Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Empirical Economics 3/2006

01.09.2006 | original paper

The distributional effects of selection and capital accumulation on firm productivity under imperfect capital markets

verfasst von: Elliott Parker, Mark Pingle

Erschienen in: Empirical Economics | Ausgabe 3/2006

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In this evolutionary model, random shocks create differences in the rate of return on capital, while individual saving and investment behavior can reduce these differences over time. Firms with either low total factor productivity (TFP) or a low average return on capital are selected for exit, and new firms enter to take their place. As would be expected, a higher turnover rate improves TFP and reduces its variation. While we show that a higher turnover rate would result in a more positively skewed TFP distribution if exit selection is based directly upon TFP, we find that when we select firms for exit based on their average product of capital, the marginal impact of a higher turnover rate is to more negatively skew the TFP distribution. Overall, our simulations highlight the importance of considering the role selection may play in shaping the distribution of productivity when econometricians seek estimates of firm inefficiency.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
Kumbhakar and Orea (2004) and Giannakas et al. (2003) are recent examples of this type of research in this journal.
 
2
In doing so, we are following Jovanovic (1982), who cites evidence that small firms grow faster than large firms but are also more likely to fail, and creates a model of “‘noisy’ selection” to explain why.
 
3
As of June, 2001, when this research began, Econlit listed 217 citations for the stochastic frontier approach since 1977, and 365 citations for the data envelopment approach since 1985. In the past few years, citations for the former approach are around half those for the latter approach, suggesting that the former method is gradually being replaced by the latter.
 
4
See, for example, Ericson and Pakes (1995) for a description and model of this process.
 
5
Cargill and Parker (2002) used a simulation of a Walrasian tattonment process, but it is computationally demanding.
 
6
Parker (1995) and Cargill and Parker (2002) assumed that this shock was exponentially normal, of the form \(a_{{it}} = a_{{i,t - 1}} \;e^{{\varepsilon _{{it}} }}\). While this has the benefit of ensuring that TFP is always positive, it biases the results towards a positive skew. However, we tested the simulation in Section 4 by re-running it with the exponential shock; in re-estimating the response function, we found the marginal effects not significantly affected.
 
7
Of course, bankruptcy as a legal process is rarely so optimal. Managers may be willing to continue operating a loss-making firm if they can hide information on the firm’s poor long-run potential from the owners. Creditors with first priority of repayment may force a potentially productive firm to liquidate to ensure that they do not have to accept a loss on their investment.
 
8
We chose 20 iterations because it was long enough to observe changes in the distribution of productivity. We also tested whether our results were sensitive to this duration by rerunning our results for 50 iterations. While coefficient values obviously changed, the sign and statistical significance of these coefficients, as reported in Tables 3, 4, and 5, did not change in either the end or trend regressions.
 
9
We thank the editor for raising the issue of changing the number of firms. An interesting extension of this work would be to change the assumptions of the model so that the number of firms is endogenously determined, say by replacing constant returns to scale with decreasing returns. Then, one could systematically examine how changing the economic environment not only changes the number of firms in an economy with selection, but also changes the mean, variance and skew of total factor productivity.
 
10
The changes in these preference parameters did not significantly influence the results.
 
11
We simulated the estimation of current consumption with different parameter sets for many values of Z. We found that consumption estimates were wildly unstable for values of Z below 5, so the stable arm of the growth path is clearly not linear. However, for Z≥10, we found that the consumption estimates started to converge asymptotically. The estimates obtained for Z=25 were very close to the estimates for T=10,000.
 
12
Each case is a separate simulation, and small differences are to be expected due to differences in the random shocks.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Aigner D, Lovell CA CAK, Schmidt P (1977) Formulation and estimation of stochastic frontier production function models. Journal of Econometrics 6:21–37MATHMathSciNetCrossRef Aigner D, Lovell CA CAK, Schmidt P (1977) Formulation and estimation of stochastic frontier production function models. Journal of Econometrics 6:21–37MATHMathSciNetCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alchian AA (1950) Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy 63:211–221 Alchian AA (1950) Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy 63:211–221
Zurück zum Zitat Barro RJ, Sala-I-Martin X (1995) Economic Growth. McGraw-Hill, New York Barro RJ, Sala-I-Martin X (1995) Economic Growth. McGraw-Hill, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Bartelsman EJ, Dhrymes P (1998) Productivity dynamics: U.S. manufacturing plants, 1972–1986. Journal of Productivity Analysis 9:5–34CrossRef Bartelsman EJ, Dhrymes P (1998) Productivity dynamics: U.S. manufacturing plants, 1972–1986. Journal of Productivity Analysis 9:5–34CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cargill TF, Parker E (2002) Asian finance and the role of bankruptcy: a model of the transition costs of financial liberalization. Journal of Asian Economics 13:297–318CrossRef Cargill TF, Parker E (2002) Asian finance and the role of bankruptcy: a model of the transition costs of financial liberalization. Journal of Asian Economics 13:297–318CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carree MA (2002) Technological inefficiency and the skewness of the error component in stochastic frontier analysis. Economic Letters 77:101–107MATHCrossRef Carree MA (2002) Technological inefficiency and the skewness of the error component in stochastic frontier analysis. Economic Letters 77:101–107MATHCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cass D (1965) Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation. Review of Economic Studies 32:233–240CrossRef Cass D (1965) Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation. Review of Economic Studies 32:233–240CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Charnes A, Cooper WW, Rhodes E (1978) Measuring the efficiency of decision-making units. European Journal of Operational Research 3:392–444MathSciNet Charnes A, Cooper WW, Rhodes E (1978) Measuring the efficiency of decision-making units. European Journal of Operational Research 3:392–444MathSciNet
Zurück zum Zitat Dwyer DW (1998) Technology locks, creative destruction, and non-convergence in productivity levels. Review of Economic Dynamics 1:430–473CrossRef Dwyer DW (1998) Technology locks, creative destruction, and non-convergence in productivity levels. Review of Economic Dynamics 1:430–473CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ericson R, Pakes A (1995) Markov-perfect industry dynamics: a framework for empirical work. Review of Economic Studies 62:53–82MATHCrossRef Ericson R, Pakes A (1995) Markov-perfect industry dynamics: a framework for empirical work. Review of Economic Studies 62:53–82MATHCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Foster L, Haltiwanger J, Krizan CJ (1998) Aggregate productivity growth: Lessons from microeconomic evidence. NBER, working paper 6803, Cambridge, MA, USA Foster L, Haltiwanger J, Krizan CJ (1998) Aggregate productivity growth: Lessons from microeconomic evidence. NBER, working paper 6803, Cambridge, MA, USA
Zurück zum Zitat Giannakas K, Tran KC, Tzouvelekas V (2003) On the choice of functional form in stochastic frontier modeling. Empirical Economics 28:75–100CrossRef Giannakas K, Tran KC, Tzouvelekas V (2003) On the choice of functional form in stochastic frontier modeling. Empirical Economics 28:75–100CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Green A, Mayes D (1991) Technical inefficiency in manufacturing industries. Economic Journal 101:523–538CrossRef Green A, Mayes D (1991) Technical inefficiency in manufacturing industries. Economic Journal 101:523–538CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Koopmans TC (1965) On the concept of optimal economic growth. In The Economic Approach to Development Planning. Elsevier, Amsterdam Koopmans TC (1965) On the concept of optimal economic growth. In The Economic Approach to Development Planning. Elsevier, Amsterdam
Zurück zum Zitat Kumbhakar SC, Orea L (2004) Efficiency measurement using a latent class stochastic frontier, Empirical Economics 29:169–183CrossRef Kumbhakar SC, Orea L (2004) Efficiency measurement using a latent class stochastic frontier, Empirical Economics 29:169–183CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Levinsohn J, Petrin A (1999) When industries become more productive, do firms? Investigating productivity dynamics. NBER, working paper 6893, Cambridge, MA, USA Levinsohn J, Petrin A (1999) When industries become more productive, do firms? Investigating productivity dynamics. NBER, working paper 6893, Cambridge, MA, USA
Zurück zum Zitat Montgomery E, Wascher W (1988) Creative destruction and the behavior of productivity over the business cycle. Review of Economics and Statistics 70:168–172CrossRef Montgomery E, Wascher W (1988) Creative destruction and the behavior of productivity over the business cycle. Review of Economics and Statistics 70:168–172CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Parker E (1995) Schumpeterian creative destruction and the growth of Chinese enterprises. China Economic Review 6:201–223CrossRef Parker E (1995) Schumpeterian creative destruction and the growth of Chinese enterprises. China Economic Review 6:201–223CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pinker S (1997) How the mind works. W.W.Norton, New York Pinker S (1997) How the mind works. W.W.Norton, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Ramsey FP (1928) A mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal 38:543–559CrossRef Ramsey FP (1928) A mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal 38:543–559CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rigby DL, Essletzbichler J (2000) Impacts of industry mix, technological change, selection and plant entry/exit on regional productivity growth. Regional Studies 34:333–342CrossRef Rigby DL, Essletzbichler J (2000) Impacts of industry mix, technological change, selection and plant entry/exit on regional productivity growth. Regional Studies 34:333–342CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
The distributional effects of selection and capital accumulation on firm productivity under imperfect capital markets
verfasst von
Elliott Parker
Mark Pingle
Publikationsdatum
01.09.2006
Verlag
Physica-Verlag
Erschienen in
Empirical Economics / Ausgabe 3/2006
Print ISSN: 0377-7332
Elektronische ISSN: 1435-8921
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-005-0046-1

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3/2006

Empirical Economics 3/2006 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner