Skip to main content

2015 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

The Emergence of Technological Paradigms: The Evolutionary Process of Science and Technology in Economic Development

verfasst von : Keiichiro Suenaga

Erschienen in: The Evolution of Economic and Innovation Systems

Verlag: Springer International Publishing

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

While the prospects for the world economy, especially advanced economies, are uncertain, and the fundamental solutions to important problems such as environmental problems have not yet been found, the emergence or development of new technological paradigms is expected. The emergence of technological paradigms is a most important phenomenon in economic development. In this paper, the relationship between science and technology will be classified using four diagrammatic models, and the hierarchy of technological paradigms and the characteristics of each hierarchy will be clarified in order to consider the emergence of these technological paradigms. In addition, this paper mentions the implications for the corporate strategy of R&D, science and technology policy, and economic theory.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
When discussing advances in science and technology, it is necessary to divide each stock and flow clearly. That is, existing scientific or technological knowledge is a ‘stock’, and advances in scientific or technological knowledge are a ‘flow’. Although the knowledge of science or technology is a state function and it can accumulate, the progress of science or technology is a process and is transitional. [With regard to this paragraph, see also Kline (1990) and Stokes (1997)].
 
2
Needless to say, scientists may obtain economic rewards through IPR or academic spin-offs.
 
3
Although there are many engineers who do not personally operate for economic reward, they aim for the economic reward of their company.
 
4
It goes without saying that Price did not deny that science and technology have interacted.
 
5
Although Chesbrough (2003) illustrates the relationship between science and technology (research and development) in order to compare ‘closed innovation’ with ‘open innovation’, the relationship takes a linear form in his model.
 
6
Stokes’s model does not illustrate the technological paradigms.
 
7
A technological paradigm is a ‘“model” and a “pattern” of solution of selected technological problems, based on selected principles derived from natural sciences and on selected material technologies’; a technological trajectory is ‘the pattern of “normal” problem solving activity (i.e. of “progress”) on the ground of a technological paradigm’ (Dosi 1982, p. 152).
 
8
Although, in Yamaguchi’s diagram, technology, such as the refinement method of a hermetic art, and knowledge of a chemical reaction are contained in ‘knowledge creation’, they are not contained in ‘science’ in this paper.
 
9
The problems of the Bush model (linear model) are pointed out in Sect. 4.
 
10
Whether these advances are improvements along a technological trajectory or a shift in paradigm, with new technological trajectories emerging, depends on whether the ‘selected scientific knowledge’ as the basis of the technological trajectory is new or not (even if scientific knowledge precedes technological knowledge as in the Bush model, or technological knowledge precedes scientific knowledge as in the Rosenberg model).
 
11
See also Suenaga (2011) for the discussion in detail.
 
12
Therefore, it can also be interpreted as follows: If seen from the 3rd layer, the change from ‘1-a’ to ‘1-b’ and the change from ‘2-a’ to ‘2-b’ will be the technological trajectory in the technological paradigm ‘3-b’. If seen from the 2nd layer, the change from ‘1-a’ to ‘1-b’ will be the technological trajectory in the technological paradigm ‘2-a’. If seen from the 1st layer, the change from the grown junction method to the alloy junction method will be the technological trajectory in the technological paradigm ‘1-b’. According to this interpretation, whether a specific change is an improvement along a technological trajectory or a shift in paradigm, with new technological trajectories emerging, depends on the layer from which it is seen. Moreover, although the scientific knowledge can also still be classified in detail, it will be enough just to clarify the existence of the hierarchy of scientific knowledge, or a technological paradigm, since the purpose here is to discuss essentials.
Of course, an old technological paradigm and a new technological paradigm may coexist. The vacuum tube and the semiconductor coexist, and the same may be said about the bipolar transistor and MOSFET. Moreover, science and technology affect each other mutually, and the chain (co-evolution) of science and technology forms an evolutionary system. For example, the invention of the point contact type transistor, based on the discovery of Walter H. Brattain and John Bardeen, led to William B. Shockley’s scientific knowledge about the junction type transistor, and the grown junction technology was based on Shockley’s scientific knowledge. Furthermore, the invention of MOSFET also led to advances in scientific knowledge about the quantum Hall effect by Klaus von Klitzing. That is, science provides the technological sources of a scientific question, technology also does so, and various feedback mechanisms exist between science and technology (also refer to Sect. 1.2).
 
13
Although we need to analyze the various examples, Yamaguchi’s analyses (2006, 2008, 2009) about the Industrial Revolution and other cases are extremely interesting.
 
14
For example, the Middle Eastern conflict affects the direction for seeking alternative energy sources. Although Dosi (1982, p. 156) mentions that ‘scope for substitution … is limited by the technology which itself defines the range of possible technological advances’, Yamaguchi’s model suggests that advances in scientific knowledge which generate new technological paradigms have an important role.
 
15
In this process, lock-in effects or path-dependency have an important influence.
 
16
About this phrase; see also Freeman and Perez (1988). ‘It is only when productivity along the old trajectories shows persistent limits to growth and future profits are seriously threatened that the high risks and costs of trying the new technologies appear as clearly justified’ (p. 49).
 
17
This is an important factor for long business fluctuations.
 
18
Refer also to Nonaka and Takeuchi (1995) in regard to the role of the ‘field’ in knowledge creation. They analyze the ‘field’ for changing tacit knowledge into explicit knowledge in the SECI model of knowledge creation.
 
19
See also Rosenberg (1990) in regard to this example. Rosenberg also discusses the relationship between scientific knowledge and technological knowledge in detail.
 
20
The reason the transistor was created in the Bell laboratory was that many specialists in various academic realms worked in the same field, transmitted tacit knowledge, and drew inspiration from each other. ‘All in all, the people playing a major role at one time or another in the work which led to the transistor discovery may have numbered about thirteen’ (Nelson 1962, p. 560).
 
21
For example, this argument is also related to arguments such as ‘More Moore’, ‘More than Moore’, and ‘Beyond CMOS’. Let me define ‘More Moore’ as ‘to pursue micro-fabrication on silicon CMOS’, ‘More than Moore’ as ‘to create new value through combinations of technology’, and ‘Beyond CMOS’ as ‘to bring forth new devices based on new connections or principles’. Although they do not necessarily correspond completely, it follows that ‘More Moore’ and ‘More than Moore’ represent paradigm-sustaining innovation. New devices based on new connections are paradigm-disruptive innovation in the first layer, and new devices based on new principles are paradigm-disruptive innovation in the second layer. Finally, paradigm disruptive innovation in the third layer is a device based on an academic framework, which is different to quantum mechanics (referred to here as ‘Beyond Quantum’).
 
22
See also the discussions about techno-economic paradigms and long waves, such as Freeman and Perez (1988).
 
23
See Chesbrough (2003) about open innovation.
 
24
This is related to the discussion about the relationship between diversity and innovation.
 
25
Suenaga (2012) examines the role of local government, focusing on IMEC in Belgium. In Japan, central government plays a significant role in implementation of science and technology policy and declines the degree of globalization about research and development in Japan. The example of IMEC has significant implications for Japan.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Aghion P, David PA, Foray D (2009) Science, technology and innovation for economic growth: linking policy research and practice in ‘STIG Systems’. Res Policy 38:681–693CrossRef Aghion P, David PA, Foray D (2009) Science, technology and innovation for economic growth: linking policy research and practice in ‘STIG Systems’. Res Policy 38:681–693CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bach L, Matt M (2005) From economic foundations to S&T policy tools: a comparative analysis of the dominant paradigms. In: Llerena P, Matt M (eds) Innovation policy in a knowledge-based economy, ch. 1. Springer, Berlin, pp 17–45CrossRef Bach L, Matt M (2005) From economic foundations to S&T policy tools: a comparative analysis of the dominant paradigms. In: Llerena P, Matt M (eds) Innovation policy in a knowledge-based economy, ch. 1. Springer, Berlin, pp 17–45CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brooks H (1994) The relationship between science and technology. Res Policy 23:477–486CrossRef Brooks H (1994) The relationship between science and technology. Res Policy 23:477–486CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bush V (1945) Science the endless frontier. United States Government Printing Office, Washington, DC Bush V (1945) Science the endless frontier. United States Government Printing Office, Washington, DC
Zurück zum Zitat Chesbrough H (2003) Open innovation: a new imperative for creating and profiting from technology. Harvard Business School Corporation, Boston, MA Chesbrough H (2003) Open innovation: a new imperative for creating and profiting from technology. Harvard Business School Corporation, Boston, MA
Zurück zum Zitat Cimoli M, Dosi G (1995) Technological paradigms, patterns of learning and development: an introductory roadmap. J Evol Econ 5:243–268CrossRef Cimoli M, Dosi G (1995) Technological paradigms, patterns of learning and development: an introductory roadmap. J Evol Econ 5:243–268CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dasgupta P, David PA (1994) Toward a new economics of science. Res Policy 23:487–521CrossRef Dasgupta P, David PA (1994) Toward a new economics of science. Res Policy 23:487–521CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dosi G (1982) Technological paradigms and technological trajectories. Res Policy 11:147–162CrossRef Dosi G (1982) Technological paradigms and technological trajectories. Res Policy 11:147–162CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dosi G (1984) Technical change and industrial transformation: the theory and an application to the semiconductor industry. Macmillan Press, London Dosi G (1984) Technical change and industrial transformation: the theory and an application to the semiconductor industry. Macmillan Press, London
Zurück zum Zitat Dosi G (1988) Sources, procedures, and microeconomic effects of innovation. J Econ Lit 26:1120–1171 Dosi G (1988) Sources, procedures, and microeconomic effects of innovation. J Econ Lit 26:1120–1171
Zurück zum Zitat Freeman C, Perez C (1988) Structural crises of adjustment, business cycles and investment behaviour. In: Dosi G et al (eds) Technical change and economic theory. Pinter Publishers, London, pp 38–66 Freeman C, Perez C (1988) Structural crises of adjustment, business cycles and investment behaviour. In: Dosi G et al (eds) Technical change and economic theory. Pinter Publishers, London, pp 38–66
Zurück zum Zitat Freeman C, Soete L (1997) The economics of industrial innovation, 3rd edn. Routledge, London Freeman C, Soete L (1997) The economics of industrial innovation, 3rd edn. Routledge, London
Zurück zum Zitat Kline SJ (1990) Innovation style in Japan and the United States: cultural bases; implications for competitiveness. Stanford University Press, Stanford Kline SJ (1990) Innovation style in Japan and the United States: cultural bases; implications for competitiveness. Stanford University Press, Stanford
Zurück zum Zitat Kuznets SS (1966) Modern economic growth: rate, structure and spread. Yale University Press, New Haven Kuznets SS (1966) Modern economic growth: rate, structure and spread. Yale University Press, New Haven
Zurück zum Zitat Merton RK (1973) The sociology of science: theoretical and empirical investigations. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago Merton RK (1973) The sociology of science: theoretical and empirical investigations. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago
Zurück zum Zitat Nelson RR (1962) The link between science and invention: the case of the transistor. In: Nelson RR (ed) The rate and direction of inventive activity: economic and social factors. Princeton University Press, Princeton Nelson RR (1962) The link between science and invention: the case of the transistor. In: Nelson RR (ed) The rate and direction of inventive activity: economic and social factors. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Zurück zum Zitat Nightingale P (1998) A cognitive model of innovation. Res Policy 27:689–709CrossRef Nightingale P (1998) A cognitive model of innovation. Res Policy 27:689–709CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nonaka I, Takeuchi H (1995) The knowledge-creating company: how Japanese companies create the dynamics of innovation. Oxford University Press, New York Nonaka I, Takeuchi H (1995) The knowledge-creating company: how Japanese companies create the dynamics of innovation. Oxford University Press, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Pavitt K (1998) The social shaping of the national science base. Res Policy 27:793–805CrossRef Pavitt K (1998) The social shaping of the national science base. Res Policy 27:793–805CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat de Solla Price DJ (1965) Is technology historically independent of science? A study in statistical historiography. Technol Cult 6:553–568CrossRef de Solla Price DJ (1965) Is technology historically independent of science? A study in statistical historiography. Technol Cult 6:553–568CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rosenberg N (1982) Inside the black box: technology and economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Rosenberg N (1982) Inside the black box: technology and economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Zurück zum Zitat Rosenberg N (1990) Why do firms do basic research (with their own money)? Res Policy 19:165–174CrossRef Rosenberg N (1990) Why do firms do basic research (with their own money)? Res Policy 19:165–174CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schumpeter JA (1934) The theory of economic development. Oxford University Press, Oxford Schumpeter JA (1934) The theory of economic development. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Zurück zum Zitat Stokes DE (1997) Pasteur’s quadrant: basic science and technological innovation. Brookings Institution Press, Washington, DC Stokes DE (1997) Pasteur’s quadrant: basic science and technological innovation. Brookings Institution Press, Washington, DC
Zurück zum Zitat Suenaga K (2011) The soil layers of innovation diagram. Paper presented at the Doshisha University Graduate School (in Japanese) Suenaga K (2011) The soil layers of innovation diagram. Paper presented at the Doshisha University Graduate School (in Japanese)
Zurück zum Zitat Suenaga K (2012) The role of local government in an era of open innovation: an analysis based on the example of a Flemish government-funded NPO. J Urban Manag Local Gov Res 27(2):1–10 Suenaga K (2012) The role of local government in an era of open innovation: an analysis based on the example of a Flemish government-funded NPO. J Urban Manag Local Gov Res 27(2):1–10
Zurück zum Zitat Yamaguchi E (2006) Innovation: paradigm disruptions and fields of resonance. NTT Publishing (in Japanese) Yamaguchi E (2006) Innovation: paradigm disruptions and fields of resonance. NTT Publishing (in Japanese)
Zurück zum Zitat Yamaguchi E (2008) Industrial revolution as paradigm disruptive innovations. Organ Sci 42(1):37–47 (in Japanese) Yamaguchi E (2008) Industrial revolution as paradigm disruptive innovations. Organ Sci 42(1):37–47 (in Japanese)
Zurück zum Zitat Yamaguchi E (2009) What is ‘Mekiki-ryoku’ of technology. Nikkei Tech-On, Feb–Mar (in Japanese) Yamaguchi E (2009) What is ‘Mekiki-ryoku’ of technology. Nikkei Tech-On, Feb–Mar (in Japanese)
Metadaten
Titel
The Emergence of Technological Paradigms: The Evolutionary Process of Science and Technology in Economic Development
verfasst von
Keiichiro Suenaga
Copyright-Jahr
2015
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-13299-0_10

Premium Partner