Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Journal of Financial Services Research 1-2/2017

07.06.2017

Social Ties and the Demand for Financial Services

verfasst von: Eleonora Patacchini, Edoardo Rainone

Erschienen in: Journal of Financial Services Research | Ausgabe 1-2/2017

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper studies the importance of social interactions for the adoption of financial services among young adults. Specifically, we investigate whether, how, and why financial decisions among interacting agents are correlated. We exploit a unique dataset of friendship networks in the United States and a novel estimation strategy that accounts for possibly endogenous network formation. We find that not all social contacts are equally important: only long-lasting relationships influence financial decisions. Moreover, this peer influence exists only in cohesive social structures. This evidence is consistent with an important role of trust in financial decisions. When agents consider whether or not to adopt a financial instrument, they face a risk and may place greater value on information coming from agents they trust. These results can help explain the importance of face-to-face social contacts for financial decisions.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
Butler et al. (2016) highlight financial advice as an important example of a trust-based exchange. In the US, 73% of all retail investors consult a financial advisor before purchasing shares (Hung et al. 2008).
 
2
See Disney and Gathergood (2013) for consumer credit products, van Rooij et al. (2011) for stock market participation and Lusardi and Mitchell (2007) for checking and savings accounts, among others.
 
3
Most high school students in the U.S. receive a failing grade in financial literacy (Mandell 2008; Markow and Bagnaschi 2005). Similar findings are reported for financial literacy among college students (Chen and Volpe 1998; Shim et al. 2010).
 
4
This research uses data from Add Health, a program project directed by Kathleen Mullan Harris and designed by J. Richard Udry, Peter S. Bearman, and Kathleen Mullan Harris at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, and funded by grant P01-HD31921 from the Eunice Kennedy Shriver National Institute of Child Health and Human Development, with cooperative funding from 23 other federal agencies and foundations. Special acknowledgment is due Ronald R. Rindfuss and Barbara Entwisle for assistance in the original design. Information on how to obtain the Add Health data files is available on the Add Health website (http://​www.​cpc.​unc.​edu/​addhealth). No direct support was received from grant P01-HD31921 for this analysis.
 
5
The limit in the number of nominations is not binding (even by gender). Less than 1% of the students in our sample show a list of ten best friends, both in Wave I and Wave II.
 
6
An alternative definition of network link that exploits the direction of the nominations does not substantially change our results.
 
7
In Section 4.2, we show that the results remain qualitatively unchanged if we use an alternative definition of weak ties.
 
8
Unfortunately, information on the precise timing of the financial decisions is not available in our data. The only existing studies using this information are based on ad hoc survey on small samples (see Varcoe et al. 2010; Danes et al. 1999; Bowen 2002).
 
9
PCA uses an orthogonal transformation to convert a set of observations of possibly correlated variables into a set of values of linearly uncorrelated variables (called principal components). This transformation is defined in such a way that the first principal component accounts for the largest portion of variability in the data.
 
10
The other existing surveys that report friend nominations are ego-networks. In these surveys, the respondent lists her contacts and some basic characteristics of them (such as gender, education, employment status). Detailed information about nominated contacts is typically not available.
 
11
Our results do not depend crucially on these network size thresholds. They remain qualitatively unchanged when changing the network size window slightly. Also, although the computational complexity of the Bayesian analysis prevents us from working with large networks, the IV estimation results remain qualitatively unchanged when using the larger sample of networks between 4 and 400 students (see Section 4.1, and Appendix 2, Tables 1214).
 
12
Spatial models are simultaneous equation models where peers’ behavior depends on own behavior. This implies that \( {\sum }_{j=1}^{n_{r}}g_{ij,r}y_{j,r} \) is correlated with the error term ε i, r in Eq. 1. ML accounts for this simultaneity as it is based on the reduced form. Network fixed effects cannot be included in the model because the group mean \(\overline {y}_{r}\) is not a sufficient statistic for η r when the adjacency matrix is not row-normalized (see Lee et al. 2010).
 
13
See Appendix 1 for more details. For the sake of brevity, the appendix focuses on the case with weak and strong ties. The case with one peer effect is just a special case, that is when ϕ S = ϕ W .
 
14
The kernel densities and the time-series of the values of the chain for the parameters of the control variables are reported in Appendix 2, Figs. 171819 and 20.
 
15
We compute these estimated probabilities using the marginal effect of an increase of the financial activity index on the probability of adopting each of the different financial services. Marginal effects are evaluated at the sample mean: \(m(\beta )=\phi (\overline {x}\beta )\beta \), where ϕ(⋅) is the normal probability density function. Results do not change significantly if the average of individual marginal effects is instead considered.
 
16
For brevity, we do not report the ML estimation results. They are similar to the IV bias-corrected estimation results.
 
17
When estimating model (2) including only strong ties (i.e. \( g_{ij,r}^{W}=0\)), we obtain comparable results.
 
18
Observe that we model unobserved factors at the individual level. This means that the unobserved factors affecting weak and strong tie formation may be different.
 
19
Borrowing from decision theory, we can say that ϕ S stochastically dominates ϕ W , that is \(P(\phi ^{S}\geq x)\geq P(\phi ^{W}\geq x),\forall x\in \mathbb {R} \) (first-order stochastic dominance). Figure 6 also shows that the distribution of ϕ S is negatively (left) skewed. This is due to the condition on the autoregressive parameter in spatial models (peer effect parameter) that guarantees matrix inversion in Model (2). More specifically, the parameter space is (-0.10,0.10) for our network. While this is never binding for ϕ W , ϕ S is constrained to be below the upper bound. See Appendix 1 for model details.
 
20
We show Appendix 2, Table 14 that the results remain qualitatively unchanged if we perform our IV analysis on a larger sample (column 4, Table 2).
 
21
The information on parental background in our data is not detailed enough to dig further into the importance of family inputs. For example, information on parental financial literacy or financial decisions are not available.
 
22
The Folk Theorem in the repeated game literature (Rubinstein 1979; Fudenberg and Maskin 1986) provides a formal model of personal enforcement, showing that any mutually beneficial outcome can be sustained as a subgame-perfect equilibrium if the same set of agents frequently play the same stage game ad infinitum.
 
23
The role of private information in a community of buyers with word-of-mouth communication is also highlighted by Ahn and Suominen M (2001). In this model, buyers receive signals from other agents and adapt their willingness to buy a seller’s product. This mechanism incentivizes the seller to produce high quality output.
 
24
See also Greif et al. (1994) for an analysis of the role of bilateral and multilateral reputation mechanisms in the organization of economic transactions.
 
25
An alternative measure of network connectivity is the clustering coefficient. While clustering is a node-specific measure, support considers pairs of nodes (link-specific measure). Thus, support is more appropriate in our analysis, which is based on bilateral interaction-types (weak or strong). Observe that networks with an high level of clustering will necessarily display a high fraction of supported links, whereas the converse is not true.
 
26
The IV estimates in column (3) of Table 6 are used.
 
27
The experiments have also been performed using each outcome separately. The results remain qualitatively unchanged and are available upon request.
 
28
The number of shocked agents is chosen in a way such that, for each category of strong ties, we use a numerosity not larger than the real one. In our case, the minimum number of agents for each category of strong ties is 13 (when the number of strong ties is equal to 4). We then shock 13 randomly chosen nodes for each category at each replication. The results, however, remain qualitatively unchanged when changing the number of shocked nodes.
 
29
The shock intensity is 2 std points. The results remain qualitatively the same when changing the shock intensity.
 
30
We set this number equal to 13, as in our previous exercise. The qualitative results, however, do not depend on this number.
 
31
The shocks are symmetrical and equal to +2 std points for agents who have no strong ties and equal to -2 std points for those who do have strong ties.
 
32
We set the individual income shock equal to 10 std points, while the shock given to the peers varies from -1 to -20 std points. The qualitative results remain qualitatively unchanged when changing such intensities.
 
33
Liu and Lee (2010) also generalize this 2SLS approach to the GMM using additional quadratic moment conditions.
 
34
Under some conditions, this 2SLS estimator is robust to the presence of network topology misspecification (see Patacchini and Rainone 2014).
 
35
See Tierney (1994) and Chib and Greenberg (1996) for details regarding the resulting Markov chain given by the combination of those two methods.
 
36
The algorithm is robust to different starting values (see Chib and Greenberg 1996). However, speed of convergence may increase significantly.
 
37
The intuition is that if a tuning parameter is too high, the draws are less likely to be within “high density regions” of the posterior and then rejection is too frequent. The “step” is too long and the chain “does not move enough”. On the other hand if the “step” is too short, the proposal is more likely to be accepted and the chain “moves too much”. Given that we want a mixing chain with a balanced proportion of rejections and acceptances, an optimal step must be chosen. Setting it manually requires a huge amount of time and many manual operations. The dynamic setting of tuning parameters is as follows:
$$\begin{array}{lllll} \text{if}\, t_{A}/t\leq 0.4\, \text{then}\,\xi_{t+1}=\ \xi_{t}/1.1,\\ \text{if}\, t_{A}/t\geq 0.6\ \text{then}\, \xi_{t+1}=\ \xi_{t}\times 1.1,\\ \text{if}\, 0.4\leq t_{A}/t\leq 0.6\ \text{then} \,\xi_{t+1}=\ \xi_{t}, \end{array}$$
where t A is the acceptance rate at iteration t. The procedure decreases the tuning parameter (the “step”) when proposals are rejected too frequently, while it increases the tuning parameter when proposals are accepted too frequently. This mechanism guarantees a bounded acceptance rate and convergence to optimal tuning.
 
38
Given that the rejection rate-based correction of tuning parameters has 0.4 and 0.6 as boundaries, rejection rates oscillate between these values. The likelihood of reaching the boundaries decreases as the number of draws increases and the rejection rates tend to 0.5, as Fig. 10 shows.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Ahn I, Suominen M (2001) Word-of-mouth communication and community enforcement. Int Econ Rev 42(2):399–415CrossRef Ahn I, Suominen M (2001) Word-of-mouth communication and community enforcement. Int Econ Rev 42(2):399–415CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alessie R, Van Rooij M, Lusardi A (2011) Financial literacy and retirement preparation in the Netherlands. J Pension Econ Financ 10(04):527–545CrossRef Alessie R, Van Rooij M, Lusardi A (2011) Financial literacy and retirement preparation in the Netherlands. J Pension Econ Financ 10(04):527–545CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Altonji J G, Elder T E, Taber C R (2005) Selection on observed and unobserved variables: assessing the effectiveness of catholic schools. J Polit Econ 113(1):151–184CrossRef Altonji J G, Elder T E, Taber C R (2005) Selection on observed and unobserved variables: assessing the effectiveness of catholic schools. J Polit Econ 113(1):151–184CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Avery C, Turner S (2012) Student loans: do college students borrow too much or not enough? J Econ Perspect 26(1):165–192CrossRef Avery C, Turner S (2012) Student loans: do college students borrow too much or not enough? J Econ Perspect 26(1):165–192CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Balmaceda F, Escobar J (2013) Escobar Trust in cohesive communities. Technical report, Manuscript Balmaceda F, Escobar J (2013) Escobar Trust in cohesive communities. Technical report, Manuscript
Zurück zum Zitat Bernheim B D, Garrett D M, Maki D M (2001) Education and saving: the long-term effects of high school financial curriculum mandates. J Public Econ 80 (3):435–465CrossRef Bernheim B D, Garrett D M, Maki D M (2001) Education and saving: the long-term effects of high school financial curriculum mandates. J Public Econ 80 (3):435–465CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Beshears J, Choi J J, Laibson D, Madrian B C, Milkman K L (2015) The effect of providing peer information on retirement savings decisions. J Financ 70 (3):1161–1201CrossRef Beshears J, Choi J J, Laibson D, Madrian B C, Milkman K L (2015) The effect of providing peer information on retirement savings decisions. J Financ 70 (3):1161–1201CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bönte W, Filipiak U (2012) Financial literacy, information flows, and caste affiliation: empirical evidence from india. J Bank Financ 36(12):3399–3414CrossRef Bönte W, Filipiak U (2012) Financial literacy, information flows, and caste affiliation: empirical evidence from india. J Bank Financ 36(12):3399–3414CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bowen C F (2002) Financial knowledge of teens and their parents. J Financ Counsel Plan 13(2):93 Bowen C F (2002) Financial knowledge of teens and their parents. J Financ Counsel Plan 13(2):93
Zurück zum Zitat Bramoullé Y., Djebbari H, Fortin B (2009) Identification of peer effects through social networks. J Econ 150(1):41–55CrossRef Bramoullé Y., Djebbari H, Fortin B (2009) Identification of peer effects through social networks. J Econ 150(1):41–55CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brown J R, Ivković Z, Smith P A, Weisbenner S (2008) Neighbors matter: causal community effects and stock market participation. J Financ 63(3):1509–1531CrossRef Brown J R, Ivković Z, Smith P A, Weisbenner S (2008) Neighbors matter: causal community effects and stock market participation. J Financ 63(3):1509–1531CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bursztyn L, Ederer F, Ferman B, Yuchtman N (2014) Understanding peer effects in financial decisions: evidence from a field experiment. Econometrica 82 (4):1273–1301CrossRef Bursztyn L, Ederer F, Ferman B, Yuchtman N (2014) Understanding peer effects in financial decisions: evidence from a field experiment. Econometrica 82 (4):1273–1301CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Butler J V, Giuliano PL, Guiso L (2016) Guiso trust and cheating. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research Butler J V, Giuliano PL, Guiso L (2016) Guiso trust and cheating. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research
Zurück zum Zitat Cai J, De Janvry A, Sadoulet E (2015) Social networks and the decision to insure. Amer Econ J Appl Econ 7(2):81–108CrossRef Cai J, De Janvry A, Sadoulet E (2015) Social networks and the decision to insure. Amer Econ J Appl Econ 7(2):81–108CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Calvó-Armengol A, Patacchini E, Zenou Y (2009) Peer effects and social networks in education. Rev Econ Stud 76(4):1239–1267CrossRef Calvó-Armengol A, Patacchini E, Zenou Y (2009) Peer effects and social networks in education. Rev Econ Stud 76(4):1239–1267CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chen H, Volpe R P (1998) An analysis of personal financial literacy among college students. Financ Serv Rev 7(2):107–128CrossRef Chen H, Volpe R P (1998) An analysis of personal financial literacy among college students. Financ Serv Rev 7(2):107–128CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chib S, Greenberg E (1996) Markov chain monte carlo simulation methods in econometrics. Econ Theory 12(03):409–431CrossRef Chib S, Greenberg E (1996) Markov chain monte carlo simulation methods in econometrics. Econ Theory 12(03):409–431CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Danes S M, Huddleston-Casas C, Boyce L (1999) Financial planning curriculum for teens: impact evaluation. J Financ Counsel Plan 10(1):26 Danes S M, Huddleston-Casas C, Boyce L (1999) Financial planning curriculum for teens: impact evaluation. J Financ Counsel Plan 10(1):26
Zurück zum Zitat De Giorgi G, Pellizzari M, Redaelli S (2010) Identification of social interactions through partially overlapping peer groups. Amer Econ J Appl Econ :241–275 De Giorgi G, Pellizzari M, Redaelli S (2010) Identification of social interactions through partially overlapping peer groups. Amer Econ J Appl Econ :241–275
Zurück zum Zitat Disney R, Gathergood J (2013) Financial literacy and consumer credit portfolios. J Bank Financ 37(7):2246–2254CrossRef Disney R, Gathergood J (2013) Financial literacy and consumer credit portfolios. J Bank Financ 37(7):2246–2254CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Duflo E, Saez E (2003) The role of information and social interactions in retirement plan decisions: evidence from a randomized experiment. Q J Econ 118(3):815–842CrossRef Duflo E, Saez E (2003) The role of information and social interactions in retirement plan decisions: evidence from a randomized experiment. Q J Econ 118(3):815–842CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fudenberg D, Maskin E (1986) The folk theorem in repeated games with discounting or with incomplete information. Econ J Econ Soc :533–554 Fudenberg D, Maskin E (1986) The folk theorem in repeated games with discounting or with incomplete information. Econ J Econ Soc :533–554
Zurück zum Zitat Gennaioli N, Shleifer A, Vishny R (2014) Finance and the preservation of wealth. Q J Econ 129(3):1221–1254CrossRef Gennaioli N, Shleifer A, Vishny R (2014) Finance and the preservation of wealth. Q J Econ 129(3):1221–1254CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goldsmith-Pinkham P, Imbens G W (2013) Social networks and the identification of peer effects. J Bus Econ Stat 31:253–264CrossRef Goldsmith-Pinkham P, Imbens G W (2013) Social networks and the identification of peer effects. J Bus Econ Stat 31:253–264CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Granovetter M (1985) Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness. Amer J Sociol :481–510 Granovetter M (1985) Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness. Amer J Sociol :481–510
Zurück zum Zitat Greif A, Milgrom P, Weingast B R (1994) Coordination, commitment, and enforcement: the case of the merchant guild. J Polit Econ :745–776 Greif A, Milgrom P, Weingast B R (1994) Coordination, commitment, and enforcement: the case of the merchant guild. J Polit Econ :745–776
Zurück zum Zitat Guiso L, Sapienza P, Zingales L (2004) The role of social capital in financial development. Amer Econ Rev 94(3):526–556CrossRef Guiso L, Sapienza P, Zingales L (2004) The role of social capital in financial development. Amer Econ Rev 94(3):526–556CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guiso L, Sapienza P, Zingales L (2008) Trusting the stock market. J Financ 63(6):2557–2600CrossRef Guiso L, Sapienza P, Zingales L (2008) Trusting the stock market. J Financ 63(6):2557–2600CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hong H, Kubik J D, Stein J C (2004) Social interaction and stock-market participation. J Financ 59(1):137–163CrossRef Hong H, Kubik J D, Stein J C (2004) Social interaction and stock-market participation. J Financ 59(1):137–163CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hsieh C-S, Lee L F (2016) A social interactions model with endogenous friendship formation and selectivity. J Appl Econ 31(2):301–319CrossRef Hsieh C-S, Lee L F (2016) A social interactions model with endogenous friendship formation and selectivity. J Appl Econ 31(2):301–319CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hung A A, Clancy N, Dominitz J, Talley E, Berrebi C (2008) nvestor and industry perspectives on investment advisers and broker-dealers, vol 767. Rand Corporation Hung A A, Clancy N, Dominitz J, Talley E, Berrebi C (2008) nvestor and industry perspectives on investment advisers and broker-dealers, vol 767. Rand Corporation
Zurück zum Zitat Jackson M O, Rodriguez-Barraquer T, Tan X (2012) Social capital and social quilts: network patterns of favor exchange. Amer Econ Rev 102(5):1857–1897CrossRef Jackson M O, Rodriguez-Barraquer T, Tan X (2012) Social capital and social quilts: network patterns of favor exchange. Amer Econ Rev 102(5):1857–1897CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kandori M (1992) Social norms and community enforcement. Rev Econ Stud 59 (1):63–80CrossRef Kandori M (1992) Social norms and community enforcement. Rev Econ Stud 59 (1):63–80CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Karlan D, Mobius M, Rosenblat T, Szeidl A (2009) Trust and social collateral. Q J Econ 124(3):1307–1361CrossRef Karlan D, Mobius M, Rosenblat T, Szeidl A (2009) Trust and social collateral. Q J Econ 124(3):1307–1361CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Klapper L, Lusardi A, Panos G A (2013) Financial literacy and its consequences: evidence from Russia during the financial crisis. J Bank Financ 37(10):3904–3923CrossRef Klapper L, Lusardi A, Panos G A (2013) Financial literacy and its consequences: evidence from Russia during the financial crisis. J Bank Financ 37(10):3904–3923CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lee L F, Liu X, Lin X (2010) Specification and estimation of social interaction models with network structures. Econ J 13:145–176 Lee L F, Liu X, Lin X (2010) Specification and estimation of social interaction models with network structures. Econ J 13:145–176
Zurück zum Zitat Lin X (2010) Identifying peer effects in student academic achievement by spatial autoregressive models with group unobservables. J Labor Econ 28(4):825–860CrossRef Lin X (2010) Identifying peer effects in student academic achievement by spatial autoregressive models with group unobservables. J Labor Econ 28(4):825–860CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lippert S, Spagnolo G (2011) Networks of relations and word-of-mouth communication. Games Econ Behav 72(1):202–217CrossRef Lippert S, Spagnolo G (2011) Networks of relations and word-of-mouth communication. Games Econ Behav 72(1):202–217CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Liu X, Lee L F (2010) Gmm estimation of social interaction models with centrality. J Econ 159:99–115CrossRef Liu X, Lee L F (2010) Gmm estimation of social interaction models with centrality. J Econ 159:99–115CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lusardi A, Mitchell O S (2007) Baby boomer retirement security: the roles of planning, financial literacy, and housing wealth. J Monetary Econ 54(1):205–224CrossRef Lusardi A, Mitchell O S (2007) Baby boomer retirement security: the roles of planning, financial literacy, and housing wealth. J Monetary Econ 54(1):205–224CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lusardi A, Mitchell O S (2014) The economic importance of financial literacy: theory and evidence. J Econ Lit 52(1):5–44CrossRef Lusardi A, Mitchell O S (2014) The economic importance of financial literacy: theory and evidence. J Econ Lit 52(1):5–44CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mandell L (2008) Financial literacy of high school students, handbook of consumer finance research. Springer, pp 163–183 Mandell L (2008) Financial literacy of high school students, handbook of consumer finance research. Springer, pp 163–183
Zurück zum Zitat Manski C F (1993) Identification of endogenous social effects: the reflection problem. Rev Econ Stud 60(3):531–542CrossRef Manski C F (1993) Identification of endogenous social effects: the reflection problem. Rev Econ Stud 60(3):531–542CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Markow D, Bagnaschi K (2005) What american teens & adults know about economics. Nat Coun Econ Educ Markow D, Bagnaschi K (2005) What american teens & adults know about economics. Nat Coun Econ Educ
Zurück zum Zitat Martin A, Oliva J C (2001) Teaching children about money: applications of social learning and cognitive learning developmental theories. J Fam Consum Sci Res Pract 93(2):26–29 Martin A, Oliva J C (2001) Teaching children about money: applications of social learning and cognitive learning developmental theories. J Fam Consum Sci Res Pract 93(2):26–29
Zurück zum Zitat Patacchini E, Rainone E (2014) The word on banking-social ties, trust, and the adoption of financial products Tech. Rep. Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance (EIEF) Patacchini E, Rainone E (2014) The word on banking-social ties, trust, and the adoption of financial products Tech. Rep. Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance (EIEF)
Zurück zum Zitat Patacchini E, Rainone E, Zenou Y (2017) Heterogeneous peer effects in education. J Econ Behav Org 134:190–227CrossRef Patacchini E, Rainone E, Zenou Y (2017) Heterogeneous peer effects in education. J Econ Behav Org 134:190–227CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rubinstein A (1979) Equilibrium in supergames with the overtaking criterion. J Econ Theory 21(1):1–9CrossRef Rubinstein A (1979) Equilibrium in supergames with the overtaking criterion. J Econ Theory 21(1):1–9CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shim S, Barber B L, Card N A, Xiao J J, Serido J (2010) Financial socialization of first-year college students: the roles of parents, work, and education. J Youth Adolesc 39(12):1457–1470CrossRef Shim S, Barber B L, Card N A, Xiao J J, Serido J (2010) Financial socialization of first-year college students: the roles of parents, work, and education. J Youth Adolesc 39(12):1457–1470CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stavins J (2016) The effect of demographics on payment behavior: panel data with sample selection. Boston FED WP Stavins J (2016) The effect of demographics on payment behavior: panel data with sample selection. Boston FED WP
Zurück zum Zitat Tierney L (1994) Markov chains for exploring posterior distributions. Ann Stat. 1701–1728 Tierney L (1994) Markov chains for exploring posterior distributions. Ann Stat. 1701–1728
Zurück zum Zitat van Rooij M, Lusardi A, Alessie R (2011) Financial literacy and stock market participation. J Fin Econ 101(2):449–472CrossRef van Rooij M, Lusardi A, Alessie R (2011) Financial literacy and stock market participation. J Fin Econ 101(2):449–472CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Varcoe K P, Peterson S S, Wooten Swanson P, Johns MC (2010) What do teens want to know about money? A comparison of 1998 and 2008. Fam Consum Sci Res J 38(4):360–371CrossRef Varcoe K P, Peterson S S, Wooten Swanson P, Johns MC (2010) What do teens want to know about money? A comparison of 1998 and 2008. Fam Consum Sci Res J 38(4):360–371CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Social Ties and the Demand for Financial Services
verfasst von
Eleonora Patacchini
Edoardo Rainone
Publikationsdatum
07.06.2017
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Journal of Financial Services Research / Ausgabe 1-2/2017
Print ISSN: 0920-8550
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-0735
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-017-0279-0

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1-2/2017

Journal of Financial Services Research 1-2/2017 Zur Ausgabe