Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Studies in Comparative International Development 1/2012

Open Access 01.03.2012

Industrial Wage Inequality in Latin America in Global Perspective, 1900–2000

verfasst von: Ewout Frankema

Erschienen in: Studies in Comparative International Development | Ausgabe 1/2012

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Standard economic theories of wage inequality focus on the factor-biased nature of technological change and globalization. This paper examines the long-run development of industrial wage inequality in Latin America from a global comparative perspective. We find that wage inequality was comparatively modest during the first half of the twentieth century, but rising much faster during the post-war era than in other industrial countries. In-depth analyses of wage inequality trends in Argentina, Brazil, and Chile confirm this pattern, but also reveal notable country peculiarities. In Argentina and Chile, trend breaks coincided with large political–institutional shocks while in Brazil, wage inequality increased unabated under the wage regulation policies of successive post-war administrations. We argue that without taking national policies with respect to education and the labor market into account, economic theory cannot explain “Latin American” patterns of wage inequality.

Introduction

Despite its longstanding historical legacy of high income and wealth inequality, the gap between rich and poor has further widened in the majority of Latin American countries (LACs henceforth) during the final quarter of the twentieth century. This development corresponded with a rise in the aggregate poverty head count ratio in the region as a whole (Psacharopoulos et al. 1997; Londoño and Székely 2000; Morley 2001; Székely and Montes 2006). Some scholars argue that the roots of current Latin American inequality can be traced far back into the colonial era, and persisted until today through institutions protecting political and economic privileges and suppressing processes of democratization and civil emancipation.
This idea is corroborated by comparative empirical research showing that the development of public education and participatory political systems was notably slower than in North America (Engerman and Sokoloff 1997; 2005; Mariscal and Sokoloff 2000). Factor market imperfections constrained the accumulation of physical and human capital, reducing long-term economic growth and intergenerational social mobility (Galor and Zeira 1993; De Soto 2000; Mookerjee and Ray 2000; Kay 2001). The authoritative World Bank report Inequality in Latin America. Breaking with History? voices the “persistent inequality” view by stating that in its modern form “high inequality is rooted in exclusionary institutions that have been perpetuated ever since colonial times and that have survived different political and economic regimes, from interventionist and import substitution strategies to more market-oriented policies” (De Ferranti et al. 2004: p. 1).
Some economic historians propagate a different perspective, however. Rather than emphasizing the resilient nature of Latin American inequality, they argue that the underlying structure of the income distribution has changed fundamentally in the past two centuries. Stressing the pervasiveness of Latin American inequality neglects the region’s distributive dynamics. The literature documenting long-term changes in the structure of the income distribution has been growing rapidly in recent years (Williamson 1999, 2002; Bértola 2005; Prados de la Escosura 2005; Bértola and Williamson 2006; Bértola et al. 2008; Coatsworth 2008; Arroyo Abad and Santos-Paulino 2009; Frankema 2009a).
This study aims to contribute to the latter strand of literature by reconstructing long-term series of industrial wage inequality in twentieth century Latin America in a global comparative perspective. The decomposition of income inequality in underlying components offers deeper insight in the secular development of income inequality. Aggregate inequality indicators (such as an income Gini) do not reveal much about the changing determinants of inequality, when the latter affect this indicator in opposite directions. The analysis of partial inequality indicators helps to isolate the effects of changing economic circumstances or political–institutional reforms.
Whereas long-run wage inequality series are extensively documented for many of the highly developed industrialized economies (for a survey, see Helpman 2004: Chapter 6, pp. 94–105), they have not been systematically explored for LACs yet. This has left important questions unanswered. Do we find “general patterns” in Latin American wage inequality? Have wage differentials always been larger in LACs than in other parts of the New World? And to which extent has wage inequality contributed to Latin American “surplus inequality”?
This study addresses these questions by analyzing three types of wage inequality: inter-industry wage inequality, intra-industry wage inequality (i.e., skill premiums), and gender wage gaps. We use a range of inequality measures but rely primarily on the Theil index to investigate changes in the long-run wage inequality trend. The USA, Canada, and Australia are used as New World benchmark countries (NWCs henceforth) to investigate contrasts and similarities. Our results can be summarized in three arguments.
First, wage inequality in the majority of LACs was comparatively modest during the first half of the twentieth century but increased rapidly during the post-war era, especially since the mid-1970s. Wage inequality thus appears to be a comparatively novel aspect of Latin American inequality, which has traditionally been dominated by the vast income gaps between minorities of wealthy proprietors and the poverty-stricken masses of mostly unskilled laborers and subsistence farmers (Williamson 1999).
Second, the post-war rise of wage inequality was a shared Latin American phenomenon. It occurred in all 15 LACs for which we were able to construct time series. An in-depth analysis of wage inequality trends in Argentina, Brazil, and Chile reveals notable country peculiarities, however. In Argentina and Chile, wage inequality trend breaks occurred in response to major political–institutional shocks, while in Brazil the post-war rise of wage inequality was gradual and concurred with a strong rise of inter-industry labor productivity differentials. The difference resides in the different nature of labor market policies conducted by successive post-war Brazilian governments.
Third, the explanatory value of standard economic theories of wage inequality, which focus on factor-biased technological change and globalization, has its limitations. While the long-term evolution of wage inequality in LACs may be attributed to the effects of increasing international market integration and skill-biased technological change, economic theory remains silent on the timing and extent of the dramatic breaks in the wage inequality trend observed in Argentina and Chile. We need to look at differences in national labor market policies and educational institutions to understand the impact of global economic developments on national distributional outcomes in Latin America.
The remainder of this study is organized as follows. The “Theories and Hypotheses of Latin American Wage Inequality” section discusses theories of wage inequality. The “Latin American Wage Inequality in Comparative Perspective, 1900–1950” and “The Post-war Rise of Latin American Wage Inequality, 1950–2000” sections present and discusses the empirical results. “Explaining Long-Term Wage Inequality Trends in Latin America” section offers some tentative explanations for the observed long run patterns by looking in greater detail to the cases of Argentina, Brazil, and Chile. The section on “From Wage Inequality to Income Inequality” discusses the changing relationship between wage and income inequality in these countries. The “Conclusion” section concludes.

Theories and Hypotheses of Latin American Wage Inequality

In standard economic theory, interpersonal wage gaps are primarily regarded as the result of differentiated market returns to varying physical and mental abilities of employees. Higher levels of human capital are supposed to induce higher levels of labor productivity and these, in turn, are supposed to command a higher market price, all else being equal. In practice, however, interpersonal skill differences tend to coincide with differences in the technological, institutional, and organizational environments in which labor is employed. This makes it notoriously hard to isolate the effect of human capital on productivity and wage differentials. Wage differentials may be taken as a proxy for variation in human capital, but only under the assumption that labor markets adhere to the rules of perfect competition. Few scholars would argue that this is an unproblematic assumption. There is always some degree of wage regulation extorted on employers by governments, collective interest groups, and social conventions.
The huge literature on changing wage structures in the industrialized economies center stages two hypotheses that are both embedded in orthodox free market philosophies. The first theory stresses the role of factor-biased technological change (Levy and Murnane 1992; Goldin and Katz 1998; Acemoglu 2002). This theory departs from the assumption that shifts in production technology are usually factor-biased and, during the modern era, more often favor the use of skilled over unskilled labor. Whenever new technologies raise the comparative productivity of skilled labor, the demand for skills will increase. For instance, in recent decades, the computerization of production processes has been associated with a reduced demand for manual and routine cognitive tasks and an increased demand for nonroutine cognitive tasks (Autor et al. 1998, 2003). There is empirical evidence suggesting that these effects have also occurred in middle-income countries, including a number of LACs (Berman and Machin 2000).
A competing theory stresses the role of globalization in explaining changes in wage structures. According to this theory, distributional changes arise from trade-induced factor price equalization. The increasing integration of international commodity and capital markets during the post-war era has forced economies to specialize according to their comparative advantages. Globalization thus enhanced the employment of low-skilled labor in labor-intensive industries in developing countries competing on the basis of low wage costs. This effect has been associated with the rapid industrialization process in East and South East Asia. In the developed industrial economies, the labor-intensive sectors were driven out of the market, which supported a process of structural change towards technology and skill-intensive production activities. This trend however, has put the system of moderate earnings inequality under pressure: intensified schooling and labor training efforts could not prevent that the demand for increasingly specific labor skills rose faster than its supply (Wood 1994; Freeman 1995; Richardson 1995; Feenstra and Hanson 2003).
One of the reasons for the longstanding debate about the primacy of one explanation over the other is that domestic technological change and international market integration tend to reinforce each other, which makes it difficult to isolate their individual effects. Modern technological change and globalization are both favoring skilled labor in the developed industrialized economies (Atkinson and Piketty 2007) and, arguably, both favoring unskilled labor in the newly industrializing countries. Hence, in line with the Stolper–Samuelson theorem of international comparative cost advantages, skill-biased technological change has been part of a broader process of economic specialization in response to global competition.
But there is more. Standard economic theories of wage inequality tend to neglect the role of public policy responses to changing labor market conditions. Governments can directly intervene in wage structures by minimum wage legislation or adjusting public sector wages to private sector developments. Trade unions have a certain degree of bargaining power depending on the legal basis for strikes and other forms of organized collective action. In a more indirect way, governments can diminish wage differentials by removing educational access barriers and allocate subsidies training programs in sectors facing skill scarcity. Immigration policies are often factor-biased as well and can work both ways.
While such policy responses may not be of decisive importance in the Anglo-Saxon economies where wages are primarily set by the market, in the coordinated market economies of Western Europe the impact of government regulation can hardly be neglected. Although skill-biased technological change and globalization have been weakening the position of low-skilled workers in more or less identical ways in both parts of the industrialized world, wage inequality levels in France, the Netherlands, or Sweden have, in contrast to the USA and UK, hardly risen in the past four decades (Atkinson and Piketty 2007).
These theoretical considerations are also relevant for Latin America, as the interaction between changing labor market forces and changing government regulation of the labor market has been intense in many LACs during the twentieth century. We can think of at least three major factors which set LACs apart from the industrialized countries in this respect.
First, during the twentieth century, Latin America transformed from a labor scarce (net receiving) region into a labor-abundant (net sending) region. Extraordinary rates of population growth in the twentieth century deepened the dualistic nature of Latin American labor markets. Dualistic labor markets are characterized by overt differences in human capital, labor rights, capital market access, and social mobility (Perry and Olarreaga 2006; Galiani and Porto 2008).1 The limited access of rural migrants to land, education, and investment capital enhanced the supply of low-qualified urban laborers, many of whom ended up in low-productive informal service sector activities with little prospects of social mobility. High access barriers to decent education reproduced socioeconomic inequality (Birdsall et al. 1997; Frankema 2009b; Wegenast 2009; Lindert 2010). A structural oversupply of low-skilled labor occurred in all major Latin American cities, albeit to different degrees (Cardoso and Helwege 1992).2
Second, many LACs were deeply engaged in import substitution industrialization (ISI) policies between ca. 1930 and 1980. The political ideologies connected to these ISI programs not only emphasized the need to protect key domestic markets against foreign competition, but also often promoted the emancipation of the urban working class. The absence of international market discipline enabled long-term wage regulation programs that sought to suppress wage gaps across industries and between blue- and white-collar workers. Consequently, the labor market reforms of the 1970s, 1980s, and 1990s unleashed a process of wage adjustments long after demand–supply relations had started to change. Labor market liberalization also coincided with the removal of international trade barriers. Between 1975 and 2000 the share of exports in total Latin American gross domestic product (GDP) increased from ca. 7% to 20% and the share of imports rose at a comparable pace (Ocampo and Martin 2003: Fig. 2.3, p. 24). The share of industrial products in total exports also increased dramatically, from ca. 17% in 1960 to 66% in 1999 (Frankema and Smits 2005: Table 3, p. 185).
Third, Latin American labor market reforms left ample space for rent-seeking behavior. When the principles of collective wage bargaining and central wage setting during the ISI era were replaced by a decentralized system of wage bargaining (Arbache and Carneiro 1999), a trade-off emerged between wage demands and mass lay-offs. Some categories of employees remained protected by preferential treatments, however. Institutionalized monopolies or monopsonies were operating in the mining industries (including oil refineries), the financial and real estate sector and, not very surprisingly, the government sector (Galiani and Porto 2008). High-profit margins in protected sectors created incentives for rent sharing (Fontagne and Mirza 2007). If rents are high, it pays for workers to organize themselves in order to command a part of that margin. Disproportionate salaries of top managers can be made acceptable by using the wage bill as a lubricant for interpersonal loyalty, positive publicity, and self-enrichment.
The diagram presented in Fig. 1 visualizes the causal logic underlying the application of standard economic theories of wage inequality to the specific features of Latin American political and economic development in the twentieth century. We derive three hypotheses from this diagram which are to explain both, the differences of long-term wage inequality among LACs, as well as between the LACs and the other NWCs:
1.
Similar to the NWCs, Latin American wage inequality has increased in the course of the twentieth century due to the skill-biased nature of international and domestic economic change.
 
2.
The rise of Latin American wage inequality tended to be higher than in the NWCs however, because of the region’s manifest inequalities in its education systems and the depth of the demographic transition in LACs, which in combination generated a vast oversupply of low-skilled labor.
 
3.
The secular rise of wage inequality has followed a step-wise pattern in most LACs, because the effects of skill-biased technological change and globalization were mediated through political-institutional shocks. Intercountry differences in labor market policies and reforms can account for the different long-term wage inequality trends observed within Latin America.
 

Latin American Wage Inequality in Comparative Perspective, 1900–1950

Inter-industry Wage Inequality

Industrial survey and census data are a grateful source for wage inequality research. Industrial surveys cover a broad range of productive activities, varying largely in terms of capital intensity and technology–skill content. Inter-industry wage gaps are therefore likely to pick up a large part of the variation resulting from differences in labor productivity and technological sophistication (Berman et al. 1994, 1998). Since industrial enterprises produce tradable commodities, the effects of (de-)globalization should be visible in the development of inter-industry wage gaps as well. The classification of industrial sectors is relatively consistent over time, which facilitates temporal and interspatial comparisons. Many economists use industrial survey for this reason focusing on the post-war era (Berman et al. 1998; Berman and Machin 2000; Galbraith and Berner 2001; Galbraith and Kum 2002). However, industrial surveys are also available for various LACs in the pre-war era, which allows us to explore wage inequality trends in a more or less consistent framework over a longer period of time.
We use pre-war industrial surveys to compute (1) the average annual wage (μ xi ) for the industrial sector of country (x), in year (i); (2) the standard deviation of inter-industry wage differentials (σ xi ) over n industries (or sectors); (3) the coefficient of variation (σ xi xi ); and (4) the Theil coefficient of inter-industry wage differentials. In contrast to the coefficient of variation, the Theil index not only includes the size of the wage gaps in measuring the dispersion of wages, but it also weighs the relative contribution of each sector in total income (Theil 1967, 1972). The Theil index is formally specified as:
$$ T = \sum\limits_i {w_y^i\log \left( {w_y^i/w_e^i} \right)} $$
where the Theil coefficient T sums up over the log percentage share of sector i in total value added or total labor income (w i y ), minus the log percentage share of sector i in the total labor force (w i e ). Each sectors’ Theil contribution is weighted for the percentage share of income of each sector i in total income (w i y ).
Contrary to the post-war surveys, which have adopted the International Standard Industrial Classification (ISIC) classification with a predetermined number of predefined industries, the number of industrial sectors included in the pre-war surveys differs from country to country and, occasionally, within countries over time. To some extent, these differences reflect differences in the industrial sector structure between countries, but they may also reflect the adoption of different industrial classification schemes. Common industries such as foodstuffs, textiles, wood, paper, printing, chemicals, nonmetallic minerals (glass, stone, clay, ceramics, etc.), metals and machinery, or engineering are covered in almost all pre-war surveys, but for a subset of industries the aggregation levels differ.
The figures presented here only relate to industrial enterprises with formally registered employees, excluding owner-operated artisan shops. As the majority of observations are based on census data, the coverage of the industrial labor force is encouraging, but never complete. For instance, the 1910 benchmark for Chile includes approximately 35% of the industrial labor force, the 1913 benchmark of Argentina ca. 63% and the 1920 benchmark of Brazil around 40%.3 For the post-war figures presented in the next section, the coverage is larger, usually ranging between 60% and 90%. Differences in coverage can have an effect on the inequality comparison, but the bias is likely to be small because the Theil coefficient is based on sectoral averages.
Biases may also result from the aggregation of industries. Whenever sectoral averages disclose part of the wage variation, they will result in a downward bias of the computed inter-industry wage gap. Therefore, a low number of recorded sectors may produce an underestimation of comparative levels of wage inequality, although this is not necessarily the case.4 Hence, caution is required when interpreting the figures in Table 1 below, especially regarding Peru (1933) and Canada (1935), which are based on a survey including only nine sectors. Yet, for most countries, we have surveys with a fair amount of sectoral detail, covering between 15 and 22 industries.
Table 1
Inter-industry labor income differentials in Latin America and the New World, 1900–1940
 
Year
Currency
No. of sectors
Average wage
SD
Coefficient of variation
Theil coefficient
Argentina
1913
Peso m/n
20
1012
277
0.27
0.0066
Argentina
1917
Peso m/n
13
3.31
0.74
0.22
0.0061
Argentina
1937
Peso m/n
22
1,513
383
0.24
0.0092
Brazil
1920
Real
12
1,606
477
0.25
0.0085
Brazil
1939
Real
20
2,469
604
0.24
0.0089
Chile
1910
Peso
17
959
226
0.24
0.0077
Chile
1925
Peso
17
2,499
602
0.23
0.0053
Colombia
1938
Peso
15
1.49
0.42
0.28
na
Mexico
1939
Peso
22
0.56
0.14
0.26
na
Peru
1933
Sol
9
846
171
0.20
na
Uruguay
1930
Peso
19
487
84
0.17
0.0042
US
1900
USD
15
437
73
0.16
0.0061
US
1914
USD
16
579
85
0.15
0.0059
US
1925
USD
16
1,280
204
0.16
0.0059
US
1935
USD
16
1,023
210
0.19
0.0082
Canada
1910
CAD
15
419
84
0.19
0.0096
Canada
1935
CAD
9
852
106
0.12
0.0044
Australia
1912
AUS Pound
17
115
20
0.18
0.0136
Australia
1923
AUS Pound
19
180
33
0.17
0.0091
Australia
1935
AUS Pound
15
167
34
0.17
0.0096
New Zealand
1906
NZ pound
18
79
18
0.23
0.0078
New Zealand
1935
NZ pound
18
207
42
0.19
0.0132
Argentina: Censo Comercal e Industrial de la Republica 1913, Boletin no. 20, Capital Federal, Minesterio de Agricultura, Buenos Aires 1914; Anuario Estadistico 1917, Boletin no. 42, Buenos Aires 1919; Estadistica Industrial de la Republica Argentina 1938, Buenos Aires 1940; Brazil: Recenseamento do Brazil 1920, Volume V, Rio de Janeiro 1927; Recenseamento do Brasil 1950, sinopse preliminar do censo industrial, Rio de Janeiro 1953; Chile: Estadistica Industrial de la Republica de Chile, 1910; Anuario Estadistico de la Republica de Chile, Vol. IX, 1925, Santiago de Chile 1927; Colombia, Mexico: ILO, Yearbook of Labour Statistics 1941, sixth year, Montreal 1942; Peru: Ministerio de Fomento, Las Industrias en el Peru 1936, Boletin del Cuerpo de Ingenieros de Minas del Peru, No. 114, Lima 1936; Uruguay: Censo Industrial de 1930, in: Revista de la Union Industrial de Uruguaya, ano 57, no. 135; USA: Abstract of the Twelfth Census of the US 1900, Washington 1902; Statistical Abstract of the US 1928, Washington 1928; Statistical Abstract of the US 1928, 50th number; Washington Statistical Abstract of the US 1938, 60th number, Washington; Canada: The Canada Yearbook 1912, Ottawa 1913; Dominion Bureau of Statistics, The Canada Yearbook 1938, Ottawa 1938; Australia: Manufacturing Industries in the Commonwealth 1912, Melbourne 1914; Production Bulletin No. 17, Summary of Australian Production Statistics for 1912–13 to 1922–23, Melbourne; Production Bulletin No. 30, Summary of Australian Production Statistics for 1925–26 to 1935–36, Canberra; New Zealand: The New Zealand Official Year-Book 1910, Nineteenth year of issue, Wellington, 1910; The New Zealand Official Year-Book 1938, Forty-Sixth issue, Wellington, 1938
The public utilities sector was deliberately removed from the estimation procedure to avoid a potential bias in comparison with surveys excluding this sector. Employees working in public utilities usually receive wages or salaries at the top end of the industrial wage distribution. In Argentina in 1917, Colombia 1938, and Mexico 1939 daily wages were recorded. Since there is no clear conjecture about the potential bias this may cause, nothing has been undertaken to correct for this. The estimates of Peru 1933 and Canada 1935 must be interpreted with care given the relatively low number of sectors included in the survey
Comparing the coefficients of variation of inter-industry wage gaps across countries suggests that inter-industry wage inequality was slightly higher in the LACs than in the four NWCs. The figures vary from 0.17 for Uruguay in 1930 to 0.28 for Colombia in 1938. In the four NWCs, the figures vary from 0.12 in Canada in 1935 (as noted above, this may be an underestimate) to 0.23 for New Zealand in 1906. Still, the overall level of wage dispersion in the LACs seems to have been relatively modest, especially when compared to the estimates of inter-industry wage inequality for the late twentieth century in a large sample of LACs (see next section, Table 3). The highest recorded coefficient of variation, 0.28 for Colombia in 1938, relates to a maximum inter-industry wage gap of 1:2.5 between the paper and cardboard industry at the bottom and the engineering industry at the top end of the wage distribution. Moreover, the estimated Theil coefficients indicate that the overall differences between the LACs and the NWCs were virtually negligible.
Figure 2 presents the Theil coefficients for Argentina, Brazil, Chile, the USA, and Australia. Note that the number of sectors included in the surveys of these countries is higher in the three LACs than in the two NWCs, so if the comparison is biased due to differences in statistical record keeping the Theil coefficients of the USA and Australia are likely to be underestimated.
Figure 2 suggests that there were no large structural differences in the overall industrial wage distribution between Argentina, Brazil, and Chile on the one hand and the USA and Australia on the other hand. Hence, the higher coefficients of variation in the LACs were mainly caused by sectors at the outer end of the distribution with a relatively small contribution to total industrial labor income and a relatively small share in industrial employment.

Intra-Industry Wage Inequality

An analysis of inter-industry wage gaps may hide the major part of industrial wage inequality, if wage gaps within industries were much larger than across industries. Wage inequality would then have been driven by earning differences between unskilled and skilled workers, while the distribution of both groups of workers across industries was relatively equal. A limited number of pre-war industrial surveys give detailed information about the relative earnings of blue- and white-collar workers. Despite the scattered nature of these observations, the ratios of the average white over blue-collar wage level can provide a crude impression of the comparative size of intra-industry wage gaps.
In Argentina in 1913, the “white-collar premium” was estimated at 1.71 in the industrial sector and 1.74 in trade and commerce (including wholesale and retail).5 In Chile in 1925, the average white-collar employee earned 3.01 times as much as the average blue-collar worker, which was notably higher, but in 1937 the Chilean white-collar premium was estimated to be 1.99, which is more in line with the level observed in Argentina. By comparison, for Canada in 1905 and 1925 we obtained a white-collar premium of 1.85 and 1.90, respectively. In Australia, we record a white-collar premium of 1.67 in 1923.
These figures suggest that Latin American wage gaps were modest across and within industries and not significantly higher than in the other NWCs. A more comprehensive view can be obtained from occupational wage surveys providing hourly wage levels in various construction occupations. These surveys are collected and published in the earliest editions of the ILO Yearbook of Labor Statistics and include information about wage levels in a number of major world cities, including some Latin American cities. Construction wages are widely used in economic historical studies to study long-term developments in real wages and skill premiums. Labor requirements for construction activities are characterized by a combination of low-skilled physical labor, such as carrying or preparing construction materials, and skilled labor with specifically designated tasks in the design and/or construction of buildings. For this reason, construction industry wages are considered to be quite suitable for comparative purposes (Phelps Brown and Hopkins 1957; Allen 2001; Clark 2007).
To calculate the average skill premium in the construction industry, we took the unweighted average of the hourly wage of carpenters and joiners, masons and bricklayers, structural iron workers, concrete workers, plumbers, painters, and electrical fitters and divided this number by the average wages of unskilled day laborers (peones) in construction. A peon, by definition, represents a worker without a clearly designated task in the construction process. Observations for a larger sample of cities are available from the mid-1930s to the mid-1950s. We split this period in two, 1935–1942 and 1946–1955, to exclude the (economically) most disruptive years of WWII (1943–45) and to accommodate differences in sample size. For the latter period, a substantial number of Asian and some African cities could be included. Figure 3a and b presents the results.
Skill premiums in the construction trade in the major Latin American cities turn out to have been only a little higher than in Melbourne, Sydney, and Wellington and more or less comparable with the North American cities New York, Los Angeles, and Toronto. Skill premiums in Latin American cities were notably smaller than in the majority of Asian cities. The variation in skill premiums across Asian cities appears to be larger as well. In Asia, the unweighted average is 2.06, with a variation coefficient of 0.18 and in Latin America (including four Caribbean cities: Havana, Kingston, San Juan, and Port of Spain) the unweighted average is 1.65 with a coefficient of variation of 0.14. Four Latin American cities in the period under consideration record a skill premium exceeding 2.0. These are Rio de Janeiro, La Paz, Bogota, and Caracas. The contrast with the few African cities in the sample underlines the conclusion that intra-industry wage gaps in Latin America appeared to be rather modest by international standards in the first half of the twentieth century.

Gender Wage Inequality

Whereas skill premiums mainly result from differences in workers’ capabilities and responsibilities in production tasks, gender wage differentials contain a discriminatory component embedded in culturally determined views on the social status of women. In theory, gender wage discrimination occurs when females with comparable capacities, performing comparable tasks, receive lower rewards than their male counterparts. In practice, it is hard to isolate the discriminatory component in female wage setting because women often perform specifically designed tasks.
The figures presented in Table 2 can therefore only provide a crude impression of gender wage differentials and should be taken as upper-bound estimates. We compare the estimates of the LACs to the USA, Canada, Australia, and two large Asian countries, Japan and India, for which comparable data is available: all the male–female wage ratios presented are based on the average wages of male and female in the industrial sector as derived from industrial surveys or national wage statistics.
Table 2
Gender wage differentials in the industrial sector in Latin America, the New World, Japan, and India, 1905–1940
  
Average wage male/female
Argentina (Buenos Aires)
1917
1.64
1940
1.90
Brazil
1920
1.68
Chile
1909
2.16
Colombia
1938
1.68
Mexico
1939
1.52
Australia
1912
2.41
1938
1.87
Canada
1905
1.99
1938
1.78
New Zealand
1906
2.10
1938
1.72
Japan
1938
2.92
India (Bombay)
1934
3.21
Argentina: Anuario Estadistico 1917, Boletin no. 42, Buenos Aires 1919; ILO, Yearbook of Labour Statistics 1941, sixth year, Montreal 1942; Brazil: Recenseamento do Brazil 1920, Volume V, Rio de Janeiro 1927; Chile: Estadistica Industrial de la Republica de Chile, 1910; Colombia, Mexico: ILO, Yearbook of Labour Statistics 1941, sixth year, Montreal 1942; Canada: The Canada Yearbook 1912, Ottawa 1913; Dominion Bureau of Statistics, The Canada Yearbook 1938, Ottawa 1938; Australia: Manufacturing Industries in the Commonwealth 1912, Melbourne 1914; ILO, Yearbook of Labour Statistics 1941, sixth year, Montreal 1942 New Zealand: The New Zealand Official Year-Book 1910, Nineteenth year of issue, Wellington, 1910; The New Zealand Official Year-Book 1938, Forty-Sixth issue, Wellington, 1938; Japan: Bank of Japan (1962) Historical Statistics of the Japanese Economy, Tokyo; India: Labour Office, Government of Bombay, General Wage Census, Part 1, Perennial Factories (May 1934), Bombay 1935
Gender wage gaps in the five recorded LACs range from 2.16 in Chile (1910) to 1.52 in Mexico (1939). These figures compare to 2.41 in Australia (1912) and 1.72 in New Zealand (1938). They suggest that between 1905 and 1940, gender wage differentials in Latin America were somewhat lower than in the NWCs and notably lower than in Japan and India in the 1930s, although the empirical evidence is rather thin. There is additional support, however, for the view that gender wage gaps were comparatively modest in Latin America. Camps et al. argue that gender wage gaps in the urban sectors of the economy in Latin America during the second globalization era (this study covers the period 1975–2000) were not only smaller, but also declined more rapidly than in a sample of East Asian countries (Camps et al. 2006). According to Camps et al., the relatively modest gender gaps in human capital formation in Latin America are the most important explanation for the observed difference. Empirical evidence of gender inequality in education for the late nineteenth and early twentieth century also demonstrates that the gender gap in LACs was comparatively small.
Table 3 presents female primary school enrolment shares for six LACs, three NWCs, and four Asian countries. The data are derived from Lindert (2004: Table 5.2, p. 95). The enrolment share of female students in primary education indicates that although there certainly existed a gap between boys and girls in Latin American primary schools, this gap was comparatively modest and around the mid-twentieth century it had been virtually completely resolved in most LACs (Frankema 2009a: Table 4.2, p.94–5). In many LACs, the female enrolment shares were comparable to those in the USA, Canada, and Australia.
Table 3
The percentage share of female in total primary school enrolment in Latin America, the New World, and Asia, 1880–1902
  
% share female of primary enrolled
Argentina
1900
46.1
Chile
1900
51.6
Uruguay
1890–04
45.1
El Salvador
1893
43.4
Guatemala
1890–04
32.8
Cuba
1901–02
46.8
Australia (3 states)
1890–04
48.3
Canada (7 provinces)
1901
49.0
US
1880
48.5
Japan
1892
30.9
India: Bombay
1900–01
14.2
 Punjab
1900–01
7.6
 Madras
1899–00
6.2
 Mysore
1900–01
17.8
Burma
1900–01
7.8
Ceylon
1898
5.0
Source: All data derived from Lindert (2004: Table 5.2, p. 95)
More remarkable is the contrast with the Asian countries. Even Guatemala, one of the least modernized LACs, recorded a female enrolment share (32.8%) higher than Japan (30.9%), arguably the most modernized East Asian country of the late nineteenth century. And compared to some of the regions of the Indian subcontinent, where the female share remained below 10%, gender inequality in primary education in Latin America appears to be very modest. Hence, the Latin American–Asian contrast in educational gender inequality seems to be reflected in the differences in gender wage inequality as revealed in Table 3.
In sum, all three analytical perspectives indicate that Latin American wage inequality has been comparatively modest by international standards during the first half of the twentieth century, despite some notable intraregional differences. The next section will show that this Latin American pattern of “modest” wage inequality changed dramatically during the second half of the twentieth century and, in some countries, also changed rather abruptly.

The Post-War Rise of Latin American Wage Inequality, 1950–2000

This section explores the long-term trend in inter-industry wage distribution by linking the scattered evidence of the first half of the twentieth century to the more consistent time series that can be obtained for the post-war period. As argued above, there exists no single wage inequality measure that captures developments in the total wage distribution, but the inter-industry wage inequality indicator is one of the most comprehensive measures available. Reflecting changes in the skill and technology composition of industrial sectors, this measure is likely to pick up the effects of skill-biased structural changes in the economy (Galbraith and Berner 2001). Sectoral data on employment, wages, and value added have been collected in a consistent framework of sector classifications from the 1950s onwards. Our post-1950 estimates of inter-industry wage inequality are based on the ISIC of economic activities, including 20 manufacturing branches, as presented in the UN Yearbook of Industrial Statistics.6 Since ISIC has been revised two times between 1950 and 2000, we show the results for the ISIC 1 and 2 classifications.7
Table 4 presents the inter-industry wage inequality estimates for 15 LACs in 6 consecutive periods during the twentieth century and compares these to the figures for the USA, Canada, and Australia. Only for Argentina, Brazil, and Chile we were able to find sufficiently reliable data for the earlier periods. We chose 1974 (the oil crises) and 1989 (endpoint of the “lost decade”) as benchmark years and excluded the 1940s due to lack of data.
Table 4
Theil coefficient of inter-industry wage inequality in Latin America, 1900–2000
 
1900–1920
1921–1940
1950–1973
1974–1989
1974–1989
1990–2000
1990–2000
 
ISIC 1
ISIC 1
ISIC 2
ISIC 1
ISIC 2
Argentina
0.006
0.009
0.006
0.014
0.015
0.022
0.023
Bolivia
  
0.019
0.023
0.025
0.038
0.040
Brazil
0.009
0.009
0.013
0.027
0.027
0.047
0.048
Chile
0.008
0.005
0.014
0.025
0.026
0.027
0.029
Colombia
  
0.020
0.015
0.017
0.018
0.019
Costa Rica
  
0.008
0.015
0.015
0.018
0.019
Dominican Republic
  
0.021
0.031
0.031
na
na
Ecuador
  
0.016
0.012
0.014
0.037
0.039
El Salvador
  
0.013
0.015
0.016
0.028
0.030
Guatemala
  
0.021
0.030
0.032
0.034
0.046
Mexico
  
0.010
0.010
0.011
0.017
0.018
Panama
  
0.007
0.022
0.023
0.040
0.041
Peru
  
0.012
0.017
0.018
0.047
0.048
Uruguay
  
0.012
0.015
0.016
0.030
0.031
Venezuela
  
0.013
0.013
0.014
0.032
0.035
Latin America average
0.007
0.008
0.014
0.019
0.020
0.031
0.033
Australia
0.014
0.009
0.002
0.003
0.003
0.007
0.008
Canada
0.010
0.005
0.007
0.008
0.008
0.009
0.010
USA
0.006
0.007
0.007
0.013
0.014
0.010
0.011
New World average
0.010
0.007
0.006
0.008
0.009
0.009
0.010
See“Latin American Wage Inequality in Comparative Perspective, 1900–1950” section for pre-1950 data. Post-1950 data are taken from various issues of the United Nations, The Growth of World Industry, National Tables, New York (1953–1974); United Nations, Yearbook of Industrial Statistics, New York (1975–1992); UNIDO, International Yearbook of Industrial Statistics, Vienna (1993–2005)
In case of more than one observation per period, the average is included
Table 4 shows that the rise of wage inequality was a widely shared Latin American phenomenon. In all 15 LACs, there was a net increase between 1950 and 2000. The unweighted regional average of the Theil coefficient of inter-industry wage inequality increased from 0.014 (1950–73) to 0.019 (1974–1989) and further, to 0.031 in the 1990s.
The magnitude and timing of the increase differed substantially across countries, however. The rise in Colombia and Mexico, for instance, was much smaller than in Panama or Peru. In some LACs, we observe a trend break in the 1960s (Costa Rica and Panama), but in the majority of cases in the 1970s or early 1980s (Argentina, Bolivia, Chile, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Guatemala, and Peru).
A global comparative perspective reveals that the dramatic upward trend that can be observed in the LACs did not occur in the three NWCs. In Australia and Canada, the rise of the Theil coefficient was gradual and modest. A slight downward trend can be discerned from the early twentieth century onwards until the mid-1970s, when inter-industry wage differentials started to widen. In the USA, a more pronounced rise can be noted during the 1970s. Considering that the three NWCs entered a phase of post-industrial economic development during the last decades of the twentieth century, it seems justified to conclude that the peak level of industrial wage inequality has been much higher in Latin America than in North America.

Explaining Long-Term Wage Inequality Trends in Latin America

We have seen that during the first half of the twentieth century, wage inequality in the LACs did not differ markedly from the NWCs. The gap between rich and poor was primarily a gap between capital owners and wage laborers. The manufacturing sector was dominated by small workshops where technology–skill complementarities and opportunities for rent sharing by the higher management were comparatively small. Moreover, the supply of unskilled labor was far less abundant in this period. This changed in the course of the twentieth century. The share of wages and salaries in the income portfolio of the higher social classes rose and the progress in industrial technology created ample opportunities for job diversification, growing productivity differentials, and increasing gaps in labor remunerations. The growing impact of wage inequality in overall income inequality has been documented for many industrial countries (Atkinson and Piketty 2007).
The key question, however, is why the post-war rise in inter-industry wage inequality was so much more pronounced in Latin America? To answer this question, it is useful to look in greater detail at three larger Latin American economies for which we have particularly good long-term series, i.e., Argentina, Brazil, and Chile. These three cases are instructive for two more reasons. First, all three countries experienced a major phase of industrialization during the twentieth century which has fundamentally transformed the structure of their economies and the composition of their export packages. Second, all three countries have experienced notably different patterns of long-term wage inequality development which helps to shed more light on the underlying determinants of some of the intraregional differences noted in the previous section. The theoretical framework of “Theories and Hypotheses of Latin American Wage Inequality” section is adopted to examine to which extent plain economic theory can account for these intraregional differences and to which extent political–institutional shocks need to be incorporated in order to understand critical junctures in the long-term trend.
Figure 4 shows that all three LACs experienced a spectacular rise in industrial labor income differentials during the post-war era when compared to the NWCs and their own pre-war levels, but the magnitude and timing of the trend breaks differs. In Argentina, we observe a modest increase of wage inequality between 1910 and the mid-1930s, followed by a marked decline during the 1940s and 1950s, and a very steep increase of wage inequality from the mid-1970s onwards, continuing until the end of the century.8 In Brazil, we observe a nearly continuous increase from the 1940s onwards, with a minor interruption in the 1970s. In Chile, we also see a long-term rise but with a steep decline between 1964 and 1973.
The Argentinean trend breaks in the mid-1940s and mid-1970s coincide with two major landmarks in its political history: the beginning and end of Peronismo. Wage regulation schemes became part of government policy during the 1940s, when Perón launched a radical reform agenda including real wage increases, a reduction of working hours, paid vacation, and the implementation of an extensive social security system. Comprehensive wage regulation programs remained in place until the mid-1970s, testifying to the longstanding commitment of various Argentine governments to ISI policies (Rock 1987: 262–6; Romero 2002: 65–9). State subsidies and trade tariffs shielded the industrial sector from foreign competition and enabled a system of wage setting that circumvented international market pressures. Not only were industrial wage gaps small, the labor share in national income was also comparatively high, between 50% and 60% of total GDP (Beccaria 1991; Galiani and Gerchunoff 2003: 152; Frankema 2010).
The military coup of 1976 heralded a decisive reorientation of socioeconomic policy inspired by neoliberal economic ideology. Confronted with inflation rates of nearly 600%, Martínez de Hoz, the minister of economy in the Vidéla administration, decreed a freeze on wages. After several failed attempts, inflation was eventually suppressed but at the expense of a dramatic fall in the purchasing power of ordinary wage earners. A wide array of economic reform schemes, including privatization of state enterprises, mass lay-offs, a reduction of trade barriers, and the introduction of a new currency, made the income position of wage earners extremely insecure (Lewis 1990: 460–9).
The major long-run changes in Argentina’s wage inequality can thus be explained by political regime changes altering the nature of government wage regulation (Altimir 1986; Altimir and Beccaria 1999). But changing government policies cannot fully explain the continuous worsening of the wage distribution after the mid-1970s. In their attempt to evaluate the impact of changing market forces, Galiani and Sanguinetti separated industries witnessing import penetration deepening from those that remained largely unaffected by trade liberalization during the 1990s. They concluded that 15% of the additional increase of the within-sector skill premium in Argentina can be attributed to trade liberalization (Galiani and Sanguinetti 2003).
Waisgrais has argued that educational inequality is the single most important explanatory variable for Argentinean wage differentials in the 1980s and 1990s (Waisgras 2003: 39–41). However, with shares ranging between 14% and 23%, the contribution of human capital differentials still appears modest. Comparable studies of other LACs produce estimates in the range of 20–40% (Cárdenas and Bernal 1998; Chanduví and Díaz 1998; Ferreira and Litchfield 1998). These studies confirm that skill-biased technological change and globalization have been important in driving up Argentinean wage gaps in the last quarter of the twentieth century, but they also leave room for an explanation that emphasizes sector-biased opportunities of rent sharing. Indeed, after controlling for schooling, age, and sex differences, the combined effects of production scale and type of productive activity (which are both highly sector-specific) was found to account for 23% of Argentinean wage inequality (Waisgras 2003: 39).
In Chile, the major trend breaks in wage inequality can also be attributed to political regime changes. During the conservative government of Alessandri (1958–1964), inter-industry wage differentials increased under influence of higher payments in the metal and chemical sectors, which were dominated by the copper and nitrate enterprises. The electoral victory of the Christian Democratic Party in 1964 redefined the political balance (Collier and Sater 2004: 308). Frei nationalized Chile’s copper industry, which until then was controlled by American companies. One of the results of the nationalization program was a reduction of wage gaps between copper-related industries and other industries. This reduction was part of a more comprehensive policy to reduce the wage gaps between the private and the public sector and expand social benefits to previously neglected groups like the landless peasants and urban poor.
Urban wages converged during the Frei era, but the steepest decline of the Theil coefficient followed upon the installation of Allende’s socialist government in September 1970. Allende declared a large-scale nationalization of industries, a massive expansion of public works, and a “Keynesian” impulse to consumption and economic growth. Average wages rose with circa 55%, overcompensating an inflation rate of 33% (Wright 1982: 344). In line with his socialist principles, blue-collar workers in low-paying industries benefitted most from the new wage regulations. The Theil coefficient dropped from 0.017 to 0.007 between 1970 and 1973. The ratio of white- to blue-collar wages also declined from 2.81 in 1970 to 2.17 in 1973.
The economic policies of Frei and Allende can be placed in a longer tradition of welfare state expansion which had already begun in the 1920s. Levels of social spending in Chile were about twice as high as in the average LAC in the post-war era and comparable to many Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries, reaching a peak level of ca. 42% of total fiscal expenditure in the early 1970s. As a percentage share of GDP, social public expenditure increased from 2.1% in 1925 to 25.8% in 1972 (Arellano 1985: 404–5). With the growing political influence of labor unions, new types of benefits were implemented in the sphere of housing, health insurance, family and maternity allowances, unemployment pay, and dismissal indemnities.
These social policies did not lead to an uninterrupted decline of wage inequality. Arellano argues that during the 1930s, 1940s, and 1950s, the trade unions became increasingly middle-class oriented: bargaining in favor of their contributors, but neglecting the increasing income security gap with non-unionized or less powerful union workers, resulting in “a rather unequal structure of benefits and contributions” (Arellano 1985: 409).
The military coup of 1973 marked the key turning point in Chilean welfare policies. Pinochet launched a radical program of market reforms and a strong repression of labor unions. The Theil coefficient rose to unprecedented levels in the decade following 1973 and reached a temporary peak in the mid-1980s. In particular, the workers in the chemical, metal, and petroleum industries started to earn much better than workers in other sectors. In 1984, the white-collar premium had gone up from 2.17 in 1973 to 3.45. Around the mid-1980s, inter-industry wage gaps were more or less stabilized at a structurally higher level.
After Pinochet’s resignation and the return to democratic government, there was a strong political commitment to revitalize labor rights and amend the social inequalities which had prevailed for almost two decades of dictatorial rule. The center-left Concertatión de Partidos por la Democracia advocated the redistribution of income and wealth as one of its top priorities. Figure 4c indicates, however, that wage gaps did not diminish during the 1990s. This raises support for the argument of Barrett that the labor reforms enacted by the Aylwin administration were “largely cosmetic changes that helped to institutionalise the profound power imbalance in capital-labor relations and the subordination of labor policy to the demands of the economic model” (Barrett 2001: 568). Frank states in a similar fashion that “the economic model created by Pinochet’s Chicago Boys has been internalized by many of the Concertation parties and their members” (Frank 2002: 63).
The case of Chile demonstrates that even in an LAC with a historical commitment to welfare policies, liberalization programs have produced levels of wage inequality which were far higher than in the NWCs. Although the exact reasons need to be researched in greater detail than we do here, there is little doubt that Chile’s high educational inequality has aggravated the inequality impact of skill-biased changes in international and domestic economic conditions (Birdsall et al. 1997; Frankema 2008).
Having said this, wage inequality in Argentina and Chile never reached levels comparable to Brazil. In fact, Brazilian levels of inter-industry wage inequality grew larger than in any other LAC, with the possible exception of Peru. Wages started to diverge in the 1940s and only temporary converged during the 1970s. Table 5 shows the Theil coefficient of inter-industry labor productivity differentials (first column), together with the Theil coefficient of wage inequality (second column) and the ratio of the average nominal industrial wage to the legal nominal minimum wage (third column) between 1949 and 1999.
Table 5
Wage inequality and productivity differentials in Brazilian industry, 1949–1999
 
Theil coefficient labor productivity distribution
Theil coefficient wage distribution
Average industrial wage/Official minimum wage
1949
0.0185
0.0132
1.4
1953
0.0191
0.0159
1.8
1958
0.0155
0.0204
2.1
1962
0.0326
0.0216
2.3
1966
0.0197
0.0257
3.1
1970
0.0408
0.0275
2.5
1974
0.0432
0.0249
3.5
1977
0.0406
0.0211
3.3
1984
0.0567
0.0345
3.6
1992
na
0.0366
4.0
1996
0.0784
0.0466
6.9
1999
0.1264
0.0522
6.5
For the data used to calculate the Theil coefficient of the productivity and wage distribution and the average industrial wage, see Fig. 3b. The official minimum wage rates were obtained from IBGE, Anuário Estatístico do Brasil (various issues 1950–2000). All hourly minimum wage rates were multiplied with 2,400 h (300 working days of 8 h) to obtain a consistent benchmark for a comparison with annual industrial wages
Table 5 demonstrates that productivity gaps diverged strongly and that the average nominal industrial wage rose far above the official minimum wage in the second half of the twentieth century (the ratio rose from 1.4 in 1949 to 6.9 in 1996). Both developments reflect the expanding scope for increasing wage gaps in the industrial sector. Rising productivity differentials also reflect the extreme inequalities in the Brazilian education system (Park et al. 1996; Birdsall et al. 1997; Brown 2002; Frankema 2008, 2009b), which drove up the skill premium to unprecedented heights in the wake of skill-biased technological change and globalization.
Langoni has made a strong case for the poor state of education as the main determinant of the steep rise of Brazilian inequality in the 1960s. He argued that the rapid economic and technological development of Brazil raised the demand for scarce skilled labor, hence increasing the skill premium, while an oversupply of low-educated workers tied wages at the bottom of the wage distribution to subsistence levels (Langoni 1973; Langoni 1974). His argument is not undisputed however, as Bonelli and Ramos point out that during the 1980s, when Brazil’s economy stagnated and experienced a decade of zero growth, inequality kept rising. According to these authors, it is difficult to see how skill-biased technological change induced a further widening of wage and income gaps during the crises years (Bonelli and Ramos 1992: 6–7).
Again, this puzzle cannot be solved without paying attention to changes in government policy. Since the inception of collective wage bargaining under the Vargas administration and the implementation of the general Labor Code (Consolidação das Leis do Trabalho) in 1943, trade unions were legally recognized negotiating partners, but with limited rights. The ideology of Integralismo, which gained influence during the Vargas era (1930–54), promoted the transcendence of traditional class conflicts in the name of national economic interests. In this ideology socioeconomic inequality was regarded as a fundamental characteristic of an organic and dynamic society (Levine 1999: 94–119).
Contrary to the coups in Argentina (1976) and Chile (1973), the military coup of 1964 in Brazil reinforced prevalent wage policies. The military dictatorship (1964–1985) strengthened state control on wage bargaining procedures and continued to suppress the political role of trade unions: state-enforced wage programs were extended to all registered workers, lay-off costs were reduced, and political strikes were prohibited. By strengthening the authoritarian character of the Labor Code, the military government tried to control the vicious cycle of price hikes by a systematic under-indexation of wages (Carneiro 1998: 140–1). Many scholars have seen the adoption of different wage indexation schemes for different sectors as the major determinant of increasing wage gaps in this period (Macedo 1977; Bacha and Taylor 1978; Wells and Drobny 1982).
Figure 4b shows that wage inequality increased during periods of high inflation, such as the years 1959–1966, 1978–1985, and 1990–1993. Baer has estimated that during the years 1983–1987, minimum wage earners experienced a decline in purchasing power of up to 10% or more as a result of incomplete indexation (Baer 2001: 105–6 and 470–1). Policy responses to inflation can also partly explain the temporary convergence of wages during the 1970s, when economic conditions were relatively favorable. Inflation rates remained comparatively moderate until 1978 (hovering between 15% and 45%) which facilitated a rise in real minimum wages. The estimated gains were about 15% in São Paulo and 8% in Rio de Janeiro between 1970 and 1978 (Baer 2001: 105–6).
To which extent indexation policies were determined by political interests or by plain market forces is still not very well understood. Various scholars have argued that the Brazilian industrial sector offers ample opportunities for rent sharing. Sectorally organized trade unions can negotiate higher wages depending on their amount of political influence. This can explain part of the excessive earnings generated in the oil-related industry in Brazil (Colistete 2007). Arbache and Carneiro also argue that the differences in the bargaining power of trade unions were substantial (Arbache and Carneiro 1999). Carneiro reports evidence of “pervasive” rent sharing in the late 1980s and early 1990s in industries with high monopolistic market power such as the petrochemical industry (Carneiro 1998: 150–1).
In sum, the different wage inequality trends in Argentina, Chile, and Brazil do not seem to be a matter of more or less government intervention in the labor market, but rather of fundamental differences in the design and objectives of government wage regulation programs. The administrations of Perón, Frei, and Allende gave higher priority to the moderation of wage gaps than any of the post-war Brazilian governments ever did. This conclusion strengthens the overall argument of this study, namely that standard economic theory fails to explain wage inequality trends in Latin America because of its neglect of political responses to changing economic conditions. This is not to say that economic change was factor neutral in Latin America, on the contrary. The surplus of wage inequality in comparison to the NWCs at the end of the twentieth century testifies to the skill-biased content of structural and technological changes in economies characterized by high levels of human capital inequality.

From Wage Inequality to Income Inequality

What has been the impact of rising wage inequality on the overall interpersonal income distribution in LACs? The results presented above leave little doubt that wage inequality in Latin America, as in most other industrialized economies, has become a more important component of total income inequality, especially during the last quarter of the twentieth century (Atkinson and Piketty 2007). To obtain an impression of the potential contribution of wage inequality, we can compute Theil coefficients of gross household income inequality for benchmark years around 1960 and 2000 and compare these to the Theil coefficients of inter-industry wage inequality reported in this study. Table 6 presents the figures for Argentina, Brazil, and Chile.
Table 6
Comparing Theil coefficients of inter-industry wage inequality and total income inequality in Argentina, Brazil, and Chile, 1960–2002
  
Wage inequality (A)
Income inequality (B)
A/B
Years of observation
Theil coeffecient
Theil coeffecient
Argentina
1963/1961
0.003
0.127
0.02
2001/2001
0.034
0.214
0.16
Brazil
1962/1960
0.022
0.24
0.09
2002/2001
0.062
0.292
0.21
Chile
1968/1968
0.02
0.175
0.11
2000/2000
0.035
0.239
0.15
For total income inequality, data have been retrieved from the UNU-WIDER, World Income Distribution Database, version 2.0c. Wage inequality data are presented in this study (see “The Post-War Rise of Latin American Wage Inequality, 1950–20004” section)
The Theil coefficient of income inequality in Argentina 2001 refers exclusively to the urban population
Because the Theil index is a decomposable inequality indicator, we can derive some educated guesses form the data about the share of total labor income inequality in total interpersonal income inequality. Let us first assume, for the sake of the argument, that the observed wage dispersion within the industrial labor force is representative for the entire wage-earning population and that the entire income earning population receives a wage in addition to possible other sources income. As shown in Table 6, the shares would then have gone up from 2–11% around the year 1960 to 15–21% around the year 2000. The unaccounted part of total income inequality should be attributed to the interpersonal distribution of capital income. Capital income is always more unequally distributed, as only a minority of income earners tends to derive a substantial amount of income from asset ownership. Moreover, within this minority, a much smaller elite category of “super wealthy” represents the “top incomes” in the overall income distribution (Piketty and Saez 2006).
In reality however, the wage inequality shares presented in Table 6 are lower bound estimates. The interpersonal wage dispersion between all wage earners, engaged in all sectors of the economy, is certainly higher than the inter-industry inequality figures we have been focusing on in this study. For these will include the wages earned in low-productive (informal) service activities, the generally higher wages in the financial or real estate sectors, as well as the generally lower rural wages. It is therefore reasonable to assume that the total contribution of labor income inequality will at least be in the order of 20–30% of total income inequality in Argentina and Chile and perhaps even higher in Brazil, although there remains a possibility that the inter-industry wage gaps in Brazil provide a better coverage of total labor income inequality than in Argentina or Chile.
Indeed, the rising contribution of wage inequality to income inequality seems beyond doubt, but it is not certain that the rise of wage inequality has been responsible for the upward trend in income inequality as has been witnessed in the majority of LACs since the 1970s (Psacharopoulos et al. 1997; Morley 2001). When increasing skill premiums (or sector premiums) contribute to the growth of a middle class, the net effect of increasing wage differentials can go in either direction: it increases inequality among wage earners, but may reduce the income gap between capital owners and (part of) the wage earners. Unfortunately, the lack of reliable capital income distribution data remains a fundamental constraint to reaching conclusive evidence on the net inequality effect of changes in the factor income distribution.

Conclusion

A long-run comparative analysis of levels and trends in industrial wage inequality has revealed that wage inequality in most LACs was moderate during the first half of the twentieth century. Inter-industry wage gaps (between-group inequality), intra-industry wage gaps (within-group inequality) and gender wage gaps were comparable to other New World countries and considerably lower than in most East Asian countries. In the course of the twentieth century, and especially during its last quarter, Latin American wage inequality rose spectacularly. The rise was remarkably steep in comparison to the pre-war period as well as the trends observed in the USA, Canada, and Australia. Although we found substantial intraregional differences in timing and levels, the rise itself was a shared feature of all the 15 LACs examined in this study.
The rise of Latin American wage inequality cannot be understood without taking the great transformation in the composition of Latin American labor markets into account. Particularly during the second half of the twentieth century, a structural imbalance in the distribution of human capital across the labor force made Latin American economies highly susceptible to skill-biased changes in technology and international competition. The cases of Argentina and Chile have shown that wage gaps exploded after having been compressed for decades. The dramatic widening of sectoral productivity differentials in Brazil shows that some sectors could indeed afford to pay the higher wages to attract skilled workers, or alternatively, could afford to share rents on the basis of monopolistic advantages. This implies that it did not necessarily make a difference for levels of wage inequality whether wages were controlled by the state or determined by the market. But more than anything else, all three cases make clear that political–institutional conditions and reforms need to be integrated in theories explaining comparative wage inequality levels and trends in Latin America.

Acknowledgment

The author gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Dutch Science Foundation (NWO). The author wishes to thank Leandro Prados de la Escosura, Jaime Reis, Luis Bértola, Leticia Arroyo Abad, Jan Luiten van Zanden, Jan Pieter Smits, Bart van Ark, Harry Garretsen, Michiel Baud, Pitou van Dijk, Herman van der Werfhorst, Debin Ma, Collin Lewis, Albrecht Ritschl, Morton Jerven, and the participants of the session “Origins of economic growth in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries” at the European Social Science History Conference, Lisbon (26 Feb–1 March 2008), the participants of the Third joint Summerschool of GlobalEuronet and the Marie-Curie Research Training Network “Economic and Social Inequalities in Historical Perspective”, Paris School of Economics (7–11 July 2008), the participants of the Social Science seminar, University of Amsterdam (23 Sept 2008), and the participants of the Economic History seminar at the London School of Economics and Political Science (14 Jan 2009) and two anonymous reviewers for their valuable comments on previous drafts. The usual disclaimer applies.

Open Access

This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution Noncommercial License which permits any noncommercial use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author(s) and source are credited.
Open AccessThis is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution Noncommercial License (https://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by-nc/​2.​0), which permits any noncommercial use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author(s) and source are credited.
Fußnoten
1
Demographic growth started to increase rapidly during the 1920s and 1930s in most LACs, reaching peak rates during the 1950s and 1960s (Thorp 1998: appendix table I.1, p. 313; Astorga et al. 2005; Frankema 2009a: pp. 151–155).
 
2
For the region as a whole, rural population growth started to decline in the 1950s and became virtually zero in the mid-1970s. Individual LACs, most notably Argentina and Uruguay, deviated from the aggregate pattern because they reached their peak growth rates already before 1914, due to the heavy influx of immigrants, see Frankema (2009b: Table 6.2, p. 154).
 
3
Industrial labor force estimates from OXLAD, http://​oxlad.​qeh.​ox.​ac.​uk/​ (24-06-09); total numbers of wage and salary earners from the sources listed below Table 1.
 
4
A lower number of sectors does not necessarily result in smaller wage gaps. For example, when calculating the level of wage inequality in the USA among the nine sectors listed in the Canadian census, the coefficient of variation is 0.20, which is actually slightly higher than the 16 sector presented in Table 3. It crucially depends on whether the sectors at the low and top end of the distribution are separately included or not. Combining sectors in the middle of the distribution can have an enlarging effect on the variation measured by the coefficient of variation.
 
5
This figure is obtained from Minesterio de Agricultura, Censo Comercal e Industrial de la Republica 1913, Boletin no. 20 (Buenos Aires, 1914). The other figures are obtained from the sources listed at the bottom of Table 1.
 
6
The first compilation of national industrial statistics by the United Nations appeared in 1967, as The Growth of World Industry, 1953–1965, National Tables, New York. In 1975, this changed into UN, Yearbook of Industrial Statistics 1975, New York, and since 1993 the statistic has been published by the United Nations Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO) under the title, International Yearbook of Industrial Statistics, Vienna. See http://​www.​unido.​org/​index.​php?​id=​4879 (24-06-2009).
 
7
To check the potential bias of the conversion of classifications we also estimated the wage inequality trends on the basis of the ISIC revision 3. Although the estimated levels are generally higher, the long terms trends hardly differed from the ISIC 1 and 2 classifications.
 
8
The exact timing of the first phase remains uncertain due to a lack of intermediate observations between 1917 and 1935.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu D. Directed technical change. Rev Econ Stud. 2002;69:781–810.CrossRef Acemoglu D. Directed technical change. Rev Econ Stud. 2002;69:781–810.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Allen RC. The great divergence in European wages and prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War. Explor Econ Hist. 2001;38:411–47.CrossRef Allen RC. The great divergence in European wages and prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War. Explor Econ Hist. 2001;38:411–47.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Altimir O. Estimaciones de la distribución del ingreso en la Argentina, 1953–1980. Desarrollo Económico. 1986;25:521–66.CrossRef Altimir O. Estimaciones de la distribución del ingreso en la Argentina, 1953–1980. Desarrollo Económico. 1986;25:521–66.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Altimir O, Beccaria L, El mercado de trabajo bajo el nuevo regimen económico en Argentina. Serie Reformas Económicas No. 28. ECLAC, 1999. Santiago. Altimir O, Beccaria L, El mercado de trabajo bajo el nuevo regimen económico en Argentina. Serie Reformas Económicas No. 28. ECLAC, 1999. Santiago.
Zurück zum Zitat Arbache JS, Carneiro FG. Unions and interindustry wage differentials. World Development. 1999;27:1875–83.CrossRef Arbache JS, Carneiro FG. Unions and interindustry wage differentials. World Development. 1999;27:1875–83.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Arellano J-P. Social policies in Chile: a historical review. J Lat Am Stud. 1985;17:398–403.CrossRef Arellano J-P. Social policies in Chile: a historical review. J Lat Am Stud. 1985;17:398–403.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Arroyo Abad AL, Santos-Paulino AU. Trading inequality? Comparing the two globalization waves in Latin America. 2009. mimeo. Arroyo Abad AL, Santos-Paulino AU. Trading inequality? Comparing the two globalization waves in Latin America. 2009. mimeo.
Zurück zum Zitat Astorga P, Berges AR, Fitzgerald V. The standard of living in Latin America during the twentieth century. Econ Hist Rev. 2005;68:765–96. Astorga P, Berges AR, Fitzgerald V. The standard of living in Latin America during the twentieth century. Econ Hist Rev. 2005;68:765–96.
Zurück zum Zitat Atkinson AB, Piketty T. Top incomes over the twentieth century. A contrast between continental European and English-speaking countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2007. Atkinson AB, Piketty T. Top incomes over the twentieth century. A contrast between continental European and English-speaking countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2007.
Zurück zum Zitat Autor DH, Katz L, Krueger A. Computing inequality: have computers changed the labor market? Q J Econ. 1998;113:1169–214.CrossRef Autor DH, Katz L, Krueger A. Computing inequality: have computers changed the labor market? Q J Econ. 1998;113:1169–214.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Autor DH, Levy F, Murnane RJ. The skill content of recent technological change: an empirical exploration. Q J Econ. 2003;188:1279–333.CrossRef Autor DH, Levy F, Murnane RJ. The skill content of recent technological change: an empirical exploration. Q J Econ. 2003;188:1279–333.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bacha EL, Taylor L. Brazilian income distribution in the 1960s: facts, model results and the controversy. J Dev Stud. 1978;14:271–97.CrossRef Bacha EL, Taylor L. Brazilian income distribution in the 1960s: facts, model results and the controversy. J Dev Stud. 1978;14:271–97.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Baer W. The Brazilian economy. Growth and development. 5th. Westport: Praeger; 2001. Baer W. The Brazilian economy. Growth and development. 5th. Westport: Praeger; 2001.
Zurück zum Zitat Barrett PS. Labor policy, labor-business relations and the transition to democracy in Chile. J Lat Am Stud. 2001;33:561–97. Barrett PS. Labor policy, labor-business relations and the transition to democracy in Chile. J Lat Am Stud. 2001;33:561–97.
Zurück zum Zitat Beccaria L. Distribución del ingreso en la Argentina: explorando lo sucedido desde mediados de los setenta. Desarrollo Económico. 1991;31:319–38.CrossRef Beccaria L. Distribución del ingreso en la Argentina: explorando lo sucedido desde mediados de los setenta. Desarrollo Económico. 1991;31:319–38.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berman E, Machin S. Skill-biased technology transfer around the world. Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 2000;16:12–22.CrossRef Berman E, Machin S. Skill-biased technology transfer around the world. Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 2000;16:12–22.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berman E, Bound J, Griliches Z. Changes in the demand for skilled labor within US manufacturing: evidence from the annual survey of manufacturers. Q J Econ. 1994;109:367–97.CrossRef Berman E, Bound J, Griliches Z. Changes in the demand for skilled labor within US manufacturing: evidence from the annual survey of manufacturers. Q J Econ. 1994;109:367–97.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berman E, Bound J, Machin S. Implications of skill-biased technological change: international evidence. Q J Econ. 1998;113:1245–79.CrossRef Berman E, Bound J, Machin S. Implications of skill-biased technological change: international evidence. Q J Econ. 1998;113:1245–79.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bértola L. A 50 años de la curva de Kuznets: crecimiento económico y distribución del ingreso en Uruguay y otras economías de Nuevo asentamiento desde 1870. Investigaciones de Historia Económica. 2005;3:135–76. Bértola L. A 50 años de la curva de Kuznets: crecimiento económico y distribución del ingreso en Uruguay y otras economías de Nuevo asentamiento desde 1870. Investigaciones de Historia Económica. 2005;3:135–76.
Zurück zum Zitat Bértola L, Williamson JG. Globalization in Latin America before 1940. In: Bulmer-Thomas V, Coatsworth JH, Cortés Conde R, editors. The Cambridge economic history of Latin America. Volume II: the long twentieth century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2006. p. 11–57. Bértola L, Williamson JG. Globalization in Latin America before 1940. In: Bulmer-Thomas V, Coatsworth JH, Cortés Conde R, editors. The Cambridge economic history of Latin America. Volume II: the long twentieth century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2006. p. 11–57.
Zurück zum Zitat Bértola L, Castelnovo CR, Javier Willebald H. Income distribution in the Latin American Southern Cone during the first globalization boom, ca: 2008; 1870–1920. Working Papers in Economic History, WP 08–05. Bértola L, Castelnovo CR, Javier Willebald H. Income distribution in the Latin American Southern Cone during the first globalization boom, ca: 2008; 1870–1920. Working Papers in Economic History, WP 08–05.
Zurück zum Zitat Birdsall N, Ross D, Sabot R. Education, growth and inequality. In: Birdsall N, Jasperson F, editors. Pathways to growth: comparing East Asia and Latin America (Inter-American Development Bank). Washington DC: Johns Hopkins University Press; 1997. p. 93–130. Birdsall N, Ross D, Sabot R. Education, growth and inequality. In: Birdsall N, Jasperson F, editors. Pathways to growth: comparing East Asia and Latin America (Inter-American Development Bank). Washington DC: Johns Hopkins University Press; 1997. p. 93–130.
Zurück zum Zitat Bonelli R, Ramos L. Income distribution in Brazil: longer term trends and changes in inequality since the mid-1970s. Texto Para Discussão No. 288. 1992. Bonelli R, Ramos L. Income distribution in Brazil: longer term trends and changes in inequality since the mid-1970s. Texto Para Discussão No. 288. 1992.
Zurück zum Zitat Brown DS. Democracy, authoritarianism and education finance in Brazil. J Lat Am Stud. 2002;34:115–41.CrossRef Brown DS. Democracy, authoritarianism and education finance in Brazil. J Lat Am Stud. 2002;34:115–41.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Camps E, Camou MM, Maubrigades S, Mora-Sitja N. Globalization and wage inequality in South and East Asia, and Latin America: a gender approach. Working Paper presented at the International Economic History Conference Helsinki. 2006. Camps E, Camou MM, Maubrigades S, Mora-Sitja N. Globalization and wage inequality in South and East Asia, and Latin America: a gender approach. Working Paper presented at the International Economic History Conference Helsinki. 2006.
Zurück zum Zitat Cárdenas M, Bernal R. Changes in the distribution of income and the new economic model in Colombia. Serie Reformas Económicas. ECLAC. 1998. Cárdenas M, Bernal R. Changes in the distribution of income and the new economic model in Colombia. Serie Reformas Económicas. ECLAC. 1998.
Zurück zum Zitat Cardoso E, Helwege A. Latin America’s economy. Diversity, trends, and conflicts. Cambridge: MIT; 1992. Cardoso E, Helwege A. Latin America’s economy. Diversity, trends, and conflicts. Cambridge: MIT; 1992.
Zurück zum Zitat Carneiro FG. Productivity effects in Brazilian wage determination. World Development. 1998;26:139–53.CrossRef Carneiro FG. Productivity effects in Brazilian wage determination. World Development. 1998;26:139–53.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chanduví JS, Díaz JJ. Desigualdad del ingreso y del gasto en el Péru antes y después de las reformas estructurales. Serie Reformas Económicas. ECLAC. 1998. Chanduví JS, Díaz JJ. Desigualdad del ingreso y del gasto en el Péru antes y después de las reformas estructurales. Serie Reformas Económicas. ECLAC. 1998.
Zurück zum Zitat Clark G. A farewell to Alms. A brief economic history of the world. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2007. Clark G. A farewell to Alms. A brief economic history of the world. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2007.
Zurück zum Zitat Coatsworth JH. Inequality, institutions and economic growth in Latin America. J Lat Am Stud. 2008;40:545–69.CrossRef Coatsworth JH. Inequality, institutions and economic growth in Latin America. J Lat Am Stud. 2008;40:545–69.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Colistete RP. Productivity, wages, and labor politics in Brazil, 1945–1962. J Econ Hist. 2007;67:93–127.CrossRef Colistete RP. Productivity, wages, and labor politics in Brazil, 1945–1962. J Econ Hist. 2007;67:93–127.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Collier S, Sater WF. A history of Chile 1808–2002. 2nd. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2004. Collier S, Sater WF. A history of Chile 1808–2002. 2nd. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2004.
Zurück zum Zitat De Ferranti D, Perry GE, Ferreira FHG, Walton M. Inequality in Latin America. Breaking with history? World Bank Latin American and Caribbean studies. Washington, DC: World Bank; 2004. De Ferranti D, Perry GE, Ferreira FHG, Walton M. Inequality in Latin America. Breaking with history? World Bank Latin American and Caribbean studies. Washington, DC: World Bank; 2004.
Zurück zum Zitat Prados de la Escosura L. Growth, inequality and poverty in Latin America: historical evidence, controlled conjectures. Working paper in Economic History. 2005. 05–41 (04). Prados de la Escosura L. Growth, inequality and poverty in Latin America: historical evidence, controlled conjectures. Working paper in Economic History. 2005. 05–41 (04).
Zurück zum Zitat De Soto H. The mystery of capital. Why capitalism triumphs in the West and fails everywhere else. New York: Basic Books; 2000. De Soto H. The mystery of capital. Why capitalism triumphs in the West and fails everywhere else. New York: Basic Books; 2000.
Zurück zum Zitat Engerman SL, Sokoloff KL. Factor endowments, institutions, and differential Paths of Growth among New World Economies: a view from economic historians of the United States. In: Haber S, editor. How Latin America Fell Behind. Essays on the Economic Histories of Brazil and Mexico, 1800–1914. Stanford: Stanford University Press; 1997. p. 260–304. Engerman SL, Sokoloff KL. Factor endowments, institutions, and differential Paths of Growth among New World Economies: a view from economic historians of the United States. In: Haber S, editor. How Latin America Fell Behind. Essays on the Economic Histories of Brazil and Mexico, 1800–1914. Stanford: Stanford University Press; 1997. p. 260–304.
Zurück zum Zitat Engerman SL, Sokoloff KL. Colonialism, inequality and long-run paths of development. NBER working paper 11057. 2005. Engerman SL, Sokoloff KL. Colonialism, inequality and long-run paths of development. NBER working paper 11057. 2005.
Zurück zum Zitat Feenstra RC, Hanson GH. Global production sharing and rising inequality: a survey of trade and wages. In: Choi K, Harrigan J, editors. Handbook of international trade. Malden: Basil Blackwell; 2003. p. 146–85.CrossRef Feenstra RC, Hanson GH. Global production sharing and rising inequality: a survey of trade and wages. In: Choi K, Harrigan J, editors. Handbook of international trade. Malden: Basil Blackwell; 2003. p. 146–85.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ferreira FHG, Litchfield JA. Calm after the storms: income distribution in Chile, 1987–1994. World Bank Policy Research Paper. Washington, DC: World Bank; 1998. Ferreira FHG, Litchfield JA. Calm after the storms: income distribution in Chile, 1987–1994. World Bank Policy Research Paper. Washington, DC: World Bank; 1998.
Zurück zum Zitat Fontagne LG, Mirza D. International trade and rent sharing among developed and developing countries. Econ Model. 2007;24:523–58.CrossRef Fontagne LG, Mirza D. International trade and rent sharing among developed and developing countries. Econ Model. 2007;24:523–58.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Frank V. The elusive goal in democratic Chile: reforming the Pinochet Labor Legislation. Latin American Politics and Society. 2002;44:35–68.CrossRef Frank V. The elusive goal in democratic Chile: reforming the Pinochet Labor Legislation. Latin American Politics and Society. 2002;44:35–68.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Frankema EHP. Comparing the distribution of education across the developing world, 1960–2005: what does the grade enrollment distribution tell about Latin America? Soc Indic Res. 2008;88:437–55.CrossRef Frankema EHP. Comparing the distribution of education across the developing world, 1960–2005: what does the grade enrollment distribution tell about Latin America? Soc Indic Res. 2008;88:437–55.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Frankema EHP. The expansion of mass education in twentieth century Latin America: a global comparative perspective. Revista de Historia Económica. 2009a;27:359–95.CrossRef Frankema EHP. The expansion of mass education in twentieth century Latin America: a global comparative perspective. Revista de Historia Económica. 2009a;27:359–95.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Frankema EHP. Has Latin America always been unequal?: A comparative study of asset and income inequality in the long twentieth century. Boston: Brill; 2009b.CrossRef Frankema EHP. Has Latin America always been unequal?: A comparative study of asset and income inequality in the long twentieth century. Boston: Brill; 2009b.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Frankema EHP. Reconstructing labor income shares in Argentina, Brazil and Mexico, 1870–2000. Revista de Historia Económica. 2010;28:343–74.CrossRef Frankema EHP. Reconstructing labor income shares in Argentina, Brazil and Mexico, 1870–2000. Revista de Historia Económica. 2010;28:343–74.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Frankema EHP, Smits JP. Exploring the historical roots of Eastern Asia’s post-war catch-up growth: a trade perspective, 1906–1999. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy. 2005;10:178–94.CrossRef Frankema EHP, Smits JP. Exploring the historical roots of Eastern Asia’s post-war catch-up growth: a trade perspective, 1906–1999. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy. 2005;10:178–94.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Freeman RB. Are your wages set in Beijing? J Econ Perspect. 1995;9:15–32.CrossRef Freeman RB. Are your wages set in Beijing? J Econ Perspect. 1995;9:15–32.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Galbraith JK, Berner M. Inequality and industrial change. A global view. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2001. Galbraith JK, Berner M. Inequality and industrial change. A global view. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2001.
Zurück zum Zitat Galbraith JK, Kum H. Inequality and economic growth: data comparisons and econometric tests. University of Texas Inequality Project (UTIP) working paper no. 21. 2002. Galbraith JK, Kum H. Inequality and economic growth: data comparisons and econometric tests. University of Texas Inequality Project (UTIP) working paper no. 21. 2002.
Zurück zum Zitat Galiani S, Gerchunoff P. The labor market. In: della Paolera G, Taylor AM, editors. A new economic history of Argentina. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2003. p. 122–69. Galiani S, Gerchunoff P. The labor market. In: della Paolera G, Taylor AM, editors. A new economic history of Argentina. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2003. p. 122–69.
Zurück zum Zitat Galiani S, Porto GG. Trends in Tariff reforms and trends in the structure of wages. SSRN working paper. 2008. Galiani S, Porto GG. Trends in Tariff reforms and trends in the structure of wages. SSRN working paper. 2008.
Zurück zum Zitat Galiani S, Sanguinetti P. The impact of trade liberalizationon wage inequality: evidence from Argentina. J Dev Econ. 2003;72:497–513.CrossRef Galiani S, Sanguinetti P. The impact of trade liberalizationon wage inequality: evidence from Argentina. J Dev Econ. 2003;72:497–513.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Galor O, Zeira J. Income distribution and macroeconomics. Rev Econ Stud. 1993;60:35–52.CrossRef Galor O, Zeira J. Income distribution and macroeconomics. Rev Econ Stud. 1993;60:35–52.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goldin C, Katz L. The origins of technology–skill complementarity. Quarterly J Econ. 1998;113:693–732.CrossRef Goldin C, Katz L. The origins of technology–skill complementarity. Quarterly J Econ. 1998;113:693–732.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Helpman E. The mystery of economic growth. Cambridge: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press; 2004. Helpman E. The mystery of economic growth. Cambridge: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press; 2004.
Zurück zum Zitat Kay C. Asia’s and Latin America’s development in comparative perspective: landlords, peasants and industrialization. ISS working paper series no. 336. 2001. Kay C. Asia’s and Latin America’s development in comparative perspective: landlords, peasants and industrialization. ISS working paper series no. 336. 2001.
Zurück zum Zitat Langoni CG. Distribuição de Renda e Desenvolvimiento Econômico do Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: Editora Expressão e Cultura; 1973. Langoni CG. Distribuição de Renda e Desenvolvimiento Econômico do Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: Editora Expressão e Cultura; 1973.
Zurück zum Zitat Langoni CG. Distribuiçã da Renda: Uma Versão para a Minoria. Pesqui Planej Econ. 1974;4:167–80. Langoni CG. Distribuiçã da Renda: Uma Versão para a Minoria. Pesqui Planej Econ. 1974;4:167–80.
Zurück zum Zitat Levine RM. The history of Brazil. New York: Palgrave Macmillan; 1999. Levine RM. The history of Brazil. New York: Palgrave Macmillan; 1999.
Zurück zum Zitat Levy F, Murnane RJ. US earnings levels and earnings inequality: a review of recent trends and proposed explanations. J Econ Lit. 1992;30:1333–81. Levy F, Murnane RJ. US earnings levels and earnings inequality: a review of recent trends and proposed explanations. J Econ Lit. 1992;30:1333–81.
Zurück zum Zitat Lewis PH. The crisis of Argentine capitalism. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press; 1990. Lewis PH. The crisis of Argentine capitalism. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press; 1990.
Zurück zum Zitat Lindert PH. Growing public. Social spending and economic growth since the eighteenth century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2004.CrossRef Lindert PH. Growing public. Social spending and economic growth since the eighteenth century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2004.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lindert PH. The unequal lag in Latin American schooling since 1900: follow the money. Revista de Historia Económica. 2010;28:375–405.CrossRef Lindert PH. The unequal lag in Latin American schooling since 1900: follow the money. Revista de Historia Económica. 2010;28:375–405.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Londoño JL, Székely M. Persistent poverty and excess inequality: Latin America, 1970–1995. J Appl Econ. 2000;3:93–134. Londoño JL, Székely M. Persistent poverty and excess inequality: Latin America, 1970–1995. J Appl Econ. 2000;3:93–134.
Zurück zum Zitat Macedo RB. A critical review of the relation between the post-1964 wage policy and the worsening of Brazil’s size income distribution in the sixties. Explorations in Economic Research. 1977;4:117–40. Macedo RB. A critical review of the relation between the post-1964 wage policy and the worsening of Brazil’s size income distribution in the sixties. Explorations in Economic Research. 1977;4:117–40.
Zurück zum Zitat Mariscal E, Sokoloff KL. Schooling, suffrage, and inequality in the Americas, 1800–1945. In: Haber S, editor. Political institutions and economic growth in Latin America. Essays in policy, history, and political economy. Stanford: Hoover Institution Press, Stanford University; 2000. p. 159–217. Mariscal E, Sokoloff KL. Schooling, suffrage, and inequality in the Americas, 1800–1945. In: Haber S, editor. Political institutions and economic growth in Latin America. Essays in policy, history, and political economy. Stanford: Hoover Institution Press, Stanford University; 2000. p. 159–217.
Zurück zum Zitat Mookerjee D, Ray D. Persistent inequality. Rev Econ Stud. 2000;70:369–93. Mookerjee D, Ray D. Persistent inequality. Rev Econ Stud. 2000;70:369–93.
Zurück zum Zitat Morley S. The income distribution problem in Latin America and the Caribbean. Santiago de Chile: UN, ECLAC; 2001. Morley S. The income distribution problem in Latin America and the Caribbean. Santiago de Chile: UN, ECLAC; 2001.
Zurück zum Zitat Ocampo JA, Martin J. Globalization and development. A Latin American and Caribbean perspective. Palo Alto: ECLAC, World Bank, Stanford University Press; 2003. Ocampo JA, Martin J. Globalization and development. A Latin American and Caribbean perspective. Palo Alto: ECLAC, World Bank, Stanford University Press; 2003.
Zurück zum Zitat Park YB, Ross D, Sabot R. Educational expansion and the inequality of pay in Brazil and Korea. In: Birdsall N, Sabot R, editors. Opportunity forgone: education in Brazil (Inter-American Development Bank). Washington DC: Johns Hopkins University Press; 1996. p. 267–88. Park YB, Ross D, Sabot R. Educational expansion and the inequality of pay in Brazil and Korea. In: Birdsall N, Sabot R, editors. Opportunity forgone: education in Brazil (Inter-American Development Bank). Washington DC: Johns Hopkins University Press; 1996. p. 267–88.
Zurück zum Zitat Perry G, Olarreaga M. Trade liberalization, inequality and poverty reduction in Latin America. Paper presented at ABCDE, St. Petersburg. 2006. Perry G, Olarreaga M. Trade liberalization, inequality and poverty reduction in Latin America. Paper presented at ABCDE, St. Petersburg. 2006.
Zurück zum Zitat Phelps Brown H, Hopkins SV. Seven centuries of the price of consumables, compared with builders’ wage rates. Economica. 1957;23:296–314.CrossRef Phelps Brown H, Hopkins SV. Seven centuries of the price of consumables, compared with builders’ wage rates. Economica. 1957;23:296–314.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Piketty T, Saez E. The evolution of top incomes: a historical and international perspective. NBER working paper 11955. 2006. Piketty T, Saez E. The evolution of top incomes: a historical and international perspective. NBER working paper 11955. 2006.
Zurück zum Zitat Psacharopoulos G, Morley S, Fiszbein A, Lee H, Wood B. Poverty and income distribution in Latin America. The story of the 1980s. World Bank technical paper no. 351. Washington DC: World Bank; 1997. Psacharopoulos G, Morley S, Fiszbein A, Lee H, Wood B. Poverty and income distribution in Latin America. The story of the 1980s. World Bank technical paper no. 351. Washington DC: World Bank; 1997.
Zurück zum Zitat Richardson JD. Income inequality and trade: how to think, what to conclude. J Econ Perspect. 1995;9:33–55.CrossRef Richardson JD. Income inequality and trade: how to think, what to conclude. J Econ Perspect. 1995;9:33–55.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rock D. Argentina 1516–1987. From Spanish colonization to Alfonsín. Berkeley: University of California Press; 1987. Rock D. Argentina 1516–1987. From Spanish colonization to Alfonsín. Berkeley: University of California Press; 1987.
Zurück zum Zitat Romero LA. A history of Argentina in the twentieth century. Philadelphia: Pennsylvania State University; 2002. Romero LA. A history of Argentina in the twentieth century. Philadelphia: Pennsylvania State University; 2002.
Zurück zum Zitat Székely M, Montes A. Poverty and inequality. In: Bulmer-Thomas V, Coatsworth JH, Cortés Conde R, editors. The Cambridge economic history of Latin America. Volume II: the long twentieth century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2006. p. 585–645. Székely M, Montes A. Poverty and inequality. In: Bulmer-Thomas V, Coatsworth JH, Cortés Conde R, editors. The Cambridge economic history of Latin America. Volume II: the long twentieth century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2006. p. 585–645.
Zurück zum Zitat Theil H. Economics and information theory. Amsterdam: North-Holland; 1967. Theil H. Economics and information theory. Amsterdam: North-Holland; 1967.
Zurück zum Zitat Theil H. Statistical decomposition analysis: with applications in the social and administrative sciences. Amsterdam: North-Holland; 1972. Theil H. Statistical decomposition analysis: with applications in the social and administrative sciences. Amsterdam: North-Holland; 1972.
Zurück zum Zitat Thorp R. Progress, poverty and exclusion. An economic history of Latin America in the twentieth century. Inter-American Development Bank. New York: The Johns Hopkins University Press; 1998. Thorp R. Progress, poverty and exclusion. An economic history of Latin America in the twentieth century. Inter-American Development Bank. New York: The Johns Hopkins University Press; 1998.
Zurück zum Zitat Waisgras S. Wage inequality and the labor market in Argentina: labor institutions, supply and demand in the period 1980–99. International Institute for Labor Studies discussion paper no. 146. 2003. Waisgras S. Wage inequality and the labor market in Argentina: labor institutions, supply and demand in the period 1980–99. International Institute for Labor Studies discussion paper no. 146. 2003.
Zurück zum Zitat Wegenast T. Of Latifundia and Coronéis: Agrarian structure and educational inequalities in Brazil. Working paper presented at the Mini-Conference “A Comparative Approach to Inequality and Development: Latin America and Europe”. 8–9 May, 2009. Madrid. 2009. Wegenast T. Of Latifundia and Coronéis: Agrarian structure and educational inequalities in Brazil. Working paper presented at the Mini-Conference “A Comparative Approach to Inequality and Development: Latin America and Europe”. 8–9 May, 2009. Madrid. 2009.
Zurück zum Zitat Wells J, Drobny A. A Distribuiçã de Renda e o Salario Mínimo no Brasil: Uma Revisão Crítica da Literatura Exsitente. Pesquisa e Planejameto Econômico 12. 1982. Wells J, Drobny A. A Distribuiçã de Renda e o Salario Mínimo no Brasil: Uma Revisão Crítica da Literatura Exsitente. Pesquisa e Planejameto Econômico 12. 1982.
Zurück zum Zitat Williamson JG. Real wages, inequality and globalization in Latin America before 1940. Revista de Historia Económica. 1999;17:101–42.CrossRef Williamson JG. Real wages, inequality and globalization in Latin America before 1940. Revista de Historia Económica. 1999;17:101–42.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Williamson JG. Land, labor and globalization in the Third World 1870–1940. J Econ Hist. 2002;62:55–85. Williamson JG. Land, labor and globalization in the Third World 1870–1940. J Econ Hist. 2002;62:55–85.
Zurück zum Zitat Wood A. North-south trade. Employment and inequality. Changing fortunes in a skill-driven world. Oxford: Clarendon; 1994. Wood A. North-south trade. Employment and inequality. Changing fortunes in a skill-driven world. Oxford: Clarendon; 1994.
Zurück zum Zitat Wright TC. Landowners and reform in Chile. The Sociedad Nacional de Agricultura. Urbana: Univeristy of Illinois Press; 1982. p. 1919–40. Wright TC. Landowners and reform in Chile. The Sociedad Nacional de Agricultura. Urbana: Univeristy of Illinois Press; 1982. p. 1919–40.
Metadaten
Titel
Industrial Wage Inequality in Latin America in Global Perspective, 1900–2000
verfasst von
Ewout Frankema
Publikationsdatum
01.03.2012
Verlag
Springer-Verlag
Erschienen in
Studies in Comparative International Development / Ausgabe 1/2012
Print ISSN: 0039-3606
Elektronische ISSN: 1936-6167
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-011-9091-2

Premium Partner