Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Political Behavior 2/2008

01.06.2008 | Original Paper

Reaching Out or Pulling Back: Macroeconomic Conditions and Public Support for Social Welfare Spending

verfasst von: Cindy D. Kam, Yunju Nam

Erschienen in: Political Behavior | Ausgabe 2/2008

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In economic hard-times, do Americans call for increases in governmental assistance, or do they clamor for declines in government assistance? We address this question by identifying the impact of state-level macroeconomic conditions on public support for social welfare spending. We analyze individual-level data from the 1984–2000 National Election Studies, combined with state-level macroeconomic indicators of inflation, unemployment, and productivity. We find that state-level inflation, not state-level unemployment nor state-level productivity, consistently and consequentially shapes citizens’ support for social welfare. With rising inflation, Americans become more supportive of means-tested social welfare spending. Our analyses generally reaffirm the value Americans place on the social welfare safety net, especially during times of economic duress. When the going gets tough, Americans reach out, rather than pull back.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
Social Security Administration. 2007. Statistical supplement to the Social Security bulletin, 2006. http://​www.​ssa.​gov/​policy/​docs/​statcomps/​supplement/​2006/​supplement06.​pdf
 
3
Such a focus is not unique. While some scholars who study attitudes towards the social welfare state take a more general view, analyzing attitudes towards government spending on services generally or in the government’s role in guaranteeing jobs and a good standard of living (e.g., Berinsky 2002; Feldman and Zaller 1992; Jacoby 2000), many others focus primarily on programs for the poor (e.g., Feldman and Steenbergen 2001; Gilens 1999; Jacoby 1994; Schneider and Jacoby 2005; Smith 1987). Further, some research has identified clear differences in the underpinnings of Americans’ views on programs representing these various categories (e.g., Cook and Barrett 1992; Kam and Kinder 1999; Winter 2006).
 
4
This would not necessarily be the case for programs that include an explicit cost-of-living adjustment mechanism. Such a mechanism is in place for Social Security but not for several other social welfare assistance programs such as AFDC/TANF and Food Stamps.
 
5
An extension of this argument would suggest that citizens would respond to inflationary pressures generally: they would call for increased spending across the board, not just on social welfare policies. We address this possibility below.
 
6
The NES, at various points in time, has included other specific mentions that are relevant to social welfare policy, including assistance to the poor, unemployment assistance, and assistance to the homeless. We have not used these measures because they were included in limited years or were asked with inconsistent wording. The Welfare Programs item is available in the 1992, 1994, 1996, and 2000 and the Food Stamps item is available biennially from 1984–1996 and in 2000.
 
7
This statement uses average opinion on Food Stamps and on Welfare Programs. Spending on reducing crime, public schools, Social Security, AIDS research, child care, protecting the environment, financial aid for students, space exploration, and even spending on blacks all garnered more support than Food Stamps and Welfare Programs.
 
8
Jacoby (1994) combines spending on “assisting blacks,” “food stamps,” “Medicaid,” “unemployment compensation,” and “Social Security” into a social welfare scale. These specific program attitudes are used to predict general attitudes towards government spending (the services and spending item). Jacoby (2000) uses seven of the federal spending items (homeless, poor people, child care, unemployed, assisting blacks, food stamps, and welfare programs) to form a scale of social welfare spending preferences (note that social security is not included in this analysis); these social welfare preferences are contrasted with the more general services and spending item, which, Jacoby characterizes as “a general and nonspecific presentation of the [government] spending issue” (p. 753, FN 3). Feldman and Zaller (1992) analyze the services and spending item and the guaranteed jobs item, noting that these items have been “the primary NES social welfare issue items for the last decade” (p. 276, FN 5). Furthermore, they argue that these items relate well to other questions on “domestic spending priorities” and “general attitudes toward economic equality and redistribution” (p. 276, FN 5). Finally, the items have the virtue of containing the open-ended probes that form the core of the contribution of the article.
 
9
The correlations between the four items appear in the Appendix.
 
10
Family budget data “tally the cost of food, housing, transportation, clothing, personal items, medical care, and taxes for an urban family of four” (Berry et al. 2000, p. 552). We use Berry, Fording and Hanson’s data instead of the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ Consumer Price Index (CPI) because the BLS CPI provides only regional, rather than state-level, information.
 
11
In a departure from previous work, we also included inflation in both its raw and its quadratic form. The two theoretical arguments we address suggest either a positive relationship between good macroeconomic conditions and public support for social welfare (the procyclical pattern) or a negative relationship between good macroeconomic conditions and public support for social welfare (the countercyclical pattern). We added a layer of complexity to these statements in arguing that the relationship between macroeconomic conditions and public support for social welfare might be better modeled using a quadratic, because the marginal effect of changes in macroeconomic conditions might depend upon the level of macroeconomic conditions. Inclusion of a quadratic allows us to identify whether the effect of inflation on social welfare policy is monotonically increasing or monotonically decreasing, or whether it is nonmonotonic (that is, if the effect is positive up to some point and negative thereafter). This specification also allows us to examine whether the effect of inflation on support for social welfare spending varies with the level of inflation itself. This quadratic specification is especially appropriate for the indicator of inflation, as target levels of inflation (e.g., in countries such as the United Kingdom, Canada, and New Zealand (Bernanke and Mishkin 1997) and endorsed by U.S. Federal Reserve Board Chairman Ben Bernanke (Geewax 2005)) suggest that interpretation of inflation levels with respect to “good” or “bad” macroeconomic conditions is not unidirectional. Instead, too low or too high levels of inflation may be undesirable, as low inflation rates may destabilize the economy (Delong 2000; Reifschneider and Williams 2000; Saunders 2000). A one-unit shift in inflation, say from 1% to 2%, may have a different effect on support for social welfare policy compared with a one-unit shift in inflation from 4% to 5%. Inclusion of the quadratic permits the size and direction of the effect of inflation on support for social welfare policy to vary with the level of inflation. The estimated coefficient for the quadratic term was not significantly different from zero in either model; hence we include a linear specification.
 
12
We also examined the effects of unemployment at its lagged level, as a raw change between the current and previous year, and as a percentage change between the current and previous year. The effect of unemployment was indistinguishable from zero in each of these specifications. On the same idea that the effect of changes in unemployment may be conditional upon the level of unemployment, we included a quadratic here as well. In all models, the quadratic term on unemployment never obtained statistical significance and was substantively tiny.
 
13
We also examined the effects of GSP at its current level, its lagged level, and as a raw change between the current and previous year. The effect of GSP was indistinguishable from zero in each of these specifications.
 
14
Within the time frame analyzed, the correlation between state-level inflation and state-level unemployment was −0.32, the correlation between state-level inflation and change in per capita GSP was 0.043, and the correlation between state-level unemployment and change in per capita GSP was −0.009.
 
15
Support for social welfare ranges from 0 (conservative) to 1 (liberal). The datapoints refer to the year-state averages across both indicators (i.e., the average opinion on Welfare Programs, within a state for a given year, combined with the average opinion on Food Stamps within the same year and state). When only one indicator is available, the dot represents the year-state average for the one indicator.
 
16
The reader may notice a few outlying observations in our state-level data. Results run without the outlying observations on inflation (California respondents in 1990) are nearly identical. Results run without the outlying observations on unemployment (West Virginia in 1984, 1986, and 1992; Louisiana in 1986; Alabama in 1984; and Michigan in 1984) were substantively similar.
 
17
We conceptualize economic interests as falling into the following 2 × 2 matrix:
 
Objective indicators
Subjective indicators
Self/Household (Pocketbook)
Income, work status, program receipt
Evaluations of how the respondent or respondent’s household has been or will be doing
Beyond the Self/Contextual (Sociotropic)
Inflation, unemployment, productivity
Evaluations of how the state/nation/group has been or will be doing
A considerable literature has examined pocketbook versus sociotropic determinants of electoral behavior (e.g., Kinder and Kiewiet 1979, 1981), using both objective and subjective indicators (see Lewis-Beck and Stegmaier 2000 for a review).
 
18
The disabled (3% of the sample) often receive Supplemental Security Income (SSI) and benefits from the Social Security Disability Insurance; they are excluded from analysis.
 
19
Note that the use of sociotropic information does not mean that individuals are altruistic: “The distinction between pocketbook and sociotropic politics is not equivalent to the distinction between a self-interested and an altruistic politics” (Kinder and Kiewiet 1981, p. 132). It simply means that contextual information about the state of the economy shapes political judgments.
 
20
We estimate each of our models with ordered probit, since the dependent variables are ordered categorical indicators. We include yearly fixed effects to allow for intercept differences across years, attributable to factors that we do not explicitly control in our model (such as political discourse, i.e., in the Welfare Reform era). We include regional dummies to capture time-invariant regional differences in the political culture surrounding social welfare policy. We are not able to include state-fixed effects due to the paucity of respondents from some states. These relationships could be modeled using hierarchical modeling or random effects models that attribute shared variance to individuals nested within states. We deal with this shared variance using robust standard error adjustments, clustering by year-state, which produce results that are quite similar to those produced using hierarchical techniques (Kam and Franzese 2007).
 
21
The predicted probabilities, based on the combined model, are graphed setting values to their means (or modes for categorical variables).
 
22
Note that this sociotropic measure is suboptimal, since we believe that most of the action occurs at the state-level. The NES only included a state-level economic assessments item in the 1992 survey.
 
23
Tables 3 and 4 provide results from ordered probit models, where respondents who reported “Don’t Know” or “Haven’t Thought About It” are set to the midpoint. We also estimated the models with selection equations, following Berinsky (2002). Our estimates of the (null) effect of state-level economic conditions remained unchanged. We also extended the time-period of our analysis. For the Guaranteed Jobs item, this meant that we went back to 1976; for the Services and Spending item, this meant that we went back to 1982. In so doing, we had to omit egalitarianism from the models (but since egalitarianism and the state-level economic indicators are not correlated, this should not have biased the estimated coefficients on the state-level economic conditions). The results were similar: null results for each of the state-level economic indicators.
 
24
These statistically insignificant coefficients could be attributable to collinearity between the multiple interaction terms. So, we estimated models with an interaction between black affect and only one of the macroeconomic indicators. The results were similar to those reported in Tables 5 and 6: a negative (but insignificant) interaction between feelings towards blacks and inflation appears when it comes to spending on Welfare and a positive but significant interaction between feelings towards blacks and inflation when it comes to spending on Food Stamps. The other interactions were insignificant. Finally, as a more direct test of whether changes in the composition of welfare recipients was responsible for more supportive views of welfare spending, we included several measures directly relating to the race of welfare recipients (e.g., the raw percentage of welfare recipients who were black; changes in the percentage of welfare recipients who were black). None of these were significantly related to support for Welfare Programs or Food Stamps.
 
25
In these models, Income is a trichotomous variable indicating low, middle, and high, corresponding to thirds in the income distribution.
 
26
Gilens’ analysis consists of an autoregressive (AR(1)) model, with a dummy included for the period between 1983 and 1988, in which there was an anomalous period of GDP growth. GDP is not analyzed alongside other macroeconomic indicators (unemployment or inflation) and no explicit justification is given for analyzing GDP instead of the other indicators.
 
27
Aggregate public opinion measures result from combining General Social Surveys, Roper polls, and two Consumer Attitudes and Behavior surveys. Like Gilens, Kluegel uses an AR(1) model to estimate the relationship.
 
28
We also analyzed the effects of national economic conditions—inflation, unemployment, and change in per capita gross domestic product. These analyses are a bit perilous, given the relatively few years that are available for analysis, and given the high degree of collinearity between the indicators. One of the symptoms of high collinearity is unstable coefficient estimates—especially estimates that change signs across models. We found that to be the case in our estimates. Hence, here are the estimates from the models where each economic indicator appears on its own. Notice that inflation is the only one that has a consistently positive effect, consistent with our state-level story. Unemployment rates have a negative relationship to Welfare Programs and a positive relationship for Food Stamps. The effect of productivity is significant but shifts direction: greater productivity is associated with less support for Welfare Programs (that is, the worse things are, the more support there is), but greater productivity is also associated with more support of Food Stamps.
 
Welfare Programs
Food Stamps
Inflation only
0.278**
0.038*
0.076
0.017
Unemployment only
−0.002
0.067**
0.021
0.014
Per capita change in
−0.171**
0.033**
GDP only
0.060
0.008
Note: * p < 0.05; ** p < 0.01, two-tailed. Ordered probit coefficients with standard errors below
Robust standard errors adjusted for year-state clustering. Models control for all state-level economic indicators and all individual-level covariates featured in Tables 1 and 2
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Alesina, A., & Ferraraz, E. L. (2001) Preferences for redistribution in the land of opportunities. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 8267, Cambridge, MA Alesina, A., & Ferraraz, E. L. (2001) Preferences for redistribution in the land of opportunities. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 8267, Cambridge, MA
Zurück zum Zitat Axinn, J., & Stern, M. J. (2005) Social welfare: A history of the American response to need (6th ed). Boston: Allyn & Bacon. Axinn, J., & Stern, M. J. (2005) Social welfare: A history of the American response to need (6th ed). Boston: Allyn & Bacon.
Zurück zum Zitat Berinsky, A. J. (2002). Silent voices: Social welfare policy opinions and political equality in America. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 276–287.CrossRef Berinsky, A. J. (2002). Silent voices: Social welfare policy opinions and political equality in America. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 276–287.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bernanke, B. S., & Mishkin, F. S. (1997). Inflation targeting: A new framework for monetary policy? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11, 97–116. Bernanke, B. S., & Mishkin, F. S. (1997). Inflation targeting: A new framework for monetary policy? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11, 97–116.
Zurück zum Zitat Berry, W. D., Fording, R. C., & Hanson, R. L. (2000) An annual cost of living index for the American states, 1960–1995. Journal of Politics, 62, 550–567.CrossRef Berry, W. D., Fording, R. C., & Hanson, R. L. (2000) An annual cost of living index for the American states, 1960–1995. Journal of Politics, 62, 550–567.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berry, W. D., Fording, R. C., & Hanson, R. L. (2005). Cost of living index for the American states, 1960–2003 [Computer file] (Study #1275). ICPSR version. Ann Arbor: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor]. Berry, W. D., Fording, R. C., & Hanson, R. L. (2005). Cost of living index for the American states, 1960–2003 [Computer file] (Study #1275). ICPSR version. Ann Arbor: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor].
Zurück zum Zitat Burtless, G. (1994). Public spending on the poor: Historical trends and economic limits. In: S. H. Danziger, G. D. Sandefur, & D. H. Weinberg (Eds.), Confronting poverty: Prescriptions for change. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Burtless, G. (1994). Public spending on the poor: Historical trends and economic limits. In: S. H. Danziger, G. D. Sandefur, & D. H. Weinberg (Eds.), Confronting poverty: Prescriptions for change. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Conover, P. J., Feldman, S., & Knight, K. (1986). Judging inflation and unemployment: The origins of retrospective evaluations. Journal of Politics, 48, 565–588.CrossRef Conover, P. J., Feldman, S., & Knight, K. (1986). Judging inflation and unemployment: The origins of retrospective evaluations. Journal of Politics, 48, 565–588.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cook, F. L., & Barrett, E. J. (1992). Support for the American welfare state. New York: Columbia. Cook, F. L., & Barrett, E. J. (1992). Support for the American welfare state. New York: Columbia.
Zurück zum Zitat Delong, J. B. (2000). America’s historical experience with low inflation. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 32, 979–993.CrossRef Delong, J. B. (2000). America’s historical experience with low inflation. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 32, 979–993.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Durr, R. H. (1993). What moves policy sentiment? American Political Science Review, 87, 158–170.CrossRef Durr, R. H. (1993). What moves policy sentiment? American Political Science Review, 87, 158–170.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ellwood, D. (1988). Poor support: Poverty in the American family. New York: Basic Books. Ellwood, D. (1988). Poor support: Poverty in the American family. New York: Basic Books.
Zurück zum Zitat Erikson, R. S., MacKuen, M. B., & Stimson, J. A. (2002). The macro polity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Erikson, R. S., MacKuen, M. B., & Stimson, J. A. (2002). The macro polity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Feldman, S. (1988). Structure and consistency in public opinion: The role of core beliefs and values. American Journal of Political Science, 32, 416–440.CrossRef Feldman, S. (1988). Structure and consistency in public opinion: The role of core beliefs and values. American Journal of Political Science, 32, 416–440.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Feldman, S., & Steenbergen, M. (2001). The humanitarian foundation of public support for social welfare. American Journal of Political Science, 45, 658–677.CrossRef Feldman, S., & Steenbergen, M. (2001). The humanitarian foundation of public support for social welfare. American Journal of Political Science, 45, 658–677.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Feldman, S., & Zaller, J. R. (1992). The political culture of ambivalence. American Journal of Political Science, 36, 268–307.CrossRef Feldman, S., & Zaller, J. R. (1992). The political culture of ambivalence. American Journal of Political Science, 36, 268–307.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fong, C. (2001). Social preferences, self-interest, and the demand for redistribution. Journal of Public Economics, 82, 225–246.CrossRef Fong, C. (2001). Social preferences, self-interest, and the demand for redistribution. Journal of Public Economics, 82, 225–246.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gabel, M., & Whitten, G. D. (1997). Economic conditions, economic perceptions, and public support for European integration. Political Behavior, 19, 81–96.CrossRef Gabel, M., & Whitten, G. D. (1997). Economic conditions, economic perceptions, and public support for European integration. Political Behavior, 19, 81–96.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gamson, W. A., & Lasch, K. E. (1983). The political culture of social welfare policy. In: S. E. Spiro & S. Yuchtman-Yaar (Eds.), Evaluating the welfare state: Social and political perspectives (pp 397–415). New York: Academic Press. Gamson, W. A., & Lasch, K. E. (1983). The political culture of social welfare policy. In: S. E. Spiro & S. Yuchtman-Yaar (Eds.), Evaluating the welfare state: Social and political perspectives (pp 397–415). New York: Academic Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Geewax, M. (2005). Bernanke confirmation hearing: Inflation ‘target’ interests nominee. Atlanta Journal-Constitution 16 November 2005 Business. Geewax, M. (2005). Bernanke confirmation hearing: Inflation ‘target’ interests nominee. Atlanta Journal-Constitution 16 November 2005 Business.
Zurück zum Zitat Gilens, M. (1999). Why Americans hate welfare. Chicago: University of Chicago. Gilens, M. (1999). Why Americans hate welfare. Chicago: University of Chicago.
Zurück zum Zitat Gilens, M. (2001). Political ignorance and collective policy preferences. American Political Science Review, 95, 379–396.CrossRef Gilens, M. (2001). Political ignorance and collective policy preferences. American Political Science Review, 95, 379–396.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gramlich, E. M. (1974). The distributional effects of higher unemployment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1974, 293–336. Gramlich, E. M. (1974). The distributional effects of higher unemployment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1974, 293–336.
Zurück zum Zitat Heclo, H. (1986). General welfare and two American political traditions. Political Science Quarterly, 101, 179–196.CrossRef Heclo, H. (1986). General welfare and two American political traditions. Political Science Quarterly, 101, 179–196.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hibbs, D. A., Jr. (1987). The American political economy: Macroeconomics and electoral politics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Hibbs, D. A., Jr. (1987). The American political economy: Macroeconomics and electoral politics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Iyengar, S. (1990). Framing responsibility for political issues: The case of poverty. Political Behavior, 12, 19–40.CrossRef Iyengar, S. (1990). Framing responsibility for political issues: The case of poverty. Political Behavior, 12, 19–40.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Iyengar, S. (1994). Is anyone responsible? How television frames political issues. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Iyengar, S. (1994). Is anyone responsible? How television frames political issues. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Iyengar, S., & Kinder, D. R. (1987). News that matters: Television and American opinion. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Iyengar, S., & Kinder, D. R. (1987). News that matters: Television and American opinion. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Jacoby, W. G. (1994). Public attitudes toward government spending. American Journal of Political Science, 38, 336–361.CrossRef Jacoby, W. G. (1994). Public attitudes toward government spending. American Journal of Political Science, 38, 336–361.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jacoby, W. G. (2000). Issue framing and public opinion on government spending. American Journal of Political Science, 44, 750–767.CrossRef Jacoby, W. G. (2000). Issue framing and public opinion on government spending. American Journal of Political Science, 44, 750–767.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kam, C. D., & Franzese, R. J., Jr. (2007). Modeling and interpreting interaction hypotheses in regression analysis. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan. Kam, C. D., & Franzese, R. J., Jr. (2007). Modeling and interpreting interaction hypotheses in regression analysis. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan.
Zurück zum Zitat Kam, C. D., & Kinder, D. R. (1999). Ethnocentrism revisited: Public opinion and the American welfare state. Presented at the 1999 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta. Kam, C. D., & Kinder, D. R. (1999). Ethnocentrism revisited: Public opinion and the American welfare state. Presented at the 1999 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta.
Zurück zum Zitat Katz, M. B. (1989). The undeserving poor: From the war on poverty to the war on welfare. New York: Pantheon Books. Katz, M. B. (1989). The undeserving poor: From the war on poverty to the war on welfare. New York: Pantheon Books.
Zurück zum Zitat Keane, M. P., & Prasad, E. S. (1991). The relation between skill levels and the cyclical variability of employment, hours, and wages. Minneapolis: Discussion Paper No. 41. Institute for Empirical Macroeconomics, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Keane, M. P., & Prasad, E. S. (1991). The relation between skill levels and the cyclical variability of employment, hours, and wages. Minneapolis: Discussion Paper No. 41. Institute for Empirical Macroeconomics, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Zurück zum Zitat Kinder, D. R., & Kiewiet, D. R. (1979). Economic discontent and political behavior: The role of personal grievances and collective economic judgments in congressional voting. American Journal of Political Science, 23, 495–527.CrossRef Kinder, D. R., & Kiewiet, D. R. (1979). Economic discontent and political behavior: The role of personal grievances and collective economic judgments in congressional voting. American Journal of Political Science, 23, 495–527.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kinder, D. R., & Kiewiet, D. R. (1981). Sociotropic politics: The American case. British Journal of Political Science, 11, 129–161.CrossRef Kinder, D. R., & Kiewiet, D. R. (1981). Sociotropic politics: The American case. British Journal of Political Science, 11, 129–161.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kluegel, J. R. (1987). Macro-economic problems, beliefs about the poor, and attitudes toward welfare spending. Social Problems, 34, 82–99.CrossRef Kluegel, J. R. (1987). Macro-economic problems, beliefs about the poor, and attitudes toward welfare spending. Social Problems, 34, 82–99.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lewis-Beck, M. S., & Stegmaier, M. (2000). Economic determinants of electoral outcomes. Annual Reviews of Political Science, 3, 183–219.CrossRef Lewis-Beck, M. S., & Stegmaier, M. (2000). Economic determinants of electoral outcomes. Annual Reviews of Political Science, 3, 183–219.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Orr, L. L. (1976). Income transfers as a public good: An application to AFDC. The American Economic Review, 66, 359–371. Orr, L. L. (1976). Income transfers as a public good: An application to AFDC. The American Economic Review, 66, 359–371.
Zurück zum Zitat Reifschneider, D., & Williams, J. C. (2000). Three lessons for monetary policy in a low-inflation era. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 32, 936–966.CrossRef Reifschneider, D., & Williams, J. C. (2000). Three lessons for monetary policy in a low-inflation era. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 32, 936–966.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Saunders, A. (2000). Low information: The behavior of financial markets and institutions. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 32, 1058–1087.CrossRef Saunders, A. (2000). Low information: The behavior of financial markets and institutions. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 32, 1058–1087.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schneider, A., & Ingram, H. (1993). Social construction of target populations: Implications for politics and policy. American Political Science Review, 87, 334–347.CrossRef Schneider, A., & Ingram, H. (1993). Social construction of target populations: Implications for politics and policy. American Political Science Review, 87, 334–347.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schneider, S. K., & Jacoby, W. G. (2005). Elite discourse and American public opinion: The case of welfare spending. Political Research Quarterly, 58, 367–379. Schneider, S. K., & Jacoby, W. G. (2005). Elite discourse and American public opinion: The case of welfare spending. Political Research Quarterly, 58, 367–379.
Zurück zum Zitat Smith, T. W. (1987). That which we call welfare by any other name would smell sweeter. Public Opinion Quarterly, 51, 75–83.CrossRef Smith, T. W. (1987). That which we call welfare by any other name would smell sweeter. Public Opinion Quarterly, 51, 75–83.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stevenson, R. T. (2001). The economy and policy mood: A fundamental dynamic of democratic politics? American Journal of Political Science, 45, 620–633.CrossRef Stevenson, R. T. (2001). The economy and policy mood: A fundamental dynamic of democratic politics? American Journal of Political Science, 45, 620–633.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Winter, N. J. G. (2006). Beyond welfare: Framing and the racialization of white opinion on social security. American Journal of Political Science, 50, 400–420.CrossRef Winter, N. J. G. (2006). Beyond welfare: Framing and the racialization of white opinion on social security. American Journal of Political Science, 50, 400–420.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Reaching Out or Pulling Back: Macroeconomic Conditions and Public Support for Social Welfare Spending
verfasst von
Cindy D. Kam
Yunju Nam
Publikationsdatum
01.06.2008
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Political Behavior / Ausgabe 2/2008
Print ISSN: 0190-9320
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-6687
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-007-9048-3

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 2/2008

Political Behavior 2/2008 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner