept of legalization. International Organization, 54(3), 401–419.CrossRef Abbott, K., Keohane, R., Moravcsik, A., Slaughter, A.-M., & Snidal, D. (2000). The concept of legalization. International Organization, 54(3), 401–419.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Abbott, K., & Snidal, D. (1998). Why states Act through formal international organizations. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 42(1), 3–32.CrossRef Abbott, K., & Snidal, D. (1998). Why states Act through formal international organizations. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 42(1), 3–32.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alexandroff, A. S. (2010). Challenges in global governance: Opportunities for G-x leadership. The Stanley Foundation: Policy Analysis Brief. Alexandroff, A. S. (2010). Challenges in global governance: Opportunities for G-x leadership. The Stanley Foundation: Policy Analysis Brief.
Zurück zum Zitat Alter, K. J., & Meunier, S. (2006). Nested and overlapping regimes in the transatlantic banana trade dispute. Journal of European Public Policy, 13(3), 362–382.CrossRef Alter, K. J., & Meunier, S. (2006). Nested and overlapping regimes in the transatlantic banana trade dispute. Journal of European Public Policy, 13(3), 362–382.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Aust, A. (1986). The theory and practice of informal international instruments. The International and Comparative Law Quarterly, 35, 787–812.CrossRef Aust, A. (1986). The theory and practice of informal international instruments. The International and Comparative Law Quarterly, 35, 787–812.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Baker, A. (2000). The G-7 as a global “ginger group”: plurilateralism and four-dimensional diplomacy. Global Governance, 6(2), 165–189. Baker, A. (2000). The G-7 as a global “ginger group”: plurilateralism and four-dimensional diplomacy. Global Governance, 6(2), 165–189.
Zurück zum Zitat Barnett, M., & Finnemore, M. (1999). The politics, power, and pathologies of international organizations. International Organization, 53, 699–732.CrossRef Barnett, M., & Finnemore, M. (1999). The politics, power, and pathologies of international organizations. International Organization, 53, 699–732.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Boehmer, C., Gartzke, E., & Nordstrom, T. (2004). Do intergovernmental organizations promote peace? World Politics, 57(1), 1–38.CrossRef Boehmer, C., Gartzke, E., & Nordstrom, T. (2004). Do intergovernmental organizations promote peace? World Politics, 57(1), 1–38.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Collier, D., LaPorte, J., & Seawright, J. (2012). Putting typologies to work: concept formation, measurement, and analytic rigor. Political Research Quarterly, 65(1), 217–232. Collier, D., LaPorte, J., & Seawright, J. (2012). Putting typologies to work: concept formation, measurement, and analytic rigor. Political Research Quarterly, 65(1), 217–232.
Zurück zum Zitat Gill, S. (1999). Structural changes in multilateralism: The G7 nexus and the global crisis. In M. Schechter (Ed.), Innovation in multilateralism. New York: St. Martin's Press. Gill, S. (1999). Structural changes in multilateralism: The G7 nexus and the global crisis. In M. Schechter (Ed.), Innovation in multilateralism. New York: St. Martin's Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Grieco, J. M. (1988). Anarchy and the limits of cooperation: a realist critique of the newest liberal institutionalism. International organization, 42(03), 485–507. Grieco, J. M. (1988). Anarchy and the limits of cooperation: a realist critique of the newest liberal institutionalism. International organization, 42(03), 485–507.
Zurück zum Zitat Gruber, L. (2000). Ruling the world: Power politics and the rise of supranational institutions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Gruber, L. (2000). Ruling the world: Power politics and the rise of supranational institutions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Goldsmith, J., & Posner, E. A. (2005). The limits of international Law. Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press. Goldsmith, J., & Posner, E. A. (2005). The limits of international Law. Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Haftel, Y. (2012). Regional economic institutions and conflict mitigation: Design, implementation, and the promise of peace. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Haftel, Y. (2012). Regional economic institutions and conflict mitigation: Design, implementation, and the promise of peace. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Haftel, Y., & Thompson, A. (2006). The independence of international organizations: Concept and applications. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50, 253.CrossRef Haftel, Y., & Thompson, A. (2006). The independence of international organizations: Concept and applications. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50, 253.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Haas, R. (2010). The Case for Messy Multilateralism. Financial Times, January 5 2010. Haas, R. (2010). The Case for Messy Multilateralism. Financial Times, January 5 2010.
Zurück zum Zitat Hawkins, D., Lake, D., Nielson, D., & Tierney, M. (2006). Delegation and agency in international organizations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Hawkins, D., Lake, D., Nielson, D., & Tierney, M. (2006). Delegation and agency in international organizations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Helmke, G., & Levitsky, S. (2004). Informal institutions and comparative politics: A research agenda. Perspectives on Politics, 2(4), 725–740.CrossRef Helmke, G., & Levitsky, S. (2004). Informal institutions and comparative politics: A research agenda. Perspectives on Politics, 2(4), 725–740.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hudec, Robert E. 1998. The Role of the GATT Secretariat in the Evolution of the WTO Dispute Settlement Procedure. in Jagdish Bhagwati and Mathias Hirsch, eds. The Uruguay Round and Beyond: Essays in Honour of Arthur Dunkel, Springer-Verlag, 101–120. Hudec, Robert E. 1998. The Role of the GATT Secretariat in the Evolution of the WTO Dispute Settlement Procedure. in Jagdish Bhagwati and Mathias Hirsch, eds. The Uruguay Round and Beyond: Essays in Honour of Arthur Dunkel, Springer-Verlag, 101–120.
Zurück zum Zitat Ikenberry, G. J. (2000). After victory: institutions, strategic restraint, and the rebuilding of order after major wars. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Ikenberry, G. J. (2000). After victory: institutions, strategic restraint, and the rebuilding of order after major wars. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Jupille, J., Mattli, W., & Snidal, D. (2013). Institutional choice in global commerce. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Jupille, J., Mattli, W., & Snidal, D. (2013). Institutional choice in global commerce. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Kelley, J. (2009). The more the merrier: The effects of having multiple international election monitoring organizations. Perspectives on Politics, 7(1), 59–64.CrossRef Kelley, J. (2009). The more the merrier: The effects of having multiple international election monitoring organizations. Perspectives on Politics, 7(1), 59–64.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Keohane, R. O., & Victor, D. G. (2011). The regime complex for climate change. Perspectives on Politics, 9, 7–23.CrossRef Keohane, R. O., & Victor, D. G. (2011). The regime complex for climate change. Perspectives on Politics, 9, 7–23.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Keohane, R. O., & Nye, J. S. (1974). Transgovernmental relations and international organizations. World Politics, 27(1), 39–62.CrossRef Keohane, R. O., & Nye, J. S. (1974). Transgovernmental relations and international organizations. World Politics, 27(1), 39–62.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kirton, J. J. (1999). Explaining G8 effectiveness. In M. Hodges, J. J. Kirton, & J. P. Daniels (Eds.), The G8’s role in the New millennium (pp. 45–68). Aldershot: Ashgate. Kirton, J. J. (1999). Explaining G8 effectiveness. In M. Hodges, J. J. Kirton, & J. P. Daniels (Eds.), The G8’s role in the New millennium (pp. 45–68). Aldershot: Ashgate.
Zurück zum Zitat Koremenos, B., Lipson, C., & Snidal, D. (2001). The rational design of international institutions. International Organization, 56, 761–800.CrossRef Koremenos, B., Lipson, C., & Snidal, D. (2001). The rational design of international institutions. International Organization, 56, 761–800.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Krasner, S. (1982). Structural causes and regime consequences: Regimes as intervening variables. International Organization, 36(2), 185–205.CrossRef Krasner, S. (1982). Structural causes and regime consequences: Regimes as intervening variables. International Organization, 36(2), 185–205.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Krasner, S. D. (1991). Global communications and national power. World politics, 43(3), 336–366. Krasner, S. D. (1991). Global communications and national power. World politics, 43(3), 336–366.
Zurück zum Zitat Lellouch, P. (1979). International Nuclear Politics. Foreign Affairs, 58(2), 336–350. Lellouch, P. (1979). International Nuclear Politics. Foreign Affairs, 58(2), 336–350.
Zurück zum Zitat Lipson, C. (1991). Why Are some international agreements informal? International Organization, 45, 495–538.CrossRef Lipson, C. (1991). Why Are some international agreements informal? International Organization, 45, 495–538.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pevehouse, J., Nordstrom, T., & Warnke, K. (2004). The correlates of War 2: International governmental organizations data version 2.0. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 21(2), 101–119.CrossRef Pevehouse, J., Nordstrom, T., & Warnke, K. (2004). The correlates of War 2: International governmental organizations data version 2.0. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 21(2), 101–119.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Prantl, J. (2005). The UN security council and informal groups of states: Complementing or competing for governance? International Organization, 59(3), 559–592.CrossRef Prantl, J. (2005). The UN security council and informal groups of states: Complementing or competing for governance? International Organization, 59(3), 559–592.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Raustiala, K., & Victor, D. G. (2004). The regime complex for plant genetic resources. International Organization, 58, 277–309.CrossRef Raustiala, K., & Victor, D. G. (2004). The regime complex for plant genetic resources. International Organization, 58, 277–309.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rochester, J. M. (1986). The rise and fall of international organization as a field of study. International Organization, 40(4). Rochester, J. M. (1986). The rise and fall of international organization as a field of study. International Organization, 40(4).
Zurück zum Zitat Shanks, C., Jacobson, H., & Kaplan, J. (1996). Inertia and change in the constellation of international governmental organizations, 1981–1992. International Organization, 50, 593–627.CrossRef Shanks, C., Jacobson, H., & Kaplan, J. (1996). Inertia and change in the constellation of international governmental organizations, 1981–1992. International Organization, 50, 593–627.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Slaughter, A.-M. (2004). A New world order. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Slaughter, A.-M. (2004). A New world order. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Snidal, D. (1979). Public goods, property rights, and political organizations. International Studies Quarterly, 23(4):532–566. Snidal, D. (1979). Public goods, property rights, and political organizations. International Studies Quarterly, 23(4):532–566.
Zurück zum Zitat Stone, R. W. (2011). Controlling institutions: International organizations and the global economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Stone, R. W. (2011). Controlling institutions: International organizations and the global economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stone, R. W. 2013. Informal governance in international organizations: Introduction to the Special Issue. Review of International Organizations. Stone, R. W. 2013. Informal governance in international organizations: Introduction to the Special Issue. Review of International Organizations.
Zurück zum Zitat Volgy, T. J., Fausett, E., Grant, K. A., & Rodgers, S. (2008). Identifying formal intergovernmental organizations. Journal of Peace Research, 45(6), 849–862.CrossRef Volgy, T. J., Fausett, E., Grant, K. A., & Rodgers, S. (2008). Identifying formal intergovernmental organizations. Journal of Peace Research, 45(6), 849–862.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wood, B. (1988). Critical choices. In J. Holmes & J. Kirton (Eds.), Canada and the New internationalism (pp. 134–137). Toronto: Canadian Institute of International Affairs. Wood, B. (1988). Critical choices. In J. Holmes & J. Kirton (Eds.), Canada and the New internationalism (pp. 134–137). Toronto: Canadian Institute of International Affairs.
Metadaten
Titel
Organization without delegation: Informal intergovernmental organizations (IIGOs) and the spectrum of intergovernmental arrangements
verfasst von
Felicity Vabulas
Duncan Snidal
Publikationsdatum
01.06.2013
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
The Review of International Organizations / Ausgabe 2/2013
Print ISSN: 1559-7431
Elektronische ISSN: 1559-744X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-012-9161-x

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 2/2013

The Review of International Organizations 2/2013 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner