Skip to main content

1997 | Buch

Normal Prices, Technical Change and Accumulation

verfasst von: Bertram Schefold

Verlag: Palgrave Macmillan UK

Buchreihe : Studies in Political Economy

insite
SUCHEN

Über dieses Buch

This book presents the most significant theoretical articles by Bertram Schefold to illuminate the development and the present state of modern classical theory. It assembles twenty heavily discussed papers on joint production and fixed capital, choice of technique and technical progress, composition of output and the relation between classical, neoclassical and keynesian economics. There is a broad new introduction. The chapter on the critique of intertemporal general equilibrium is novel and represents an original theoretical advance.

Inhaltsverzeichnis

Frontmatter

Introduction: Sraffa’s Theory Today

1. Introduction: Sraffa’s Theory Today
Abstract
‘Piero Sraffa was one of the greatest economists of this century’, wrote P.A. Samuelson, one of Sraffa’s greatest critics, in his obituary in the Italian newspaper Corriere della Sera. Anyone who is familiar with the very large literature on capital theory, in which Sraffa’s name is most prominent, and has seen the possibly still larger literature on Sraffa’s own theory, with books, articles and comments written in many languages, might be very surprised to hear, if he had not yet been told, how modest and unpretentious Sraffa was. Friendly, with shining eyes, he was always prepared to engage in a discussion when students met him walking in the backs of Trinity College.
Bertram Schefold

General Properties of Single and Joint Production Systems

Frontmatter
2. Multiple Product Techniques with Properties of Single Product Systems
Abstract
In the context of Sraffa systems most economists tend to avoid joint production and prefer to discuss single product systems because of their simple and elegant properties which have often been represented under the familiar headings of activity analysis or linear economic systems outside the circle of the Sraffa school. It is true that joint production raises a number of intricate problems; no straightforward economic assumptions are known which could be made to ensure that prices in joint production systems are positive at a given rate of profit prior to truncation, the distinction between basics and non-basics is not easily maintained in the presence of joint production, etc. Sraffa (1960) has hinted at many of the problems involved. I believe, however, that it is possible to characterise those instances of joint production systems which retain some of the simple properties of single product systems, to distinguish them analytically from those with more paradoxical properties and to relate the paradoxes appearing in the theoretical model to obstacles to the competitive formation of prices in the real world.
Bertram Schefold
3. Relative Prices as a Function of the Rate of Profit: A Mathematical Note
Abstract
The reswitching debate has made it obvious that prices are in general complicated functions of the rate of profit in single product systems of the Sraffa type (Sraffa, 1960):
Bertram Schefold
4. The Standard Commodity as a Tool of Economic Analysis
Abstract
Sraffa, in his Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities (Sraffa, 1960), intended to achieve two purposes: to lay the foundation for a critique of neoclassical theory and to prepare for a return to the classical theory of accumulation by providing a modern formulation of a classical theory of value. He showed that prices are determined and vary in function of the rate of profit, if the quantities to be produced are given with the technology in use. On the one hand, the variations in the total value of capital goods so induced are incompatible with traditional views of a determination of distribution and employment through supply and demand for capital as a factor of production. On the other hand, room was made for a determination of the levels of output and employment, and of distribution, through non-neoclassical theories. As a matter of fact, a given real wage rate had been the key to the explanation of distribution in the Ricardian system (with profits being a residual in the surplus after the payment of rents), and with the level of accumulation reached in any period determining the number of workers then to be employed. The theory of distribution (Pivetti, 1985), of the level of output (effective demand, Garegnani, 1964/5) and of its composition (Chapter 14 in this volume) would have to be rather different under modern circumstances; the reconstruction of classical theory therefore remains a laborious task.
Bertram Schefold

The Dominant Technique

Frontmatter
5. On Counting Equations
Abstract
Productive Sraffa joint production systems are known to possess a number of properties which appear to be counterintuitive, if contrasted with single product systems: prices may fluctuate even if expressed in terms of the wage rate, they may turn negative, the standard commodity may not exist, etc. If joint production is, by contrast, approached in terms of inequalities (von Neumann’s method), positive prices and a tradeoff between real wages and the rate of profit obtain but the solution will in general not allow the activation of all processes, some commodities are overproduced and the resulting system of commodities with positive prices in activated processes need not be ‘quadratic’, i.e. the number of positive activity levels need not be equal to the number of positive prices in an optimal solution.
Bertram Schefold
6. Von Neumann and Sraffa: Mathematical Equivalence and Conceptual Difference
Abstract
In this chapter I compare Sraffa’s and von Neumann’s methods for the analysis of joint production systems from the point of view of economic methodology; a parallel article gives the mathematical background with complete proofs but without the interpretation proposed here (see Chapter 5 in this volume and the summary of mathematical definitions and results in the Appendix).
Bertram Schefold
7. The Dominant Technique in Joint Production Systems
Abstract
There was very little discussion of Sraffa’s theory of joint production during the first ten years after the publication of Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities (Sraffa, 1960) because attempts to understand his theory of single product systems and the critique of the dominant theory of capital absorbed all attention. Thereafter, the theory of joint production came increasingly into focus. One reason, little understood at first, was that for the first time Sraffa’s approach provided economists working in the classical tradition with the possibility of defining prices of production in the presence of multiple product industries. When I wrote my ‘Mr Sraffa on Joint Production’ in 1970, Luigi Pasinetti drew my attention to the famous passage in Jevons ([1871] 1957) in which he invokes joint production to prove that a classical cost of production theory — as he understood it — could not explain the relative prices of by-products. A little later, Sraffa’s solution to the explanation of relative prices was used by Steedman to criticise Marx’s form of the labour theory of value (Steedman, 1975).
Bertram Schefold
8. Joint Production: A Further Assessment
Abstract
As is well known, the classical theory of value would still be stuck in an impasse without Sraffa’s theory of joint production, because the authors of the 19th and early 20th century saw no possibility of providing a general explanation for the pricing of the outputs of multiple product industries without having recourse to the subjective theory of preferences, as the early mariginalists did. The solution was very elegant and agreed with the new approach, which superseded the Ricardian and Marxian idea of explaining prices of production as modified labour values, by having direct recourse to the structure of production and consumption. The structure was expressed in the form of an input-output system, with given output levels, so that prices could be calculated for single product industry systems, given the rate of profit, as being equal to the normal cost of production. The extension to joint production systems then followed from the simple consideration that the production of a given vector of commodities as (gross or net) outputs (the ‘requirements for use’) is generically possible — if there is some variability in the scale at which processes may be run — only if there are at least as many processes used as there are commodities to be produced. Hence there will be enough processes in use to determine prices, and if the rate of profit is to be uniform, the number of processes cannot exceed that of commodities; otherwise, prices would be overdetermined. The system therefore is ‘square’.
Bertram Schefold

Fixed Capital and Technical Progress

Frontmatter
9. Fixed Capital as a Joint Product
Abstract
Since the Reswitching Debate the point has become familiar that the means of production in a capitalist society represent different ‘quantities of capital’ depending on the prevailing rate of profit. But because these discussions were about a critique of the neoclassical theory of value and distribution and not about a new comprehensive theory of capital, they have been conducted either in terms of circulating capital without machines or in terms of production by means of one machine at different ages (cf. Hicks, 1970, Nuti, 1970). Although von Neumann and Sraffa revived the ‘old classical idea’ (Sraffa) of treating what is left at the end of the year’s process of production as an economically different good from the one which entered the process, very few1 have tried to construct models with several fixed capital goods which are explicitly distinguished from other kinds of joint products.
Bertram Schefold
10. Reduction to Dated Quantities of Labour, Roundabout Processes and Switches of Technique in Fixed Capital Systems
Abstract
This chapter examines a formal simplification of fixed capital systems of the Sraffa type1 by means of an extension of the reduction to dated quantities of labour. The reduction will be used to discuss particular types of switches of techniques which arise only in the context of fixed capital systems.
Bertram Schefold
11. Different Forms of Technical Progress
Abstract
The classics, Smith and Ricardo, used their theory of value to base their theories of accumulation, technical progress, and the long-term trend of distribution on the analysis of the technological development in specified industries such as textiles, corn production, watch-making, etc. Marx undertook vast studies of the history of technology and related it to the evolution of the productive relations. The chapters on cooperation, the division of labour, and on modern industry in Das Kapital are the best known distillates of that research, and they link up with his theory of accumulation. The modern neoclassicals, on the other hand, tend to separate their microeconomic theory of value — be it at the level of firms or of industries — from the macroeconomic theory of accumulation. The static character of much general equilibrium theory has prevented its use for an analysis of technical progress — hence the need for aggregate production functions in neoclassical economics for the analysis of accumulation. This dichotomy of the theory of value and of the theory of accumulation is unfortunate, all the more so since the foundations of neoclassical macroeconomics have been undermined in the reswitching debate.
Bertram Schefold
12. Capital, Growth and Definitions of Technical Progress
Abstract
There is a silent conflict between theories of growth which tend — with notable exceptions — to describe smooth evolutions in growth processes based on neutral technical progress, and capital theory which emphasises the potentially radically different features of alternative techniques in static comparisons. Capital theory has shaken the neoclassical theory of growth by discrediting the construction of the surrogate production function but I shall attempt to show here briefly that capital theory in its full abstract generality is incompatible with any reasonable theory of growth and progress so that progress must be represented on the basis of more concrete specifications if any notion of steady growth and of regular increases of productivity is to be retained.
Bertram Schefold

The Composition of Output

Frontmatter
13. Sraffa and Applied Economics: Joint Production
Abstract
Is there a field of application for Sraffa’s theory? There can be no doubt that Sraffa’s work has so far almost exclusively been interpreted as a critique of the theory of value. As a consequence of discussions which were decisively influenced by Sraffa, the economic profession has in the last 15 years begun to accept the fact that the aggregate production function is an illegitimate tool of analysis. Wider implications for the neoclassical school are still being debated. Within the classical approach, the traditional form of the labour theory of value was superseded. But the empirical applications were few; they really consist only of some attempts to calculate wage curves. These attempts were necessarily inconclusive as far as the debate about capital theory was concerned while they did shed some light on the analysis of technical progress.2
Bertram Schefold
14. On Changes in the Composition of Output
Abstract
It has often been remarked that ‘demand’ is missing from the Sraffa system. If the level and composition of output change, the input-output coefficients change so that there seems to be no room for a consideration of demand. If, on the other hand, distribution is given and there are constant returns to scale, prices are determined independently of the levels of output in the different sectors. It would then seem that demand conditions can be freely introduced, but they only fix the quantities. The latter case can clearly only serve as an introduction; yet it is regarded as the main case by neoclassical interpreters.
Bertram Schefold

Relations between Classical, Neoclassical and Keynesian Theories

Frontmatter
15. Joint Production, Intertemporal Preferences and Long-period Equilibrium
Abstract
Bidard’s stimulating paper (Bidard, 1990b) raises a number of important questions on two levels: 1. the scope and extent of Sraffa’s critique of neoclassical theory, 2. the further development of classical theory. It had always been clear that the researcher at both these levels would influence each other because of the common concern with long-period equilibrium. Intertemporal models seemed to represent a different ‘Walrasian’ world — neither truly short-term nor long-term in the Marshallian sense. Bidard now declares that he belongs to the crowd of those who proclaim that Sraffa’s critique does not apply to the intertemporal models, and that ‘classical dynamics’ should be used to overcome the ‘steady state’ character of classical analysis.
Bertram Schefold
16. The Market and the Classical Theory of Prices
Abstract
During the last decades, a tentative revival of the classical theory of prices has been observed. It originated from diverse sources. The broad social outlook, the theoretical coherence and the political impetus of the classical authors had never lost its fascination for economists but some distinctive traits of their analysis had been obscured by attempts to minimise the fundamental difference between the classical approach, based on the surplus principle, and the neoclassical one, based on the idea that supply and demand for factors of production, as governed by subjective preferences, regulate an equilibrium at full employment. Keynes had used the neoclassical theory of value and generalised the equilibrium concept to encompass labour unemployment. This led, in the age of growth theory, to a reconsideration of the classical processes of accumulation, as revived by Harrod and the followers of Keynes in Cambridge, who considered classical paths of accumulation where the growth of capacity did not automatically adjust through the supply and demand mechanism to the growth of the labour supply and productivity.
Bertram Schefold
17. On the Classical and Marshallian Foundations of Keynesian and Post-Keynesian Economics
Abstract
In this chapter I want to reconsider the microeconomic foundations of Keynes’s theory of effective demand as described in Chapter 3 of The General Theory. Athanasios Asimakopulos has dedicated an important article to this subject, focusing on the Marshallian construction of the supply curve and on procedures of aggregation.1 I want to adopt a wider perspective in order to allow a comparison by means of a simple model between rival proposals for the microeconomic foundation of macroeconomics.
Bertram Schefold
18. Classical Theory and Intertemporal Equilibrium
Abstract
Sraffa’s book contributed to a critique of neoclassical theory and to a reconstruction of the classical approach. Three phases in its discussion may be distinguished: In a first, single product systems were analysed and the famous debate on the existence of the production function, the possibility of aggregating capital and the validity of the neoclassical theory of distribution took place. Afterwards, the importance of joint production was discovered while the critique of economic thought turned against Marx. During the 1980s, the analysis of processes of gravitation was begun and, on the level of the critique, Hahn’s challenge was taken up who had asserted that Sraffa’s model was but a special case of neoclassical equilibrium. Duménil and Lévy1 showed that the equilibrium of classical theory, characterised by the uniformity of the rate of profit, constituted a norm for the neoclassical theory as well. For the intertemporal equilibrium, which is representative of modern neoclassical thinking, tends in normal conditions towards a long-period position, with a rate of profit both unique and uniform.
Bertram Schefold
19. Schumpeter as a Walrasian Austrian and Keynes as a Classical Marshallian
Abstract
‘Schumpeter and Keynes were two outstanding economists of their time. Neither felt that there was much room for the other.’ I am grateful to J.K. Galbraith for this characterisation of the two persons whom we celebrate (in 1983); in fact, their theories seem to exclude each other as much as the policies they advocated. Keynesianism represented a provocative challenge for the more traditional — though in his own way also unorthodox — Schumpeter. In order to learn as much as possible from the opposition, it seems appropriate to take the less well-known Schumpeterian view and his system as our our point of departure.
Bertram Schefold
20. Ecological Problems as a Challenge to Classical and Keynesian Economics
Abstract
Special ecological problems such as that of man’s influence on the productivity of land are an old theme in economics. A brilliant early and systematic account of the consequences of environmental disruption for modern society was given in K.W. Kapp’s The Social Costs of Private Enterprise (1950). However, the suspicion that the exhaustion of raw materials and the main energy carriers (hydrocarbons) might set definitive limits to growth reached world prominence only with the report of the Club of Rome (Meadows et al, 1972). The model of the Club of Rome formalised in a way impressive to the layman (and suspicious to the specialist) what had seemed obvious to a small number of observers before and seems plausible to a great many today, namely that the resource constraint (or the constraints arising from environmental pollution) will, even if population does not grow indefinitely, eventually force a reversal of the present trend of a general average rise in the standard of living in the world as a whole and, in particular, in industrialised countries.
Bertram Schefold
Backmatter
Metadaten
Titel
Normal Prices, Technical Change and Accumulation
verfasst von
Bertram Schefold
Copyright-Jahr
1997
Verlag
Palgrave Macmillan UK
Electronic ISBN
978-0-230-37240-5
Print ISBN
978-1-349-39302-2
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1057/9780230372405