Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 3-4/2020

13.05.2019

The development and evolution of predatory-state institutions and organizations: beliefs, violence, conquest, coercion, and rent seeking

verfasst von: Bruce L. Benson

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 3-4/2020

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

The purposes of this presentation are to (1) provide a relatively short coherent picture of predatory states, (2) pull some of North, Wallis and Weingast’s important arguments, particularly from their discussion of “natural states”, into predatory state analysis, including their fundamental elements of “violence, organizations, institutions and beliefs”; and (3) criticize the kinds of assumptions public-interest views rely on by using NWW’s very public-interest and non-public-choice depiction of the “open access order” as a way to reveal some of those assumptions. Even if states provide public goods, the primary focus for politicians appears to be on transferring wealth to themselves and/or to elites and interest groups. Most states also have engaged in aggression to expand their jurisdictions. Predatory-state theories focuses on wealth transfers and aggression. These models explain states’ historical development and many observed state actions. Perhaps surprisingly, they even provide a theoretical explanation of public-good provision. The primary conclusion is that states, including the U.S., are predatory. Consideration of violence, organizations, institutions, and beliefs adds power to this contention. Observed state institutions and organization are consistent with an evolved predatory state. Examination of a number of explicit or implicit institutional and organizational assumptions supporting public-interest views of states further reinforces the contention. These assumptions either do not hold, or hold only in part.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
Hume (1741–42, pp/189–90) explains that “almost all governments, which exist at present or of which there remains any record in story have been founded either originally on usurpation or conquest, or both, without any pretence of a fair consent, or voluntary subjection of the people.”
 
2
Samuelsonian public goods are non-excludable and non-rivalrous in consumption, resulting in free riding and underproduction (or non-production) by the private sector (McNutt 2000, pp. 927–928). However, Demsetz (1970) explains that when exclusion is possible non-rivalrous consumption will not prevent efficient private production; Goldin (1977) points out that institutions always are available for exclusion. Benson (1994) adds that free access inevitably leads to crowding/congestion and, therefore, rivalrous consumption. Examinations of many alleged public goods also reject claims of non-rivalrous consumption and/or non-excludability, including lighthouses (Coase 1974); lightships (Candela and Geloso 2018); policing, courts and other social-order organizations (Benson 1994, 1998, 2010; Ekelund and Dorton 2003; Stringham 2015); roads (Benson 1994, 2017; Roth 1996); national defense (Coyne 2015; Vahabi 2016) and other social services (Foldvary 1994). Holcombe (1977) also explains that public-goods theory is best seen as an attempted justification for taxation and state production. Also see subSect. 3.6.
 
3
See, for example, Lane (1958), Levi (1988), Tilley (1990), Usher (1992), Barzel (2002), Bates (2001) and Moselle and Polak (2001). Relatively explicit public-choice analyses of predatory states include Olson (1993), Benson (1999), Kurrild-Klitgaard and Svendsen (2003), Leeson (2007a), Powell and Stringham (2009), Leeson and Williamson (2009), Vahabi (2016) and Benson and Meehan (2018).
 
4
NWW page references are from the Kindle electronic volume. North et al. (2012) is an edited companion volume.
 
5
A natural state manages the problem of violence by forming a dominant coalition that limits access to valuable resources—land, labor, and capital—or access to and control of valuable activities—such as trade, worship, and education – to elite groups. The creation of rents [by] limiting access provides the glue that holds the coalition together, enabling elite groups to make credible commitments to one another to support the regime, perform their functions, and refrain from violence” (NWW 2009, p. 30).
 
6
It is difficult to define NWW’s open access order succinctly, but they suggest that “perhaps the most central feature of open access orders is the transformation of a society based on elites to one based on a mass citizenry. This transformation also combines beliefs in equality and open access to markets, the institutional apparatus of rule of law, and mass political participation” (NWW 2009, p. 18). Other characteristics are discussed in Sect. 3.
 
7
Behavioral economics challenges the rationality assumption. Indeed, that assumption often does not explain an individual’s behavior. However, as Brennan and Buchanan (1983) remark, it is important to assume rational self-interest for comparative institutional analysis, since at least some people will take advantage of any institution.
 
8
NWW (2009, p. 254) suggest that people are “motivated by economic rents” but they do not discuss the behavioral implications systematically, arguing that “A full account of human behavior would begin by asking how the mind deals with the process of change. A necessary preliminary is to understand how the brain interprets signals received by the senses and how the mind structures the result into coherent beliefs” (NWW 2009, pp. 250–251). NWW note that they do not know how signals are transformed into beliefs. Neither do I, but an imperfect model nevertheless can be quite powerful (see note 7).
 
9
Property rights never are completely defined and secured because of the transaction costs of delineating and enforcing rights to the multiple attributes of most assets. In Barzel’s (1989) terms, “some valued properties will always remain in the public domain.” Individuals have incentives to discover ways to capture such value, but competition for rights goes beyond the discovery process, as individuals also pursue transfers of existing rights.
 
10
NWW (2009, p. 42) do note that violence can be employed to take property rights, but it is not clear that they consider such takings to be a primary reason for violence, since they suggest that “our genetic makeup predisposes humans to be violent” (NWW 2009, p. 8). They also contend repeatedly that violence is considered, in all societies, to be a “problem” (NWW 2009, pp. 14, 17, 18, 30 and elsewhere). Some societies actually value violence, however. In his examination of Native American plains tribes of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, for instance, Hoig (1993, p. 22; also see Lowie 1954, p. 106; and Mishkin 1940, p. 2) explains, “tribal male's innermost self was programmed from birth toward his emergence as a warrior.… Bravery was stressed above all other virtues”.
 
11
NWW (2009) do not examine choices between taking and trading, but see Bastiat (1845, 1850), Oppenheimer (1908), Skaperdas (1992), Rider (1993), Anderson and McChesney (1994) and Benson (1999, 2006, 2007).
 
12
Two types of institutions develop. Behavioral rules apply to interpersonal interactions and governance rules support behavioral rules. As noted above, rules establishing adjudication arise, but so do rules encouraging individuals to recognize and follow behavioral rules (and adjudication rulings). In a dynamic setting, rules establishing procedures for creating/changing behavioral rules also arise. See Benson (1999).
 
13
NWW (2009) do not go into much detail regarding foraging social orders, so, for instance, the rest of this subsection does not reflect their analysis, but it facilitates the discussion of predatory-state formation.
 
14
Creating private property rights is costly but occurs as the benefits of doing so increase or costs fall (Demsetz 1967).
 
15
NWW (2009) do not consider the issues in this and the next paragraph but they are key to understanding state development.
 
16
At least two types of beliefs can be distinguished in this context. One “subset of beliefs [is] causal beliefs, which concern the causal connections between actions and outcomes in the world around us” (NWW 2009, p. 27). Causal beliefs often are “positive beliefs”. Normative beliefs, or moral beliefs, are about how people, including decision makers, should behave. NWW (2009, p. 262) also consider ideology, which often is inaccurate. Ideology can be formulated intentionally and spread to legitimize certain organizations and practices. For instance, NWW (2009, pp. 54, 56–57) explain that
Aztecs held that the sun god daily battled his way across the sky against his brothers the stars and his sister the moon. In order to triumph in this battle, the sun … required chalchihuatl, the precious liquid, the blood of man. Failure to nourish the sun would result in the destruction of the earth. The expanding use of human sacrifice fueled the expansionary military goals of the Aztecs, and it provided an ideological framework that justified the labor of the masses….
NWW (2009. p. 28) also suggest that beliefs can be adopted or changed by education, but given the points just made, organized education can influence normative beliefs and ideology as well as causal beliefs.
 
17
NWW (2009) do not address the issues raised in this subsection, but it is relevant for a transition from band/tribal organizations to a state.
 
18
Parts of this section reflect NWW’s (2009) analysis or employ some of their historical discussion, but significant additions and alterations also are made.
 
19
Nobles had access to royal court to resolve disputes, and obligations to give counsel to the king when called upon.
 
20
Nobles and gentry (about 0.5–1.0% of England’s population) controlled around 45% of England’s land in 1436 (NWW 2009, p. 93), while the King held about 5% and the church controlled about 20%.
 
21
Freeholders held land on feudal or seignorial tenures whereby a direct relationship existed with the landlord. They had access to royal courts so they could seek protection against landlords. Villeins held unfree tenure, were bound to their lord’s service, and did not have access to royal courts for several centuries. Unfree laborers also were bound to their lord’s service with no royal court access.
 
22
The remainder of this subsection does not reflect points emphasized by NWW (2009) for reasons noted below.
 
23
For the most part, the next two subsections focus on predatory state characteristics and do not reflect NWW’s (2009) analysis (the exception is the paragraph about consolidation of the military).
 
24
Predatory systems generally have "parallel", predominately cooperative institutional systems dominating many and even most interactions (de Soto 1989).
 
25
Groups outside the conquerors’ jurisdiction also pose threats as roaming bandits or aspiring stationary bandits.
 
26
Other institutional changes also helped undermine the system (Benson 1998).
 
27
Also see the discussion of changes in public finance in subsection 3.5.
 
28
Strong bureaus may facilitate the transfer process, but they also can pursue objectives that reduce potential wealth transfers. Their pursuit of larger budgets and power can lead to excess bureaucratic production and increase incentives for resistance. Also see Sects. 3.3 and 3.4.
 
29
Further reductions in sheriffs’ power were instituted between 1232 and 1237, when sheriffs became appointees of the exchequer, another expanding bureaucracy.
 
30
As explained below, the material in this section address points from NWW (2009) but adds to the analysis and challenges their conclusions. Also see Sect. 3.3.
 
31
Conceivably, the winner’s gains could exceed the loser’s losses (see note 31), but then bargaining should make both better off if transaction costs are not prohibitively high.
 
32
NWW (2009) do not consider the issues raised in this subsection.
 
33
The claim may be true, if outsiders have short time horizons because they are not sure that they can maintain control over a distant jurisdiction. Note that a number of such services exist beyond those discussed here. The provision of transportation infrastructure may in fact benefit many people, for instance, although the primary purpose may be to facilitate movement of military and policing personnel (see note 23 and Sect. 3).
 
34
The fifth characteristic is challenged in subsection 3.4. The first four appear to apply, at least to most of Western Europe, North America, Australia and New Zealand. The question here is, what generated these characteristics, development of OAOs, or something else, such as predatory state development of parliaments, governments that recognize the potential for large takings if economies are strong?.
 
35
The list reflects my perception of the institutions and organizations NWW (2009) stress. The page citations in this paragraph are very incomplete as each argument appears numerous time elsewhere. Note that I include doorstep conditions 2 and 3 in the list, but see doorstep 1 becoming more inclusive.
 
36
This rebellion occurred when the federal government imposed its first selective tax on a product, distilled spirits.
 
37
The United States was involved in an undeclared naval war with France, the so-called Quasi-War (1798–1800), because of default on war debt to the French and trade with Great Britain (France was at war with the British). In July 1798, Congress imposed $2 million in new taxes on dwellings, lands and slaves to fund military expansions. Fries’s Rebellion (1789–1800) resulted from that taxation.
 
38
Between 1800 and 1850, in addition to the military actions discussed in the text, the United States sent troops, naval ships, or both, repeatedly in some cases, to Tripoli, Algeria, the Barbary states, Greece, the Ivory Coast, the Gulf of Mexico and the Caribbean, including Cuba, Puerto Rico, Santo Domingo and the Yucatan, in pursuit of pirates. Military action to protect US citizens or interests, or to punish groups who harmed or killed them also occurred in the Marquesas Islands, the Falkland Islands, Canada, Sumatra, Argentina, Peru, Fiji, McKean Island in the Gilbert Islands, Samoa and Smyrna (Izmir, Turkey).
 
39
As noted above, the country was at war with the Cherokees when it was formed. The Posey War (1923) often is cited as the last of the Indian wars.
 
40
Tribes (in many cases coalitions of tribes, such as Tecumseh’s Confederacy) against which the United States went to war after 1800 include the Creek, Seminole (three wars between 1817 and 1858), Comanche (lasting about 40 years), Arikara, Ho-Chunk, Potawatoni, Cayuse, Ute (spread over almost 75 years), Paiute, Navaho, Apache (spread over 75 years), Yuma, Mohave, Cocopah, Cahulla, Cupeno, Sioux (over 35 years), Klickitat, Cascade, Nisqually, Muckleshoot, Puyallup, Haidi, Tingit, Yakama, Yokut, Yuki, Whkut, Chilula, Hupa, Chimariko, Lassik, Matolle, Nongaltl, Sinkyone, Tsnungwe, Wallaki, Mohave, Walalai, Shoshone, Bannock, Yavapai, Kawaiisu, Tubatulabal, Cheyenne, Arapaho, Snake, Hualapai, Yavapai, Havasupai, Modoc, Nez Perce, and Crow.
 
41
It did much more, of course, but the issue here is the effect on control of land.
 
42
Between 1850 and 1900, US military forces also were sent into the Ottoman Empire, Johanna Island, China, Nicaragua, Fiji Islands, Uruguay, Panama, Granada, Paraguay, Angola, Mexico, Formosa, Columbia, Korea, Hawaii, Egypt, Haiti, Samoa, Argentina and Chile some multiple times, as well as numerous incursions into Mexico in pursuit of outlaws, and the Bering Sea against foreign seal hunters.
 
43
Cultural arguments have been raised (Gillespie 2012, p. 19), as well as media bias (Gillespie 2012, pp. 19–21), control of participation in television debates (Gillespie 2012, pp. 30-32), and Constitutional issues, including single-member districts for legislative elections and the Electoral College process for presidential elections (Gillespie 2012, pp. 21–25).
 
44
Various laws also have made certain alternative parties illegal (particularly communists), as well as particular activities associated with some alternative parties (e.g., anti-war and anti-military actions) (Gillespie 2012, pp. 33–36).
 
45
The citations to this publication are to one of its 14 sections because my Kindle version does not have page numbers. Congressman X revealed that he is a current Democratic congressman, but beyond that, he demanded that the publisher safeguard his identity: “I don’t have the fortitude or desire to soil my legacy. I also don’t want to embarrass my family or congressional colleagues I have worked with over the years. Nor do I want to subject myself to a barrage of incoming crap from the hard-nosed progressives in my party”.
 
46
Congressman X asserts that deceit by Members of Congress is “well-meaning”. Virtually every action can be rationalized as being in the public interest by pointing to some alleged consequence, even if the legislation is structured to benefit narrow interests (Meehan and Benson 2015). Congressman X (2016, p. 7) confesses that “Rationalizing lies is part of our [Congress’s] DNA…. Is it a lie if I truly believe what I’m saying?”.
 
47
NWW never refer to the rent-seeking literature except to criticize it (NWW 2009, pp. 24, 140).
 
48
It is conceivable that actual rent creation could occur if a valuable use of an unowned asset is discovered and the benefits of creating rights to the asset exceed the costs (e.g., recall note 10’s point that property rights never are fully assigned, so value remains to be captured). The state does not need to create the rights (Ellickson 1991, 1993; Benson 1999), however. The likelihood of true net rent creation through state action must be very small relative to the likelihood of rent-creation through property rights transfers.
 
49
$3.15 billion was spent on lobbying at the federal level in 2016, a year when 11,168 lobbyists were registered (https://​www.​opensecrets.​org/​lobby/​). Many lobbyists represent multiple clients. For more details, see https://​www.​opensecrets.​org/​lobby/​.
 
50
See note 2.
 
51
Butler (2007) provides a long list of parks and the railroads associated with them.
 
52
Market organizations are more likely to sustain impersonal categories such as “customers” and then treat everyone in that category alike. First, they generally ration by price, so excess demand is unlikely. In addition, if a market is competitive, discrimination is not profitable. Third, customer abuse can lead to tort litigation, and firms are generally liable for the actions of their employees. It is much more difficult to sue the state or its employees successfully.
 
53
On November 29, 1864, the Colorado militia attacked a Cheyenne encampment on Sand Creek. The targets were followers of Black Kettle, one of the tribal leaders who wanted to maintain peace and agreed to move to a reservation. Even though the encampment flew a flag of truce, 150– 200 persons, mostly Cheyenne women and children, were killed.
 
54
Police are supposed to be consolidated too (NWW 2009, pp. 21–22), but that has never been the case in the United States.
 
55
See Note 2.
 
56
Such goods generate substantial rivalrous private benefits (rents), as do many other alleged public goods. When private benefactors are businesses or labor unions (i.e., complementary to some market), they are likely to be the interest to which legislators respond. In addition, bureaucratic interests appear to be a much more likely source of demand than are the masses (Benson and Meehan 2018). Also see Note 2.
 
57
Predation on future generations is reinforced when voter ignorance in competitive elections with limited term lengths requiring repeated reelection, means that legislators have limited time horizons (Lee and Buchanan 1982). Congressman X (2016, p. 5) puts it more bluntly:
Nobody here [in Congress] gives a rat’s ass about the future and who’s going to pay for all this stuff we vote for. That’s the next generation problem. It’s all about immediate publicity, getting credit now, lookin’ good for the upcoming election.
 
58
A related predatory-state hypothesis from Tilly (1990; also see Bates 2001) is that military competition drove state formation and growth in Europe: when a state adopted new expensive military technologies, other states had to follow suit, so all states grew. To do so, they had to develop new financial institutions.
 
59
See NWW’s (2009, p. 183) informative discussion of the development of an external financial market for England’s naval debt, for instance.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Anderson, T., & Hill, P. (1996). Appropriable rents from Yellowstone Park: A case of incomplete contracting. Economic Inquiry,36, 506–518. Anderson, T., & Hill, P. (1996). Appropriable rents from Yellowstone Park: A case of incomplete contracting. Economic Inquiry,36, 506–518.
Zurück zum Zitat Anderson, T., & McChesney, F. (1994). Raid or trade? An economic model of Indian-White relations. The Journal of Law and Economics,37(1), 39–74. Anderson, T., & McChesney, F. (1994). Raid or trade? An economic model of Indian-White relations. The Journal of Law and Economics,37(1), 39–74.
Zurück zum Zitat Barzel, Y. (1989). Economic analysis of property rights. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Barzel, Y. (1989). Economic analysis of property rights. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Barzel, Y. (2002). A theory of the state, economic rights, legal rights, and the scope of the state. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Barzel, Y. (2002). A theory of the state, economic rights, legal rights, and the scope of the state. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Bastiat, F. (1845 [1996]). Economic sophisms. A. Goddard (Tr. & Ed.). Irvington-on-Hudson, NY: Foundation for Economic Education. Bastiat, F. (1845 [1996]). Economic sophisms. A. Goddard (Tr. & Ed.). Irvington-on-Hudson, NY: Foundation for Economic Education.
Zurück zum Zitat Bastiat, F. (1850 [1996]) The law. D. Russell (Tr.). Irvington-on-Hudson, NY: Foundation for Economic Education. Bastiat, F. (1850 [1996]) The law. D. Russell (Tr.). Irvington-on-Hudson, NY: Foundation for Economic Education.
Zurück zum Zitat Bates, R. (2001). Prosperity and violence: The political economy of development. NY: W.W. Norton. Bates, R. (2001). Prosperity and violence: The political economy of development. NY: W.W. Norton.
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. (1981). Why are congressional committees dominated by `high demand’ legislators? Southern Economic Journal,48(1), 68–77. Benson, B. (1981). Why are congressional committees dominated by `high demand’ legislators? Southern Economic Journal,48(1), 68–77.
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. (1984). Rent seeking from a property rights perspective. Southern Economic Journal,51, 388–400. Benson, B. (1984). Rent seeking from a property rights perspective. Southern Economic Journal,51, 388–400.
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. (1994). Are public goods really common pools: Considerations of the evolution of policing and highways in England. Economic Inquiry,32(2), 249–271. Benson, B. (1994). Are public goods really common pools: Considerations of the evolution of policing and highways in England. Economic Inquiry,32(2), 249–271.
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. (1998). To serve and protect: Privatization and community in criminal justice. New York: New York University Press. Benson, B. (1998). To serve and protect: Privatization and community in criminal justice. New York: New York University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. (1999). An economic theory of the evolution of governance and the emergence of the state. Review of Austrian Economics,12(2), 131–160. Benson, B. (1999). An economic theory of the evolution of governance and the emergence of the state. Review of Austrian Economics,12(2), 131–160.
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. (2006). Property rights and the buffalo economy of the Great Plains. In T. Anderson, B. Benson, & T. Flannagan (Eds.), Self-determination: The other path for Native Americans (pp. 29–67). Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press. Benson, B. (2006). Property rights and the buffalo economy of the Great Plains. In T. Anderson, B. Benson, & T. Flannagan (Eds.), Self-determination: The other path for Native Americans (pp. 29–67). Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. (2007). Beliefs as institution-specific rationalized self-interest. In H. Bouillon & H. Kliemt (Eds.), Ordered anarchy: Jasay and his surroundings (pp. 103–145). Aldershot: Ashgate. Benson, B. (2007). Beliefs as institution-specific rationalized self-interest. In H. Bouillon & H. Kliemt (Eds.), Ordered anarchy: Jasay and his surroundings (pp. 103–145). Aldershot: Ashgate.
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. (2010). The allocation of police. In B. Benson & P. Zimmerman (Eds.), The handbook on the economics of crime (pp. 518–522). Aldershot: Edward Elgar. Benson, B. (2010). The allocation of police. In B. Benson & P. Zimmerman (Eds.), The handbook on the economics of crime (pp. 518–522). Aldershot: Edward Elgar.
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. (2017). Are roads public goods, club goods, private goods, or common pools. In J. Hall (Ed.), Explorations in public sector economics: Essays by prominent economists (pp. 171–213). Cham, Switzerland: Springer. Benson, B. (2017). Are roads public goods, club goods, private goods, or common pools. In J. Hall (Ed.), Explorations in public sector economics: Essays by prominent economists (pp. 171–213). Cham, Switzerland: Springer.
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B., & Meehan, B. (2018). Predatory public finance and the evolution of the war on drugs. In A. Hoffer & T. Nesbit (Eds.), For your own good: Taxes, paternalism, and fiscal discrimination in the twenty-first century (pp. 167–304). Mercatus Center: Arlington, VA. Benson, B., & Meehan, B. (2018). Predatory public finance and the evolution of the war on drugs. In A. Hoffer & T. Nesbit (Eds.), For your own good: Taxes, paternalism, and fiscal discrimination in the twenty-first century (pp. 167–304). Mercatus Center: Arlington, VA.
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B., & Mitchell, J. (1988). Rent seekers who demand government production: Bureaucratic output and the price of complements. Public Choice,56(1), 3–16. Benson, B., & Mitchell, J. (1988). Rent seekers who demand government production: Bureaucratic output and the price of complements. Public Choice,56(1), 3–16.
Zurück zum Zitat Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. (1983). Predictive power and the choice among regimes. Economic Journal,93, 89–105. Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. (1983). Predictive power and the choice among regimes. Economic Journal,93, 89–105.
Zurück zum Zitat Brown, D. (1991). Human universals. New York: McGraw Hill. Brown, D. (1991). Human universals. New York: McGraw Hill.
Zurück zum Zitat Butler, W. (2007). Railroads in the national parks. Estes Park, CO: Rocky Mountain National Park Archeologist manuscript. Butler, W. (2007). Railroads in the national parks. Estes Park, CO: Rocky Mountain National Park Archeologist manuscript.
Zurück zum Zitat Candela, R., & Geloso, V. (2018). The lightship in economics. Public Choice, 176(3), 479–506. Candela, R., & Geloso, V. (2018). The lightship in economics. Public Choice, 176(3), 479–506.
Zurück zum Zitat Coase, R. (1974). The lighthouse in economics. Journal of Law and Economics,17(2), 357–376. Coase, R. (1974). The lighthouse in economics. Journal of Law and Economics,17(2), 357–376.
Zurück zum Zitat Congressman, X. (2016). The confessions of Congressman X. Minneapolis, MN: Mill City Press. Congressman, X. (2016). The confessions of Congressman X. Minneapolis, MN: Mill City Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Coyne, C. (2015). Lobotomizing the defense brain. The Review of Austrian Economics,28(4), 371–396. Coyne, C. (2015). Lobotomizing the defense brain. The Review of Austrian Economics,28(4), 371–396.
Zurück zum Zitat Demsetz, H. (1967). Toward a theory of property rights. American Economic Review,57, 347–359. Demsetz, H. (1967). Toward a theory of property rights. American Economic Review,57, 347–359.
Zurück zum Zitat Demsetz, H. (1970). The private production of public goods. Journal of Law and Economics,13, 293–306. Demsetz, H. (1970). The private production of public goods. Journal of Law and Economics,13, 293–306.
Zurück zum Zitat DeSoto, H. (1989). The other path: The economic answer to terrorism. New York, NY: Harper & Row. DeSoto, H. (1989). The other path: The economic answer to terrorism. New York, NY: Harper & Row.
Zurück zum Zitat Ekelund, R., & Dorton, C. (2003). Criminal justice institutions as a common pool: The nineteenth century analysis of Edwin Chadwick. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,50, 271–294. Ekelund, R., & Dorton, C. (2003). Criminal justice institutions as a common pool: The nineteenth century analysis of Edwin Chadwick. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,50, 271–294.
Zurück zum Zitat Ellickson, R. (1991). Order without law, how neighbors settle disputes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Ellickson, R. (1991). Order without law, how neighbors settle disputes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Ellickson, R. (1993). Property in land. Yale Law Journal,102, 1317–1400. Ellickson, R. (1993). Property in land. Yale Law Journal,102, 1317–1400.
Zurück zum Zitat Foldvary, F. (1994). Public goods and private communities: The market provision of social services. Aldershot, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing. Foldvary, F. (1994). Public goods and private communities: The market provision of social services. Aldershot, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.
Zurück zum Zitat Fukuyama, F. (2018). Identity: The demand for dignity and the politics of resentment. New York: Farrar, Strauss and Giroux. Fukuyama, F. (2018). Identity: The demand for dignity and the politics of resentment. New York: Farrar, Strauss and Giroux.
Zurück zum Zitat Gillespie, D. (2012). Challengers to duopoly: Why third parties matter in American two-party politics. Columbia, SC: University of South Carolina Press. Gillespie, D. (2012). Challengers to duopoly: Why third parties matter in American two-party politics. Columbia, SC: University of South Carolina Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Goldin, K. (1977). Equal access vs. selective access: A critique of public goods theory. Public Choice,29, 53–71. Goldin, K. (1977). Equal access vs. selective access: A critique of public goods theory. Public Choice,29, 53–71.
Zurück zum Zitat Hibbert, C. (1990). King mob: The story of Lord George Gordon and the riots of 1780. Dorset, UK: Dorset Press. Hibbert, C. (1990). King mob: The story of Lord George Gordon and the riots of 1780. Dorset, UK: Dorset Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Hill, P. (2014). Are all commons tragedies? The case of bison in the 19th century. The Independent Review,18(4), 485–502. Hill, P. (2014). Are all commons tragedies? The case of bison in the 19th century. The Independent Review,18(4), 485–502.
Zurück zum Zitat Hoig, S. (1993). Tribal wars of the southern plains. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press. Hoig, S. (1993). Tribal wars of the southern plains. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Holcombe, R. (1977). A theory of the theory of public goods. Review of Austrian Economics,10, 1–22. Holcombe, R. (1977). A theory of the theory of public goods. Review of Austrian Economics,10, 1–22.
Zurück zum Zitat Holcombe, R. (1994). The economic foundations of government. New York: New York University Press. Holcombe, R. (1994). The economic foundations of government. New York: New York University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Holder, P. (1970). The hoe and the horse on the plains: A study of cultural development among North American Indians. Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press. Holder, P. (1970). The hoe and the horse on the plains: A study of cultural development among North American Indians. Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Hume, D. (1957 [1751]) C. Hendel. (Ed.) An inquiry concerning the principles of morals. Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill. Hume, D. (1957 [1751]) C. Hendel. (Ed.) An inquiry concerning the principles of morals. Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill.
Zurück zum Zitat Hume, D. (1994[1741-42]). On the original contract. In K. Haakonssen (Ed.) Political essays. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Hume, D. (1994[1741-42]). On the original contract. In K. Haakonssen (Ed.) Political essays. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Kant, I. (1960). Religion within the limits of reason alone, T. Green and H. Hudson (Trs.) New York: Harper. Kant, I. (1960). Religion within the limits of reason alone, T. Green and H. Hudson (Trs.) New York: Harper.
Zurück zum Zitat Kirzner, I. (1985). Discovery and the capitalist process. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Kirzner, I. (1985). Discovery and the capitalist process. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Krebs, D., & Denton, K. (1997). Social illusions and self-deception: The evolution of biases in person perception. In J. Simpson & D. Kenrick (Eds.), Evolutionary social psychology. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. Krebs, D., & Denton, K. (1997). Social illusions and self-deception: The evolution of biases in person perception. In J. Simpson & D. Kenrick (Eds.), Evolutionary social psychology. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.
Zurück zum Zitat Kroszner, R., & Stratmann, T. (1998). Interest-group competition and the organization of congress: Theory and evidence form financial services’ political action committees. American Economic Review,88, 1163–1187. Kroszner, R., & Stratmann, T. (1998). Interest-group competition and the organization of congress: Theory and evidence form financial services’ political action committees. American Economic Review,88, 1163–1187.
Zurück zum Zitat Kurrild-Klitgaard, P., & Svendsen, G. (2003). Rational bandits: Plunder, public goods, and the Vikings. Public Choice,117(3), 255–272. Kurrild-Klitgaard, P., & Svendsen, G. (2003). Rational bandits: Plunder, public goods, and the Vikings. Public Choice,117(3), 255–272.
Zurück zum Zitat Lane, F. (1958/1979). Economic consequences of organized violence (pp. 50–65). In F. Lane (Ed.), Profit from power. New York: State University of New York. Lane, F. (1958/1979). Economic consequences of organized violence (pp. 50–65). In F. Lane (Ed.), Profit from power. New York: State University of New York.
Zurück zum Zitat Lee, D., & Buchanan, J. (1982). Tax rates and tax revenues in political equilibrium: Some simple analytics. Economic Inquiry,20, 344–354. Lee, D., & Buchanan, J. (1982). Tax rates and tax revenues in political equilibrium: Some simple analytics. Economic Inquiry,20, 344–354.
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. (2007a). Efficient anarchy. Public Choice,130(1), 41–53. Leeson, P. (2007a). Efficient anarchy. Public Choice,130(1), 41–53.
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. (2007b). Trading with bandits. Journal of Law and Economics,50(2), 303–321. Leeson, P. (2007b). Trading with bandits. Journal of Law and Economics,50(2), 303–321.
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. (2009). The invisible hook: The hidden economics of pirates. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Leeson, P. (2009). The invisible hook: The hidden economics of pirates. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P., & Williamson, C. (2009). Anarchy and development: An application of the theory of second best. The Law and Development Review,2(1), 76–96. Leeson, P., & Williamson, C. (2009). Anarchy and development: An application of the theory of second best. The Law and Development Review,2(1), 76–96.
Zurück zum Zitat Levi, M. (1988). Of rule and revenue. Berkeley: University of California Press. Levi, M. (1988). Of rule and revenue. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Lowie, R. (1954). Indians of the plain. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company. Lowie, R. (1954). Indians of the plain. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company.
Zurück zum Zitat McChesney, F. (1987). Rent extraction and rent creation in the economic theory of regulation. Journal of Legal Studies,16, 101–118. McChesney, F. (1987). Rent extraction and rent creation in the economic theory of regulation. Journal of Legal Studies,16, 101–118.
Zurück zum Zitat McNutt, P. (2000). Public goods and club goods. In B. Bouckaert & G. De Geest (Eds.), Encyclopedia of law and economics. Chelthenham, UK: Edward Elgar. McNutt, P. (2000). Public goods and club goods. In B. Bouckaert & G. De Geest (Eds.), Encyclopedia of law and economics. Chelthenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Zurück zum Zitat Meehan, B., & Benson, B. (2015). The occupation of regulators influences occupational regulation: Evidence from the U.S. private security industry. Public Choice,162(1), 97–117. Meehan, B., & Benson, B. (2015). The occupation of regulators influences occupational regulation: Evidence from the U.S. private security industry. Public Choice,162(1), 97–117.
Zurück zum Zitat Mishkin, B. (1940). Rank and warfare among the plains Indians. Monographs of the American Ethnological Society III. New York: J.J. Augustin Publisher. Mishkin, B. (1940). Rank and warfare among the plains Indians. Monographs of the American Ethnological Society III. New York: J.J. Augustin Publisher.
Zurück zum Zitat Moselle, B., & Polak, B. (2001). A model of a predatory state. Journal of Law Economics and Organization,17, 1–33. Moselle, B., & Polak, B. (2001). A model of a predatory state. Journal of Law Economics and Organization,17, 1–33.
Zurück zum Zitat Musto, D. (1973). The American disease: Origins of narcotic control. New Haven, CN: Yale University Press. Musto, D. (1973). The American disease: Origins of narcotic control. New Haven, CN: Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Nee, V. (1998). Norms and networks in economic and organizational performance. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings,88, 85–89. Nee, V. (1998). Norms and networks in economic and organizational performance. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings,88, 85–89.
Zurück zum Zitat Neely, R. (1982). Why courts don’t work. New York: McGraw-Hill. Neely, R. (1982). Why courts don’t work. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Zurück zum Zitat North, D. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: Norton. North, D. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: Norton.
Zurück zum Zitat North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat North, D., Wallis, J., Webb, S., & Weingast, B. (Eds.). (2012). In the shadow of violence: Politics, economics, and the problems of development. New York: Cambridge University Press. North, D., Wallis, J., Webb, S., & Weingast, B. (Eds.). (2012). In the shadow of violence: Politics, economics, and the problems of development. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat North, D., Wallis, J., & Weingast, B. (2009). Violence and social orders: A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. New York: Cambridge University Press. North, D., Wallis, J., & Weingast, B. (2009). Violence and social orders: A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy and development. American Political Science Review,87, 567–576. Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy and development. American Political Science Review,87, 567–576.
Zurück zum Zitat Oppenheimer, F. (1908 [1914]). The state: Its history and development viewed sociologically, J. Gitterman (Tr.). Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill. Oppenheimer, F. (1908 [1914]). The state: Its history and development viewed sociologically, J. Gitterman (Tr.). Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill.
Zurück zum Zitat Pollock, F. & Maitland, F. (1898 [1959]). The history of English law before the time of Edward I. Washington, DC: Lawyers’ Literary Library. Pollock, F. & Maitland, F. (1898 [1959]). The history of English law before the time of Edward I. Washington, DC: Lawyers’ Literary Library.
Zurück zum Zitat Pospisil, L. (1971). Anthropology of law: A comparative theory. New York: Harper and Row. Pospisil, L. (1971). Anthropology of law: A comparative theory. New York: Harper and Row.
Zurück zum Zitat Powell, B., & Stringham, E. (2009). Public choice and the economic analysis of anarchy: A survey. Public Choice,140(3), 503–538. Powell, B., & Stringham, E. (2009). Public choice and the economic analysis of anarchy: A survey. Public Choice,140(3), 503–538.
Zurück zum Zitat Reid, R. (1989). The Peterloo Massacre (1st ed.). William Heinemann Ltd (December 1). Reid, R. (1989). The Peterloo Massacre (1st ed.). William Heinemann Ltd (December 1).
Zurück zum Zitat Rider, R. (1993). War, pillage, and markets. Public Choice,75, 149–156. Rider, R. (1993). War, pillage, and markets. Public Choice,75, 149–156.
Zurück zum Zitat Rosenberg, N., & Birdzell, L. (1986). How the west grew rich: The economic transformation of the industrial world. New York: Basic Books. Rosenberg, N., & Birdzell, L. (1986). How the west grew rich: The economic transformation of the industrial world. New York: Basic Books.
Zurück zum Zitat Roth, G. (1996). Roads in a market economy. Aldershot, UK: Avebury Technical. Roth, G. (1996). Roads in a market economy. Aldershot, UK: Avebury Technical.
Zurück zum Zitat Skaperdas, S. (1992). Cooperation, conflict and power in the absence of property rights. American Economic Review,82, 720–739. Skaperdas, S. (1992). Cooperation, conflict and power in the absence of property rights. American Economic Review,82, 720–739.
Zurück zum Zitat Stratmann, T. (1991). What do campaign contributions buy? Deciphering causal effects of money and votes. Southern Economic Journal,57(3), 606–620. Stratmann, T. (1991). What do campaign contributions buy? Deciphering causal effects of money and votes. Southern Economic Journal,57(3), 606–620.
Zurück zum Zitat Stratmann, T. (1992). Are contributors rational: Untangled strategies of political action committees. Journal of Political Economy,100(3), 647–664. Stratmann, T. (1992). Are contributors rational: Untangled strategies of political action committees. Journal of Political Economy,100(3), 647–664.
Zurück zum Zitat Stratmann, T. (1998). The market for congressional votes: Is timing of contributions everything? Journal of Law and Economics,41(1), 85–114. Stratmann, T. (1998). The market for congressional votes: Is timing of contributions everything? Journal of Law and Economics,41(1), 85–114.
Zurück zum Zitat Stringham, E. (2015). Private governance, creating order in economic and social life. Oxford, NY: Oxford University Press. Stringham, E. (2015). Private governance, creating order in economic and social life. Oxford, NY: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Tilly, C. (1990). Coercion, capital and European states AD 900–1900. Oxford, UK: Blackwell. Tilly, C. (1990). Coercion, capital and European states AD 900–1900. Oxford, UK: Blackwell.
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies and theft. Western Economic Journal,5, 224–232. Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies and theft. Western Economic Journal,5, 224–232.
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1980). Rent seeking as a negative sum gain”. In J. Buchanan, R. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Towards a theory of a rent seeking society. College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press. Tullock, G. (1980). Rent seeking as a negative sum gain”. In J. Buchanan, R. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Towards a theory of a rent seeking society. College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Usher, D. (1992). The welfare economics of markets, voting and predation. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Usher, D. (1992). The welfare economics of markets, voting and predation. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Vahabi, M. (2016). A positive theory of the predatory state. Public Choice,168, 153–175. Vahabi, M. (2016). A positive theory of the predatory state. Public Choice,168, 153–175.
Metadaten
Titel
The development and evolution of predatory-state institutions and organizations: beliefs, violence, conquest, coercion, and rent seeking
verfasst von
Bruce L. Benson
Publikationsdatum
13.05.2019
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 3-4/2020
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00667-7

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3-4/2020

Public Choice 3-4/2020 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner