Skip to main content

2010 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

8. The Neuroeconomics of Rational Decision Making

verfasst von : Prof. Richard B. McKenzie

Erschienen in: Predictably Rational?

Verlag: Springer Berlin Heidelberg

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Economists appropriately stress the problem of scarcity of resources in the external physical world where people seek to maximize their gain from an array of individually conceived wants that far exceed their capacities to fulfill their wants. A nontrivial portion of life for almost everyone is spent making choices and tradeoffs, some made unconsciously, which is to say, automatically or by instincts, routines and habits (regardless of whether or not the routines and habits are set by rational processes). A major goal of conventional microeconomics is to understand how the particulars of alternative institutional settings will encourage people to use their scarce resources efficiently in the external physical world, given whatever rational capacities people possess. And people’s rational capacities are typically viewed as fixed (more or less), not as a variable, subject to more or less activation. The so-called “economic problem,” which reduces, in conventional neoclassical microeconomics, the inherent difficulty of achieving economic efficiency in the external physical world, has been qualified in key ways throughout the discipline’s intellectual history, most notably by Frank Knight and Friedrich Hayek (see Chap. 5). Knight insisted that economics was concerned with the “rationale of life,” but he also recognized that a central problem for the discipline was how far life was, or even could be, rational, or (as rationality is normally conceived by neoclassical economists) as a matter of people deliberately choosing to allocate known resources among known wants. Knight mused that much time and human energy is soaked up in a life-long exploration into the field of alternatives and their evaluations in order that people can determine what ends can be and should be pursued (Knight 1935, p. 105). Hayek’s major concern was that information on people’s wants and the scarcities of resources is scattered among individuals who are the ultimate (and, according to Hayek, only) wellspring of wants. Moreover, subjectively conceived wants determine what physical things in the external world can, indeed, serve as resources; that is, as material and nonmaterial inputs that can be used to actually satisfy individually determined wants (Hayek 1945 and 1952b). Subjective evaluation, accordingly, is at the foundation of both sides of the scarcity dichotomy, wants and resources, the market values of which are necessarily determined interactively in social settings in the external physical world, which means that as a discipline, economics could not, and should not, imitate the methods of the physical sciences. Since Lionel Robbins defined the economic problem as that of coping with scarcity, Knight’s and Hayek’s (and other subjectivists’) methodological concerns have been largely sidelined, if not dismissed, because, if taken seriously, economists’ pursuit of empirical science would be seriously hobbled.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
Paul Zak is a professor and director of the Center for Neuroeconomics Studies at the Claremont Graduate University. Jessica Turner is a senior neuroscience researcher in the School of Medicine at the University of California, Irvine.
 
2
For extended discussions of exploit-or-explore decisions, see Zak and Denzau (2001) and Ghiselin (1974).
 
3
Granted, the human brain contains far more intelligence – or capacity for thinking, reasoning, remembering, and learning – than that of any other species, including, of course, cows and ducks. The intelligence of adult chimpanzees, for example, comes close to rivaling humans’ intelligence, but only for humans up to 18-months of age or so. Adult human intelligence reaches well beyond the mental capacities of chimpanzees. “By adolescence,” observes neuroscientist Michael Gazzaniga, “human intelligence is uniquely human, and other primate intelligence is unique to those particular species. When circuits unique to our species click in, we leave the chimps in the trees” (Gazzaniga 1992, p. 105). Humans may be the only species capable of contemplating its own consciousness, much less the origins and fate of the universe or create complex production processes and markets to ease the scarcity problems they face, and these abilities must be traced to their mental resources unmatched by other species.
 
4
It is hard to see how humans in any transient generation would be able to conceive of a more efficient, higher level of mental capacity and then institute the biological modifications required to establish the greater mental capacity throughout future generations. Any species, human or otherwise, able to pull off such a feat would not need to move to a higher mental capacity, or so it would seem. Of course, genetic engineering might eventually overcome the time constraints of evolution, enabling people in some future generation to transform human mental abilities in a matter of generations, if not during one or two generations.
 
5
A potential basis for this can be seen in neural responses in visual areas to the same visual stimuli being modulated by attentional states (Treue and Maunsell 1996).
 
6
The experiment can be better visualized by viewing a video of the interviews with the change of interviewers occurring in the midst of the interviews (http://viscog.beckman.uiuc.edu/grafs/demos/15.html).
 
7
The experiment can be seen in a video of the experimental setting (http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=T0nYQEm6Ajg).
 
8
In another version of the experiment involving basketball players passing the ball, a research assistant walked through the players holding an open black umbrella with the results much the same (Simons and Chabris 1999).
 
9
See the classic article by Squire (1986) and the more recent review by Bruel-Jungerman et al. 2007).
 
10
Again, the irreducible noise in neural firing rates may partially affect the changes in people’s decisions. Neurons have background stochastic firing rates for reasons that are not well-understood, but may accomplish “housekeeping” tasks that cells need to function properly, and the neurons’ stochastic firing rates can, we surmise, give rise to productive exploration of people’s sensory landscape about them. Laboratory studies of animals and humans consistently reveal this behavior, and doing the occasional exploration can easily be understood as an evolutionarily adaptive trait (or else we must wonder how or why humans could, as Frank Knight suggested, see so much of life as an “exploration” into the field of alternatives and their values).
 
11
A summary of the evidence of the myth that humans used only 10 percent of the brain is available at http://faculty.washington.edu/chudler/tenper.html.
 
12
As reported in “Not on the List? The Truth about Impulse Purchases” at Knowledge Wharton, accessed March 6, 2009 at http://knowledge.wharton.upenn.edu/article.cfm?articleid=2132.
 
13
Andreoni et al. (2003) have shown that half of contributions in public goods games are due to confusion and half due to “warm glow,” or wanting to benefit others. However, over time people get more selfish; i.e., learn they can exploit the system, presumably as they gain experience with the task and engage brain circuits to fully evaluate options.
 
14
For example, neuroeconomists have found brain processes that produce empathy and motivate other regarding behaviors, as well as the utility function already acknowledged (Zak et al. 2007).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Ariely D (2008) Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces that Shape Our Decisions. HarperCollins Publishers, New York Ariely D (2008) Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces that Shape Our Decisions. HarperCollins Publishers, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Bardo, M.T., R. L. Donohew,and N.G. Harrington, N.G. 1996, Psychobiology of novelty seeking and drug seeking behavior, Behavioral Brain Research. 77(1-2):23-43. Bardo, M.T., R. L. Donohew,and N.G. Harrington, N.G. 1996, Psychobiology of novelty seeking and drug seeking behavior, Behavioral Brain Research. 77(1-2):23-43.
Zurück zum Zitat Bateson M (2002) Recent advances in our understanding of risk-sensitive foraging preferences. Proceedings of the Nutrition Society 61:509–516CrossRef Bateson M (2002) Recent advances in our understanding of risk-sensitive foraging preferences. Proceedings of the Nutrition Society 61:509–516CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Conde JR, Streit WJ (2006) Microglia in the aging brain. Journal of Neuropathology and Experimental Neurology 65(3):199–203 Conde JR, Streit WJ (2006) Microglia in the aging brain. Journal of Neuropathology and Experimental Neurology 65(3):199–203
Zurück zum Zitat Crockett MJ, Clark L, Tabibnia G, Lieberman MD, Robbins TW (2008) Serotonin modulates behavioral reactions to unfairness. Science 320:1739CrossRef Crockett MJ, Clark L, Tabibnia G, Lieberman MD, Robbins TW (2008) Serotonin modulates behavioral reactions to unfairness. Science 320:1739CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ghiselin MT (1974) The Economy of Nature and the Evolution of Sex. University of California Press, Berkeley, Calif Ghiselin MT (1974) The Economy of Nature and the Evolution of Sex. University of California Press, Berkeley, Calif
Zurück zum Zitat Glimcher, P.W., M.C. Dorris, and H.M. Bayer H.M. 2005. Physiological utility theory and the neuroeconomics of choice. Games and Economic Behavior 52: 213-56 Glimcher, P.W., M.C. Dorris, and H.M. Bayer H.M. 2005. Physiological utility theory and the neuroeconomics of choice. Games and Economic Behavior 52: 213-56
Zurück zum Zitat Kachelmeier SJ, Shehata M (1992) Examining risk preferences under high monetary incentives: Experimental evidence from the People’s Republic of China. American Economic Review 82(5):1120–1141 Kachelmeier SJ, Shehata M (1992) Examining risk preferences under high monetary incentives: Experimental evidence from the People’s Republic of China. American Economic Review 82(5):1120–1141
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: An analysis of decisions under risk. Econometrica 47:313–327CrossRef Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: An analysis of decisions under risk. Econometrica 47:313–327CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kandel ER (2007) In Search of Memory: The Emergence of a New Science of Mind. W.W. Norton & Company, New York Kandel ER (2007) In Search of Memory: The Emergence of a New Science of Mind. W.W. Norton & Company, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Knutson B, Peterson R (2005) Neurally reconstructing expected utility. Games and Economic Behavior. 52:305–315CrossRef Knutson B, Peterson R (2005) Neurally reconstructing expected utility. Games and Economic Behavior. 52:305–315CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Knutson B, Rick S, Wimmer GE, Prelec D, Loewenstein G (2007) Neural predictors of purchases. Neuron 53:147–157CrossRef Knutson B, Rick S, Wimmer GE, Prelec D, Loewenstein G (2007) Neural predictors of purchases. Neuron 53:147–157CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leclerc F, Schmitt B, Dubé L (1995) Is time like money?: Decision making and waiting time. Journal of Consumer Research 22:110–119CrossRef Leclerc F, Schmitt B, Dubé L (1995) Is time like money?: Decision making and waiting time. Journal of Consumer Research 22:110–119CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Loftus EF (1997) Creating false memories. Scientific American, September 277:70–75CrossRef Loftus EF (1997) Creating false memories. Scientific American, September 277:70–75CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Marcus G (2008) Kluge: The Haphazard Evolution of the Human Mind. Mariner Books, Boston Marcus G (2008) Kluge: The Haphazard Evolution of the Human Mind. Mariner Books, Boston
Zurück zum Zitat McClure SM, Laibson D, Loewenstein G, Cohen JD (2004) Separate neural systems value immediate and delayed monetary reward. Science 306:503–507CrossRef McClure SM, Laibson D, Loewenstein G, Cohen JD (2004) Separate neural systems value immediate and delayed monetary reward. Science 306:503–507CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McGaugh JL (2004) The amygdale modulates the consolidation of memories of emotionally arousing experiences. Annual Review of Neuroscience 27:1–28CrossRef McGaugh JL (2004) The amygdale modulates the consolidation of memories of emotionally arousing experiences. Annual Review of Neuroscience 27:1–28CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McKenzie RB (2008) Why Popcorn Costs So Much at the Movies, and Other Pricing Puzzles. Springer Publishers, Heidelberg, Germany McKenzie RB (2008) Why Popcorn Costs So Much at the Movies, and Other Pricing Puzzles. Springer Publishers, Heidelberg, Germany
Zurück zum Zitat Nelson, A. J., D.J. Heeger, K. McCabe, D. Houser; P. J. Zak, P.W. Glimcher. 2004. Expected utility provides a model for choice behavior and brain activation in humans. Nelson, A. J., D.J. Heeger, K. McCabe, D. Houser; P. J. Zak, P.W. Glimcher. 2004. Expected utility provides a model for choice behavior and brain activation in humans.
Zurück zum Zitat Nuñez A, Malmiera E (2007) Corticofugal Modulation of Sensory Information. Springer, Heidelberg, Germany Nuñez A, Malmiera E (2007) Corticofugal Modulation of Sensory Information. Springer, Heidelberg, Germany
Zurück zum Zitat Park JW, Zak PJ (2007) Neuroeconomics studies. Analyse & Kritik 29(1):47–59 Park JW, Zak PJ (2007) Neuroeconomics studies. Analyse & Kritik 29(1):47–59
Zurück zum Zitat Samuelson W, Zeckhauser R (1988) Status quo bias in decision making,". Journal of Risk and Uncertainty. 1(1):7–59CrossRef Samuelson W, Zeckhauser R (1988) Status quo bias in decision making,". Journal of Risk and Uncertainty. 1(1):7–59CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Scholey AB, Harper S, Kennedy DO (2001) Cognitive demand and blood glucose. Physiological Behavior. 73(4):585–592CrossRef Scholey AB, Harper S, Kennedy DO (2001) Cognitive demand and blood glucose. Physiological Behavior. 73(4):585–592CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schwartz B (2004) The Paradox of Choice: Why More Is Less. Harper Collins, New York Schwartz B (2004) The Paradox of Choice: Why More Is Less. Harper Collins, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Simon H (1957) Models of Man. John Wiley & Co., New York Simon H (1957) Models of Man. John Wiley & Co., New York
Zurück zum Zitat Simons DJ, Levin DT (1997) Change blindness. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 1:261–267CrossRef Simons DJ, Levin DT (1997) Change blindness. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 1:261–267CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Slagter, H. A., A. Lutz, L.L. Greischar, A.D. Francis, S. Nieuwenhuis, J.M. Davis, and R.J. Davidson. 2007. Mental training affects use of limited brain resources. PLoS Biology 5 (6):e138 doi:10.1371/journal.pbio.0050138). Slagter, H. A., A. Lutz, L.L. Greischar, A.D. Francis, S. Nieuwenhuis, J.M. Davis, and R.J. Davidson. 2007. Mental training affects use of limited brain resources. PLoS Biology 5 (6):e138 doi:10.1371/journal.pbio.0050138).
Zurück zum Zitat Squire LR (1986) Mechanisms of Memory. Science. 232(4758):1612–1619CrossRef Squire LR (1986) Mechanisms of Memory. Science. 232(4758):1612–1619CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Thaler RH (2001) Anomalies. Journal of Economic Perspective 15(1):219–232CrossRef Thaler RH (2001) Anomalies. Journal of Economic Perspective 15(1):219–232CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Thaler RH, Sunstein CR (2008) Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness. Yale University Press, New Haven, Conn Thaler RH, Sunstein CR (2008) Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness. Yale University Press, New Haven, Conn
Zurück zum Zitat Tversky A, Kahneman D (1981) The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science 211(4481):453–458CrossRef Tversky A, Kahneman D (1981) The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science 211(4481):453–458CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wicker B, Keysers C, Plailly J, Royet J-P (2003) Both of us disgusted in My Insula: The Common Neural Basis of Seeing and Feeling Disgust. Neuron. 40(3):655–664CrossRef Wicker B, Keysers C, Plailly J, Royet J-P (2003) Both of us disgusted in My Insula: The Common Neural Basis of Seeing and Feeling Disgust. Neuron. 40(3):655–664CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Zak PJ (2004) Neuroeconomics. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B 359:1737–1748CrossRef Zak PJ (2004) Neuroeconomics. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B 359:1737–1748CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Zak PJ, Park KW (2002) Population genetics and economic growth. Journal of Bioeconomics 4(1):1–37CrossRef Zak PJ, Park KW (2002) Population genetics and economic growth. Journal of Bioeconomics 4(1):1–37CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
The Neuroeconomics of Rational Decision Making
verfasst von
Prof. Richard B. McKenzie
Copyright-Jahr
2010
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-01586-1_8

Premium Partner