Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Social Choice and Welfare 2-3/2020

26.11.2018 | Original Paper

The theoretical Shapley–Shubik probability of an election inversion in a toy symmetric version of the US presidential electoral system

verfasst von: Olivier de Mouzon, Thibault Laurent, Michel Le Breton, Dominique Lepelley

Erschienen in: Social Choice and Welfare | Ausgabe 2-3/2020

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In this article, we evaluate asymptotically the probability \(\phi \left( n\right) \) of an election inversion in a toy symmetric version of the US presidential electoral system. The novelty of this paper, in contrast to all the existing theoretical literature, is to assume that votes are drawn from an IAC (Impartial Anonymous Culture)/Shapley–Shubik probability model. Through the use of numerical methods, it is conjectured, that \(\sqrt{n}\)\( \phi \left( n\right) \) converges to 0.1309 when n (the size of the electorate in one district) tends to infinity. It is also demonstrated that \( \phi \left( n\right) =o\left( \sqrt{\frac{ln(n)^{3}}{n}}\right) \) and \(\phi \left( n\right) =\Omega \left( \frac{1}{\sqrt{n}}\right) \).

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
See Nurmi (1999).
 
2
Miller (2012b) contains an insightful presentation of the Electoral College that he qualifies as “a terrific boon for political science (and public choice) research (and teaching)”.
 
3
If there are m feasible orderings, this means that each marginal distribution is (1 / m, 1 / m, ..., 1 / m).
 
4
This prior is a special case of a Dirichlet distribution.
 
5
See Straffin (1988) for a very nice united presentation of IC and IAC.
 
6
In the two-alternative case, the IC and IAC model have been extensively used to study the fairness of voting bodies from the point of view of the power defined as the expected propensity for a voter to be influent/pivotal in the decision making process. The computation of the Banzhaf and Shapley–Shubik power indices is one of the main area of applied research.
 
7
Saying that the beta parameter of the distribution tends to \(+\infty \) amounts to say that the probability that the election is tied in any given district tends to 1, which is what postulates the IC model.
 
8
While this paper is about election inversions, the same apparatus could be used to estimate the votes/seats relationship (see e.g. Tufte 1973) and the likelihood of any event like ‘The left won \(x\%\) of the popular vote and \(y\%\) of the seats/electoral votes’ where both x and y are numbers in \( \left[ 0,1\right] \). If you divide the unit square \(\left[ 0,1\right] ^{2}\) into the four squares \(\left[ 0,\frac{1}{2}\right] \times \left[ 0,\frac{1}{2 }\right] ,\left[ 0,\frac{1}{2}\right] \times \left[ \frac{1}{2},1\right] , \left[ \frac{1}{2},1\right] \times \left[ 0,\frac{1}{2}\right] \) and \(\left[ \frac{1}{2},1\right] \times \left[ \frac{1}{2},1\right] \), the probability of election inversions is the probability of the union of the two anti-diagonal squares. Obviously, knowing the totality of the joint distribution on \(\left[ 0,1\right] ^{2}\) has some intrinsic value.
 
9
Owen computes the Shapley–Shubik and the Banzhaf powers of the US citizens as a function of the state where they vote. He shows, surprisingly, that the relative powers of the citizen of any state (the denominator is the power of a citizen from the District of Columbia) are about the same for the two models.
 
10
In Sect. 3, we sketch the general principles of our numerical analysis. The reader is refered to the online appendix for the full details. In this, we discuss the asymptotic behavior of estimates resulting from approximations together with two bounds.
 
11
Most authors in the theoretical vein have considered toy symmetric versions of the Electoral College. Recent developments aiming to an evaluation of the probability of an election inversion in the general case are Kikuchi (2017) and Kaniovski and Zaigraev (2017).
 
12
An immediate corollary of these results is that the probability of an election inversion tends to 0 when the number of voters per district tends to \(\infty \). Kikuchi (2018) proves that this convergence to 0 holds true for any number of districts and any profile of populations and electoral votes across districts.
 
13
So malapportionment is excluded from the scope of our analysis.
 
14
A more pedestrian and illustrative exposition of these probability models emphasizing their differences in terms of correlation between votes is presented in the following subsection.
 
15
In particular, \(\Gamma \left( n\right) =(n-1)!\) if n is a positive integer.
 
16
In our paper, we do not need to define the majority mechanism when m is an even integer.
 
17
This illustration remains valid for any number of districts and any number of voters per district.
 
18
Other ways to generate correlation among Bernoulli variables exist. For instance, we could use a beta distribution instead of this truncated uniform distribution or the Gaussian distribution as in Le Breton et al. (2016).
 
19
Strictly speaking the density is not defined for \(\delta =0\). IC is the limit when \(\delta \rightarrow 0\).
 
20
In the conclusion, we report computations of the probability of election inversions obtained from simulations for that one-parameter model.
 
21
To compute \(\phi \), we need therefore to know the values of \(\ln \Gamma \) for the integers ranging from 1 to \(3n+2\). For large values of n, this is done by the use of Stirling’s formula.
 
22
Proofs are provided in appendix A.
 
23
The number of computations for \(\phi _{maj}\) and \(\phi _{min}\) is of order n (in contrast to \(n^{3}\) for \(\phi \)).
 
24
If we pile up the r levels, we obtain indeed, a geometric pattern close to a tetrahedron. It is represented in Fig. 2. When we compute \(\phi \) for the following value of n, we add to the tetrahedron a ground level with a number of new entries to compute equal to \(\frac{n+1}{2}\times (\frac{n+1}{2}-1)/2\). Note that when n increases, the values \(B^{k,l,r}\) will decrease and converge to 0. For instance, on the top \(B^{\frac{n+1}{2},\frac{n+1}{2},\frac{n-3}{2}}=O(n^{-2})\). The values on low levels converge even more rapidly towards 0. For instance, for the ground level (\(r=0\)), \(B^{\frac{n+1}{2},\frac{n+1}{2},0}\) behaves as \(n^{-1.5}\left( \frac{16}{27}\right) ^{n} \).
 
25
The approximation error resulting from \({\tilde{\phi }}_{min}\) rather than \( \phi _{min}\) is evaluated and analysed in the online appendix.
 
26
We refer to the online appendix for the details and in particular for an evaluation of the ultimate number of computations needed to compute \(\tilde{ \phi }(n)\) and of the approximation error.
 
27
We refer to the online appendix for an evaluation of the ultimate number of computations needed to compute \({\tilde{\phi }}(n)\) and of the approximation error.
 
28
Omitted proofs appear in appendix B.
 
29
This restriction on the set of values of n which are considered makes the writing easier (which would otherwise call for the introduction of the integer parts).
 
30
Precisely, \(n=2\times 10^{6}+1\) and 10\(^{6}\) simulations.
 
31
This exercise is theoretical and is by no means intended to suggest that this model fits the data. It simply points out the impact of the specific value of the correlation coefficient on the probability of an election inversion.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Banzhaf JF (1965) Weighted voting does not work: a mathematical analysis. Rutgers Law Rev 19:317–343 Banzhaf JF (1965) Weighted voting does not work: a mathematical analysis. Rutgers Law Rev 19:317–343
Zurück zum Zitat Banzhaf JF (1966) Multi-member electoral districts: do they violate the one man, one vote principle. Yale Law J 75:1309–1338CrossRef Banzhaf JF (1966) Multi-member electoral districts: do they violate the one man, one vote principle. Yale Law J 75:1309–1338CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chamberlain G, Rothschild M (1981) A note on the probability of casting a decisive vote. J Econ Theory 25:152–162CrossRef Chamberlain G, Rothschild M (1981) A note on the probability of casting a decisive vote. J Econ Theory 25:152–162CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Feix MR, Lepelley D, Merlin V, Rouet JL (2004) The probability of conflicts in a U.S. presidential type election. Econ Theory 23:227–257CrossRef Feix MR, Lepelley D, Merlin V, Rouet JL (2004) The probability of conflicts in a U.S. presidential type election. Econ Theory 23:227–257CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gehrlein WV, Lepelley D (2011) Voting paradoxes and group coherence. Springer, BerlinCrossRef Gehrlein WV, Lepelley D (2011) Voting paradoxes and group coherence. Springer, BerlinCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fishburn PC, Gehrlein WV (1976) Borda’s rule, positional voting, and Condorcet’s simple majority principle. Public Choice 28:79–88CrossRef Fishburn PC, Gehrlein WV (1976) Borda’s rule, positional voting, and Condorcet’s simple majority principle. Public Choice 28:79–88CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Good IJ, Mayer LS (1975) Estimating the efficacy of a vote. Behav Sci 20:25–33CrossRef Good IJ, Mayer LS (1975) Estimating the efficacy of a vote. Behav Sci 20:25–33CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hinich MJ, Mickelsen R, Ordeshook PC (1972) The electoral college versus a direct vote: policy bias, reversals, and indeterminate outcomes. J Math Sociol 4:3–35CrossRef Hinich MJ, Mickelsen R, Ordeshook PC (1972) The electoral college versus a direct vote: policy bias, reversals, and indeterminate outcomes. J Math Sociol 4:3–35CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kaniovski S, Zaigraev A (2017) The probability of majority inversion in a two-stage voting system with three states. Austrian Institute of Economic Research, Mimeo Kaniovski S, Zaigraev A (2017) The probability of majority inversion in a two-stage voting system with three states. Austrian Institute of Economic Research, Mimeo
Zurück zum Zitat Kikuchi K (2017) The likelihood of majority inversion in an indirect voting system. Waseda University, Mimeo Kikuchi K (2017) The likelihood of majority inversion in an indirect voting system. Waseda University, Mimeo
Zurück zum Zitat Kikuchi K (2018) A note on election inversion. Private Correspondence, Mimeo Kikuchi K (2018) A note on election inversion. Private Correspondence, Mimeo
Zurück zum Zitat Kuga K, Nagatani H (1974) Voter antagonism and the paradox of voting. Econometrica 42:1045–1067CrossRef Kuga K, Nagatani H (1974) Voter antagonism and the paradox of voting. Econometrica 42:1045–1067CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Le Breton M, Lepelley D (2014) Une analyse de la loi électorale du 29 Juin 1820. Rev Écon 65:469–518CrossRef Le Breton M, Lepelley D (2014) Une analyse de la loi électorale du 29 Juin 1820. Rev Écon 65:469–518CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Le Breton M, Lepelley D, Smaoui H (2016) Correlation, partitioning and the probability of casting a decisive vote under the majority rule. J Math Econ 64:11–22CrossRef Le Breton M, Lepelley D, Smaoui H (2016) Correlation, partitioning and the probability of casting a decisive vote under the majority rule. J Math Econ 64:11–22CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lepelley D, Merlin V, Rouet JL (2011) Three ways to compute accurately the probability of the referendum paradox. Math Soc Sci 23:227–257 Lepelley D, Merlin V, Rouet JL (2011) Three ways to compute accurately the probability of the referendum paradox. Math Soc Sci 23:227–257
Zurück zum Zitat May K (1948) Probability of certain election results. Am Math Mon 55:203–209CrossRef May K (1948) Probability of certain election results. Am Math Mon 55:203–209CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Miller NR (2012a) “Election inversions by the U.S. Electoral College”, Chapter 4. In: Felsenthal DDS, Machover M (eds) Electoral systems, studies in social choice and welfare. Springer-Verlag, Berlin, Heidelberg Miller NR (2012a) “Election inversions by the U.S. Electoral College”, Chapter 4. In: Felsenthal DDS, Machover M (eds) Electoral systems, studies in social choice and welfare. Springer-Verlag, Berlin, Heidelberg
Zurück zum Zitat Miller NR (2012b) Why the Electoral College is good for political science (and public choice). Public Choice 150:1–25CrossRef Miller NR (2012b) Why the Electoral College is good for political science (and public choice). Public Choice 150:1–25CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nurmi H (1999) Voting paradoxes and how to deal with them. Springer-Verlag, BerlinCrossRef Nurmi H (1999) Voting paradoxes and how to deal with them. Springer-Verlag, BerlinCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Owen G (1975) Evaluation of a presidential election game. Am Polit Sci Rev 69:947–953CrossRef Owen G (1975) Evaluation of a presidential election game. Am Polit Sci Rev 69:947–953CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shapley LS, Shubik M (1954) A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a committee system. Am Polit Sci Rev 48:787–792CrossRef Shapley LS, Shubik M (1954) A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a committee system. Am Polit Sci Rev 48:787–792CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Straffin PD (1988) The Shapley-Shubik and Banzhaf power indices as probabilities. In: Roth AE (ed) The Shapley value: essays in honor of Lloyd S. Cambridge University Press, Shapley Straffin PD (1988) The Shapley-Shubik and Banzhaf power indices as probabilities. In: Roth AE (ed) The Shapley value: essays in honor of Lloyd S. Cambridge University Press, Shapley
Zurück zum Zitat Tufte ER (1973) The relationship between seats and votes in two-party systems. Am J Polit Sci 67:540–554CrossRef Tufte ER (1973) The relationship between seats and votes in two-party systems. Am J Polit Sci 67:540–554CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
The theoretical Shapley–Shubik probability of an election inversion in a toy symmetric version of the US presidential electoral system
verfasst von
Olivier de Mouzon
Thibault Laurent
Michel Le Breton
Dominique Lepelley
Publikationsdatum
26.11.2018
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Social Choice and Welfare / Ausgabe 2-3/2020
Print ISSN: 0176-1714
Elektronische ISSN: 1432-217X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-018-1162-0

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 2-3/2020

Social Choice and Welfare 2-3/2020 Zur Ausgabe