Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 3-4/2013

01.12.2013

The influence of direct democracy on the shadow economy

verfasst von: Désirée Teobaldelli, Friedrich Schneider

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 3-4/2013

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We analyze, both theoretically and empirically, the influence of direct democratic institutions on the size and development of shadow economies. Our model suggests that, as the extent of direct democracy increases, implemented fiscal policies more nearly reflect the preferences of citizens and so reduce their incentives to operate in the informal sector. This theory implies a negative relationship between the extent of direct democracy and the size of the country’s shadow economy. We also theorize that direct democracy has a greater effect in reducing the informal sector when the former is at low or intermediate values and when the electoral system is characterized by a larger district magnitude. An empirical investigation of a sample of 57 democracies confirms our model’s predictions.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
Similarly, Pommerehne and Schneider (1978) and Frey (1994) show that popular referendums increase the likelihood that voters control the policy choices of governments.
 
2
The analysis developed herein is close in spirit to the works on fiscal decentralization and the shadow economy (Torgler et al. 2010; Teobaldelli 2011) that demonstrate how federal institutions improve fiscal policies as well as government accountability to citizens, both of which end up reducing the informal sector’s size. Schneider and Enste (2002) were the first to recognize that proper elements of direct democracy, together with fiscal federalism, might strengthen public trust in political institutions and reduce the size of the shadow economy.
 
4
We refer to G as public goods and services, but it could also be interpreted as publicly provided private goods and services. One justification for hypothesizing that G does not enter the informal sector’s production function is that informal producers are unable to take full advantage of public services (e.g., social welfare, skill training programs) or government-sponsored credit facilities that could improve the production process. Moreover, according to Loayza (1996) and Johnson et al. (1997), the illegal status of informal agents prevents them from benefiting from government-provided goods and services. Examples of such benefits include being able to secure full enforceable property rights over their capital and output (through the legal and judicial system) and enjoying police protection from crimes committed against that property.
 
5
The status quo policy is assumed to be chosen randomly by nature at the beginning of the period. In a dynamic setting, the status quo policy could be interpreted as the policy implemented in the previous period.
 
6
Direct democracy identifies a variety of political processes that assign to ordinary citizens the right to decide directly on certain political issues through popular votes. All forms of direct democracy deal with the decision of citizens on substantive laws listed on the ballot, which are known as ballot measures or propositions. Ballot measures can concern either the proposal of a new law or the abolition of an old law. There are differences in how propositions are placed on the ballot. We can distinguish between an initiative, which allows citizens to propose new laws (constitutional or more ordinary legislation) of varying scopes, and a referendum, which is a vote on a law already approved by the legislature. Both forms of direct democracy allow citizens to control the agenda and typically require a predetermined number of signatures from eligible voters to qualify for the ballot. In order to simplify the analysis, we do not distinguish between these types and use the term “referendum” to signify any means of enabling citizens to intervene directly in the political process.
 
7
In the standard model of retrospective voting, individuals coordinate on the same retrospective voting strategy; this leads to reelection of the incumbent when the policy provides a utility to voters that exceeds some endogenous threshold. Our setting of the voters’ reservation utility at the exogenous level of the status quo policy (rather than allowing it to be endogenous) does not affect the main results; it changes only the rents of the politician and voters. Our assumption that the incumbent’s punishment is associated with a strictly positive reelection probability (rather than zero) can be viewed as the reduced form of a more general model in which politicians differ along multiple dimensions (e.g., competence, ideology) and voters do not have the same preferences or information about the politician. Observe also that this assumption is relevant only to our analysis of the interaction between direct democracy and other institutional details.
 
8
Persson and Tabellini (2000, 2003) explain the link between district magnitude and the electoral formula in terms of larger districts being associated with proportional electoral systems and smaller districts associated with majoritarian systems. Majoritarian elections reduce politicians’ rents because voters in marginal districts are more mobile and electoral competition is stiffer, which implies that citizens can punish politicians more severely for wasteful spending.
 
9
Our approach recognizes that promotion of a referendum may be characterized by the standard collective action problems (Olson [1965] 1971) typical of rebellions (e.g., Tullock 1971; Silver 1974; Kurrild-Klitgaard 1997); for a review of this literature and open issues, see Kurrild-Klitgaard (2004). For this reason, we assume that the promotion of a referendum involves private costs and benefits related to the process itself. The positive effect of direct democracy on the probability that the referendum takes place can be explained by any framework under which such probability is increasing in number of citizens who mobilize relative to a required threshold. This means that the same result obtains also in a model where direct democracy reduces the number of individuals necessary for the promotion of the referendum. However, it seems reasonable to assume that higher levels of direct democracy are associated with lower thresholds required for a referendum to occur or with simpler and less costly procedures for the promoters.
 
10
The next two lemmas are similar to Lemmas 1 and 3, respectively, in Teobaldelli (2011); their proofs, together with those of Lemmas 3–5 and Corollary 1, are given in Online Appendix.
 
11
In writing the maximized net income of the individuals in (5), we have used the government’s budget constraint (2) and also that all individuals are identical.
 
12
The only country ranked as high as 7 is Switzerland, and there are more countries (25) ranked 1 than any other value.
 
13
In other words, it allows us to account for even the quality of procedures underlying popular initiatives and referendums intended to propose, approve, amend, or remove laws. In clarifying this point, Fiorino and Ricciuti cite the case of Belarus: even though nine referendums were held in this country from 1995 to 2004, Belarus still receives the lowest possible ranking; the reasons are that (a) the referendums were proposed and used by President Lukashenko to amplify his power at the legislature’s expense and (b) a positive outcome was secured thanks to arrests of political adversaries and pressure on citizens.
 
14
District magnitude determines how many legislators are elected in a typical voting district. The index used here comes from Persson and Tabellini (2003) and is defined as the ratio of the number of districts to the number of seats in the country’s lower house; the index is thus an inverse measure of districts’ average size. It takes the value 1 in a UK-style system with (single-member districts) and a value slightly above 0 in an Israeli-style system (a single national district from which all legislators are elected). As discussed in Persson and Tabellini (2000, 2003), district magnitude is strongly correlated with the electoral system (this correlation is 0.84 in our sample): electoral districts tend to be large in proportional systems and small in majoritarian ones.
 
15
According to Persson and Tabellini (2003), the age of a democracy may have important effects on the policies implemented in that mature democracies might adopt systematically different policies than young ones. For example: welfare-state programs are strongly associated with democracies, but the decision to establish these programs (e.g., public pension systems) may take a long time. Moreover, some important constitutional features may be correlated with the period during which a democratic form of governance was adopted.
 
16
We use the GDP of 1960 in order to avoid possible endogeneity problems with respect to the dependent variable.
 
17
It is worth emphasizing that the index of religious fractionalization measures a society’s religious heterogeneity and therefore captures different phenomena than do the variables used for the type of religion that is most diffused in the country.
 
18
We remark that an absence of nonlinear effects resulting from direct democracy need not be at odds with our model’s predictions since the region in which the politician adopts a prevention strategy may simply be too small for such effects to manifest.
 
19
Column 1 shows the estimate when we include only the indexes related to direct democracy and district magnitude; this estimate is reported as a robustness check.
 
20
That the estimated marginal effects are positive for DDI values of 6 and 7 is due to the quadratic form used in the estimation; however, these coefficients are not statistically significantly different from zero. Recall that DDI=7 for only one country (Switzerland).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation. The American Economic Review, 91, 1369–1401. CrossRef Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation. The American Economic Review, 91, 1369–1401. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2005). Institutions as the fundamental cause of long-run economic growth. In P. Aghion & S. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of economic growth (Vol. 1A, pp. 386–414). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2005). Institutions as the fundamental cause of long-run economic growth. In P. Aghion & S. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of economic growth (Vol. 1A, pp. 386–414). Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Zurück zum Zitat Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., & Wacziarg, R. (2003). Fractionalization. Journal of Economic Growth, 8, 155–194. CrossRef Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., & Wacziarg, R. (2003). Fractionalization. Journal of Economic Growth, 8, 155–194. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alt, J., & Lassen, D. (2003). The political economy of institutions and corruption in American states. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 5(3), 341–365. CrossRef Alt, J., & Lassen, D. (2003). The political economy of institutions and corruption in American states. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 5(3), 341–365. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barro, R. (1973). The control of politicians: an economic model. Public Choice, 14, 19–42. CrossRef Barro, R. (1973). The control of politicians: an economic model. Public Choice, 14, 19–42. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blomberg, S., Hess, G., & Weerapana, A. (2004). The impact of voters initiatives on economic activity. European Journal of Political Economy, 20(1), 207–226. CrossRef Blomberg, S., Hess, G., & Weerapana, A. (2004). The impact of voters initiatives on economic activity. European Journal of Political Economy, 20(1), 207–226. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blume, L., Müller, J., & Voigt, S. (2009). The economic effects of direct democracy—a first global assessment. Public Choice, 140, 431–461. CrossRef Blume, L., Müller, J., & Voigt, S. (2009). The economic effects of direct democracy—a first global assessment. Public Choice, 140, 431–461. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Borooah, V. K., & Paldam, M. (2007). Why is the world short of democracy? A cross-country analysis of barriers to representative government. European Journal of Political Economy, 23, 582–604. CrossRef Borooah, V. K., & Paldam, M. (2007). Why is the world short of democracy? A cross-country analysis of barriers to representative government. European Journal of Political Economy, 23, 582–604. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dell’Anno, R., & Teobaldelli, D. (2012). Keeping both corruption and the shadow economy in check: the role of decentralization. Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics. WP-EMS 2012/13. Dell’Anno, R., & Teobaldelli, D. (2012). Keeping both corruption and the shadow economy in check: the role of decentralization. Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics. WP-EMS 2012/13.
Zurück zum Zitat Feld, L. P., & Frey, B. S. (2002). Trust breeds trust: how taxpayers are treated. Economics of Governance, 3, 87–99. CrossRef Feld, L. P., & Frey, B. S. (2002). Trust breeds trust: how taxpayers are treated. Economics of Governance, 3, 87–99. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Feld, L. P., & Kirchgässner, G. (2001a). Does direct democracy reduce public debt? Evidence from Swiss municipalities. Public Choice, 109(3), 181–213. Feld, L. P., & Kirchgässner, G. (2001a). Does direct democracy reduce public debt? Evidence from Swiss municipalities. Public Choice, 109(3), 181–213.
Zurück zum Zitat Feld, L. P., & Kirchgässner, G. (2001b). The political economy of direct legislation: direct democracy and local decision-making. Economic Policy, 33, 229–263. Feld, L. P., & Kirchgässner, G. (2001b). The political economy of direct legislation: direct democracy and local decision-making. Economic Policy, 33, 229–263.
Zurück zum Zitat Feld, L. P., & Matsusaka, J. G. (2003). Budget referendums and government spending: evidence from Swiss cantons. Journal of Public Economics, 87, 2703–2724. CrossRef Feld, L. P., & Matsusaka, J. G. (2003). Budget referendums and government spending: evidence from Swiss cantons. Journal of Public Economics, 87, 2703–2724. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Feld, L. P., & Tyran, J.-R. (2002). Tax evasion and voting: an experimental analysis. Kyklos, 55(2), 197–222. CrossRef Feld, L. P., & Tyran, J.-R. (2002). Tax evasion and voting: an experimental analysis. Kyklos, 55(2), 197–222. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ferejohn, J. (1986). Incumbent performance and electoral control. Public Choice, 30(2–3), 5–25. CrossRef Ferejohn, J. (1986). Incumbent performance and electoral control. Public Choice, 30(2–3), 5–25. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fiorino, N., & Ricciuti, R. (2007). Determinants of direct democracy. CESifo working papers No. 2035. Fiorino, N., & Ricciuti, R. (2007). Determinants of direct democracy. CESifo working papers No. 2035.
Zurück zum Zitat Frey, B. S. (1994). Direct democracy: politico-economic lessons from Swiss experience. The American Economic Review, 84(2), 338–342. Frey, B. S. (1994). Direct democracy: politico-economic lessons from Swiss experience. The American Economic Review, 84(2), 338–342.
Zurück zum Zitat Frey, B. S. (1997). Constitution for knaves crowds out civic virtues. The Economic Journal, 110, 918–938. CrossRef Frey, B. S. (1997). Constitution for knaves crowds out civic virtues. The Economic Journal, 110, 918–938. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Friedman, E., Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., & Zoido–Lobaton, P. (2000). Dodging the grabbing hand: the determinants of unofficial activity in 69 countries. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 459–493. CrossRef Friedman, E., Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., & Zoido–Lobaton, P. (2000). Dodging the grabbing hand: the determinants of unofficial activity in 69 countries. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 459–493. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Galletta, S., & Jametti, M. (2012). How to tame two Leviathans? Revisiting the effect of direct democracy on local public expenditure. CESifo working papers No. 3982. Galletta, S., & Jametti, M. (2012). How to tame two Leviathans? Revisiting the effect of direct democracy on local public expenditure. CESifo working papers No. 3982.
Zurück zum Zitat Gerxhani, K. (2004). The informal sector in developed and less developed countries: a literature survey. Public Choice, 120(3–4), 267–300. CrossRef Gerxhani, K. (2004). The informal sector in developed and less developed countries: a literature survey. Public Choice, 120(3–4), 267–300. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Glaeser, E. L., Ponzetto, G., & Shleifer, A. (2007). Why does democracy need education? Journal of Economic Growth, 12(2), 77–99. CrossRef Glaeser, E. L., Ponzetto, G., & Shleifer, A. (2007). Why does democracy need education? Journal of Economic Growth, 12(2), 77–99. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hug, S. (2004). Occurrence and policy consequences of referendums. A theoretical model and empirical evidence. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 16(3), 321–356. CrossRef Hug, S. (2004). Occurrence and policy consequences of referendums. A theoretical model and empirical evidence. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 16(3), 321–356. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hug, S., & Spörri, F. (2011). Referendums, trust, and tax evasion. European Journal of Political Economy, 27, 120–131. CrossRef Hug, S., & Spörri, F. (2011). Referendums, trust, and tax evasion. European Journal of Political Economy, 27, 120–131. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hwang, J.-Y. (2005). Direct democracy in Asia: a reference guide to the legislation and practice. Taiwan Foundation for Democracy Publication. Hwang, J.-Y. (2005). Direct democracy in Asia: a reference guide to the legislation and practice. Taiwan Foundation for Democracy Publication.
Zurück zum Zitat Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., & Schleifer, A. (1997). The unofficial economy in transition. Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, Economic Studies Program, The Brookings Institution, 28(2), 159–240. CrossRef Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., & Schleifer, A. (1997). The unofficial economy in transition. Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, Economic Studies Program, The Brookings Institution, 28(2), 159–240. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., & Zoido-Lobatón, P. (1998). Regulatory discretion and the unofficial economy. The American Economic Review, 88(2), 387–392. Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., & Zoido-Lobatón, P. (1998). Regulatory discretion and the unofficial economy. The American Economic Review, 88(2), 387–392.
Zurück zum Zitat Kaufmann, D. (2004). Initiative and referendum monitor 2004/2005. IRI Europe, Amsterdam. Kaufmann, D. (2004). Initiative and referendum monitor 2004/2005. IRI Europe, Amsterdam.
Zurück zum Zitat Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2005). Governance matters IV: governance indicators for 1996–2004. The World Bank. Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2005). Governance matters IV: governance indicators for 1996–2004. The World Bank.
Zurück zum Zitat Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (1997). Rational choice, collective action and the paradox of rebellion. Copenhagen: Institute of Political Science, University of Copenhagen & Copenhagen Political Studies Press. Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (1997). Rational choice, collective action and the paradox of rebellion. Copenhagen: Institute of Political Science, University of Copenhagen & Copenhagen Political Studies Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2004). The paradox of rebellion. In C. K. Rowley & F. Schneider (Eds.), The encyclopedia of public choice (Vol. 2, pp. 403–406). Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic. Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2004). The paradox of rebellion. In C. K. Rowley & F. Schneider (Eds.), The encyclopedia of public choice (Vol. 2, pp. 403–406). Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic.
Zurück zum Zitat Landes, D. (1998). The wealth and the poverty of nations. New York: W.W. Norton. Landes, D. (1998). The wealth and the poverty of nations. New York: W.W. Norton.
Zurück zum Zitat La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1999). The quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 15(1), 222–279. CrossRef La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1999). The quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 15(1), 222–279. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lipset, S. M. (1959). Some social requisites of democracy: economic development and political legitimacy. American Political Science Review, 53(1), 69–105. CrossRef Lipset, S. M. (1959). Some social requisites of democracy: economic development and political legitimacy. American Political Science Review, 53(1), 69–105. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Loayza, N. A. (1996). The economics of the informal sector. A simple model and some empirical evidence from Latin America. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 45, 129–162. CrossRef Loayza, N. A. (1996). The economics of the informal sector. A simple model and some empirical evidence from Latin America. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 45, 129–162. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Madroñal, J. C. (2005). Direct democracy in Latin America. Mas Democracia and Democracy International. Madroñal, J. C. (2005). Direct democracy in Latin America. Mas Democracia and Democracy International.
Zurück zum Zitat Matsusaka, J. G. (1995). Fiscal effects of the voter initiative: evidence from the last 30 years. Journal of Political Economy, 103, 587–623. CrossRef Matsusaka, J. G. (1995). Fiscal effects of the voter initiative: evidence from the last 30 years. Journal of Political Economy, 103, 587–623. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Matsusaka, J. G. (2005). Direct democracy works. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19, 185–206. CrossRef Matsusaka, J. G. (2005). Direct democracy works. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19, 185–206. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Matsusaka, J. G., & McCarty, N. M. (2001). Political resource allocation: benefits and costs of voter initiatives. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 17, 413–448. CrossRef Matsusaka, J. G., & McCarty, N. M. (2001). Political resource allocation: benefits and costs of voter initiatives. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 17, 413–448. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Olson, M. ([1965] 1971). The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of groups (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Olson, M. ([1965] 1971). The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of groups (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Paldam, M. (2001). Corruption and religion. Adding to the economic model. Kyklos, 54(2/3), 383–414. Paldam, M. (2001). Corruption and religion. Adding to the economic model. Kyklos, 54(2/3), 383–414.
Zurück zum Zitat Paldam, M., & Gundlach, E. (2008). Two views on institutions and development: the grand transition vs the primacy of institutions. Kyklos, 61(1), 65–100. CrossRef Paldam, M., & Gundlach, E. (2008). Two views on institutions and development: the grand transition vs the primacy of institutions. Kyklos, 61(1), 65–100. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics: explaining economic policy. Cambridge: MIT Press. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics: explaining economic policy. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2003). The economic effects of constitutions. Cambridge: MIT Press. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2003). The economic effects of constitutions. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Pommerehne, W. W. (1990). Institutional approaches to public expenditure: empirical evidence from Swiss municipalities. Journal of Public Economics, 9, 255–280. CrossRef Pommerehne, W. W. (1990). Institutional approaches to public expenditure: empirical evidence from Swiss municipalities. Journal of Public Economics, 9, 255–280. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pommerehne, W. W., & Schneider, F. (1978). Fiscal illusion, political institutions and local public spending. Kyklos, 31(3), 381–408. CrossRef Pommerehne, W. W., & Schneider, F. (1978). Fiscal illusion, political institutions and local public spending. Kyklos, 31(3), 381–408. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pommerehne, W. W., & Weck-Hannemann, H. (1996). Tax rates, tax administration and income tax evasion in Switzerland. Public Choice, 88, 161–170. CrossRef Pommerehne, W. W., & Weck-Hannemann, H. (1996). Tax rates, tax administration and income tax evasion in Switzerland. Public Choice, 88, 161–170. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1978). Political resource allocation, controlled agendas, and the status quo. Public Choice, 33, 27–43. CrossRef Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1978). Political resource allocation, controlled agendas, and the status quo. Public Choice, 33, 27–43. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schneider, F. (2005). Shadow economies of 145 countries all over the world: estimation results of the period 1999 to 2003. Discussion paper Linz. Schneider, F. (2005). Shadow economies of 145 countries all over the world: estimation results of the period 1999 to 2003. Discussion paper Linz.
Zurück zum Zitat Schneider, F., & Enste, D. H. (2000). Shadow economies: size, causes and consequences. Journal of Economic Literature, 38(1), 77–114. CrossRef Schneider, F., & Enste, D. H. (2000). Shadow economies: size, causes and consequences. Journal of Economic Literature, 38(1), 77–114. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schneider, F., & Enste, D. H. (2002). The shadow economy. An international survey. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Schneider, F., & Enste, D. H. (2002). The shadow economy. An international survey. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Schneider, F., & Neck, R. (1993). The development of the shadow economy under changing tax systems and structures. Finanzarchiv, 50(3), 344–369. Schneider, F., & Neck, R. (1993). The development of the shadow economy under changing tax systems and structures. Finanzarchiv, 50(3), 344–369.
Zurück zum Zitat Silver, M. (1974). Political revolution and repression: an economic approach. Public Choice, 17, 63–71. CrossRef Silver, M. (1974). Political revolution and repression: an economic approach. Public Choice, 17, 63–71. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Teobaldelli, D. (2011). Federalism and the shadow economy. Public Choice, 146(3–4), 269–289. CrossRef Teobaldelli, D. (2011). Federalism and the shadow economy. Public Choice, 146(3–4), 269–289. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Torgler, B. (2005). Tax morale and direct democracy. European Journal of Political Economy, 21, 525–531. CrossRef Torgler, B. (2005). Tax morale and direct democracy. European Journal of Political Economy, 21, 525–531. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Torgler, B., & Schneider, F. (2009). The impact of tax morale and institutional quality on the shadow economy. Journal of Economic Psychology, 30(2), 228–245. CrossRef Torgler, B., & Schneider, F. (2009). The impact of tax morale and institutional quality on the shadow economy. Journal of Economic Psychology, 30(2), 228–245. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Torgler, B., Schneider, F., & Schaltegger, C. A. (2010). Local autonomy, tax morale and the shadow economy. Public Choice, 144(1–2), 293–321. CrossRef Torgler, B., Schneider, F., & Schaltegger, C. A. (2010). Local autonomy, tax morale and the shadow economy. Public Choice, 144(1–2), 293–321. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Treisman, D. (2000). The causes of corruption: a cross national study. Journal of Public Economics, 76(3), 399–457. CrossRef Treisman, D. (2000). The causes of corruption: a cross national study. Journal of Public Economics, 76(3), 399–457. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1971). The paradox of revolution. Public Choice, 11, 89–100. CrossRef Tullock, G. (1971). The paradox of revolution. Public Choice, 11, 89–100. CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
The influence of direct democracy on the shadow economy
verfasst von
Désirée Teobaldelli
Friedrich Schneider
Publikationsdatum
01.12.2013
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 3-4/2013
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0098-2

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3-4/2013

Public Choice 3-4/2013 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner