Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 4/2021

Open Access 27.04.2021 | Original Research

The value of in-person banking: evidence from U.S. small businesses

verfasst von: Song Zhang, Liang Han, Konstantinos Kallias, Antonios Kallias

Erschienen in: Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting | Ausgabe 4/2021

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We produce the first systematic study of the determinants and implications of in-person banking. Using survey data from the U.S., we show that firms which are informationally opaque or operate in rural areas are liable to contact their primary bank in-person. This tendency extends to older, less educated, and female business owners. We find that a relationship based on face-to-face communication, on average, lasts 17.88 months longer, spans a wider range of financial services, and is more likely to be exclusive. The associated loans mature 3.37 months later and bear interest rates which are 11 basis points lower. For good quality firms, in-person communication also relates to less discouraged borrowing. These results are robust to multiple approaches for endogeneity, including recursive bivariate probits, treatment effect models, and instrumental variables regressions. Overall, our findings offer empirical grounding to soft information theory and a note of caution to banks against suppressing channels of interpersonal communication.
Hinweise

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

1 Introduction

Modern technology has revolutionized communication with banking institutions, offering users a high degree of autonomy and geographic liberalization. Everyday examples include online banking (Hernández-Murillo et al. 2010), ATMs in off-site locations (Magnac 2017), and mobile banking (Baptista and Oliveira 2015). Yet, small businesses have never been at the forefront of these innovations. U.S. evidence from the Federal Reserve’s Survey of Small Business Finances (SSBF) shows that only a fourth of the participant firms are willing to utilize some impersonal banking channel as a substitute for face-to-face communication with bank officers, raising two main questions. Why are certain firms more likely than others to visit the bank’s premises? How do in-person interactions compare with impersonal banking in terms of contribution to financial intermediation efficiency?
Small businesses face considerable difficulty in raising capital from stock markets. Their limited organizational footprint heightens concerns over adverse selection and moral hazard, calling for a level of information production which is disproportionately high to the available resources (Ang 1991). A preferred alternative is bank credit, mainly because it enables the transcendence of informational asymmetries through the repeated borrower-lender interactions (Rosenfeld 2014; D’Aurizio et al. 2015; Beck et al. 2018). As per substantial theoretical work (Boot 2000; Stein 2002; Berger and Udell 2002, 2006; Liberti and Petersen 2019), a distinctive feature of relationship banking is that part of the lending decision is based on soft information which, unlike hard information (e.g. accounting records, credit scores, history of payments), is neither quantifiable nor in any other manner observable by the market. Importantly, “with soft information, the context under which the information is collected and the collector of the information are part of the information. It is not possible to separate the two” (Liberti and Petersen 2019, pp. 3–4).
To disentangle the relative importance of soft and hard information over the course of the bank-firm relationship is unrealistic. However, it is equally unrealistic to assume it constant, given an environment of increasing technological automation and the vast heterogeneity of small firms’ characteristics. Relatedly, a shortcoming of the dominant empirical approach is the implicit assumption that a large number of interactions, as over a wide time frame or product range, suffice to enable the relationships effects (Petersen and Rajan 1994, 1995; Berger and Udell 1995; Hernández-Cánovas and Martínez-Solano 2010; Castelli et al. 2012; Karolyi 2018; Mi and Han 2020). By downplaying the importance of how the two parties actually communicate, this approach renders the soft information flow untraceable, obfuscating the sources of the added value of relationship banking. After all, if the main driver of the relationship is still hard data, relationship banking would not be fundamentally different from transactions-based banking technologies (e.g. financial statement or asset-based lending).
Motivated by this disconnect between theory and empirical investigation, we aim to capture more of the role of soft information on small business finance than is currently reflected in the literature. Towards this, the present paper offers, for the first time, a rigorous treatment of the determinants and implications of in-person banking by drawing evidence from a sample of 12,438 firms with less than 500 employees, spanning 9 U.S. regions, and 10 SIC divisions. Central to our approach is a previously overlooked SSBF question which sets the framework of a useful dichotomy: firms choosing to interact with their primary financial institution1 in-person vis-à-vis firms mainly relying on impersonal communication methods (internet, post, etc.). Underlying our approach is the recognition that soft information resides within in-person contact, whereas alternative communication channels tend to suppress it. Hence, although we have no way of filtering out hard information, by choosing to focus on the communication mode, we can ensure that every firm within our sample of interest also yields substantial soft information—a condition that prior studies are unable to provide.
Exploiting this property of our dataset, we first seek to enlighten our understanding of the factors invoking face-to-face interactions. Our expectation is that this need surfaces when the hardening of information is: (1) costlier, as when the firm is informationally opaque (Petersen and Rajan 1994, 1995; Schwert 2018); and (2) of limited reusability, as within rural banking markets (Cole et al. 2004; DeYoung et al. 2012). We ascribe much of the remaining variation to owners’ characteristics which drive organisational choices to a larger extent in the context of small business (Raymond 1985). Subsequently, we seek to capture the implications. Ceteris paribus, a higher frequency of in-person communication levels the informational playing field more than is attainable via impersonal communication. In turn, a treatment of information asymmetries equates to a treatment of the common root of three major challenges in small business banking: high borrowing costs (Datta et al. 1999), tight lending horizons (Ortiz-Molina and Penas 2008), and discouraged borrowers’ propensity to self-ration (Stiglitz and Weiss 1981; Kon and Storey 2003; Han et al. 2009). Accordingly, we hypothesize that credit becomes cheaper and more available for in-person communicators, consolidating their relationship with the bank.
Our findings are in line with the above conjectures. In our determinants tests, we obtain two primary results that are new to the literature. First, banking market conditions, after controlling for potential confounding factors, emerge as a strong driver of in-person contact, which supports the theoretical conjectures of Boot and Thakor (2000) and Hauswald and Marquez (2006) about the link between banking market structure and soft information transmission. Second, we document the incremental significance of small business owners’ characteristics on determining the nature of the relationship with the main bank; the inclusion of proxies for demographics and educational attainment not only increases the explanatory power of our probit model but also reveals the high marginal effects of these variables. On this basis, we sketch the profile of owners more liable to steer their firms towards in-person banking as predominantly female, older and less educated individuals.
Next, we test for a causal effect of the communication dichotomy on a variety of banking outcomes. As we find, a preponderance of face-to-face interactions benefits both ends of the relationship: (1) the bank experiences increased loyalty from small firms; and (2) the latter gain access to cheaper credit for an extended period of time. These effects are of high economic significance. A relationship based on in-person communication, on average, lasts 17.88 months longer and is 24.46% more likely to be the firm’s sole banking relationship; the associated loans mature 3.37 months later and bear interest rates which are 11 basis points lower. Furthermore, we complement the traditional proxies for relationship strength (e.g. Berger et al. 2005) with a new and comprehensive measure, services concentration, defined as the proportion of financial services a firm purchases from the primary bank relative to the total financial services it utilizes. As an outcome variable, this ratio confirms that in-person communication drives not only the credit decision but also the totality of a small firm’s banking needs. Finally, we find that the likelihood of discouraged borrowing is smaller for in-person communicators, albeit with a caveat. Because the effect holds for borrowers of good quality only, this finding is indicative of a decrease in screening errors made by the bank rather than a window of opportunity for bad borrowers.
Endogeneity poses a valid concern in our empirical setting. This is mainly due to additional factors which might correlate with the communication decision but lie outside the SSBF scope. For example, Uchida et al. (2012) caution that a high loan officer turnover undermines the bank’s ability to act as an information repository and Schoar (2012) finds that bonding (or lack thereof) with the bank’s relationship manager explains a portion of the variability in borrowers’ delinquency. To address this concern, we conduct a battery of tests, including recursive bivariate probit estimation and treatment effect models, which jointly create a framework for inferences least distorted by selection and / or omitted variables bias.
As a new and refined lens of soft information, our in-person contact approach speaks to a longstanding deficiency in literature: “existing work falls short in that it has not measured the precise sources of the added value of relationship banking” Boot (2000 p. 21). The most important contribution of this paper, therefore, is our ability to assign the observed effects to soft information and know that soft information, rather than any other element of the bank-firm relationship, represents the actual cause. In this vein, we provide empirical grounding to the theoretical predictions of the relationship banking literature (Stein 2002; Berger and Udell 2002, 2006; Liberti and Petersen 2019) and demonstrate the salience of soft information with evidence that is both objective and measurable.
Another contribution is to shed light on a hitherto unknown aspect of soft information production. The aim to capture the underlying mechanism which generates soft information is explicit in the studies of Uchida et al. (2012) and Hattori et al. (2015) which debate whether loan officers or the branch manager, respectively, play the leading role in the process; and implicit in studies analysing the characteristics which make a bank most receptive to this type of information (Petersen and Rajan 1995, 2002; Berger et al. 2005, 2014). While this research makes inroads on the bank’s ability to capitalize on soft information, we focus on the transmitting end, showing how likely a small firm is to provide critical input in the first place.
Finally, we contribute to two evolving strands of research by offering: (1) a partial remedy, in the form of in-person contact, to the challenge of discouraged borrowing in small business banking (Kon and Storey 2003; Han et al. 2009; Chakravarty and Xiang 2013); and (2) generalizable insight which is of interest to research investigating the efficacy of communication methods in entrepreneurial settings (e.g. Casson and Giusta 2007; Sarapaivanich and Patterson 2015).
Boiled down, this paper is a note of caution for both banks and their small business customers. The former should provide adequate space for subtle, noncontractual information to emerge, or else their unremitting investment in technological automation2 is likely to eliminate a key value driver. From the small business perspective, impersonal banking channels should be utilized on the understanding that they represent inferior substitutes for relationships built on face-to-face interactions.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 reviews the relevant literature. We develop our hypotheses in Sect. 3 and present the dataset in Sect. 4. The empirical results are in Sect. 5. The paper concludes in Sect. 6.

2 Background literature

Sourcing capital has always been an arduousendeavour for small businesses and indeed a financier has important reasons to shy away from this economic sector. First, small firms typically lack the managerial skills and resources to produce accounting records or other data useful to investors (Ang 1991). Hence, whether the owner has a pipeline of positive NPV projects to invest in (adverse selection problem) or whether she stands willing to channel funds towards these as opposed to subpar investments (moral hazard problem) are warranted concerns. Second and related, future prospects might be linked to owners’ characteristics which are either irreplaceable or, in part, unobservable (Bates 2005). Third, organizations of smaller size are vulnerable to environmental factors with a dramatically higher likelihood of failure (Hart and Oulton 1996).3 Consequently, with the exception of high-growth firms which might be on private equity’s radar, financing options for the vast majority of small businesses reduce to bank lending.
Banks are equipped to manage firm-specific uncertainty, the root cause of the above concerns, by their capacity to gather and integrate into the lending decision information generated from the interactions with clients. The greater the frequency of interactions, the more input becomes available and, hence, the greater the value added of the relationship banking (Petersen and Rajan 1994, 1995; Berger and Udell 1995; Hernández-Cánovas and Martínez-Solano 2010; Bharath et al. 2011; Castelli et al. 2012; Karolyi 2018; Tian and Han 2019). In spite of its vast volume, the relevant literature obtains evidence from a limited number of empirical proxies. Degryse and Van Cayseele (2000) and Iturralde et al. (2010) identify the three most popular in the following relationship dimensions: (1) duration, i.e. how long the firm has been the bank’s client; (2) breadth i.e. the range of services that the bank-firm relationship involves; and (3) concentration i.e. the firm’s total banking relationships.
Yet, unlike what such proxies imply, the informational output of relationship banking is not homogenous. This recognition becomes for first time explicit in Stein (2002) and Berger and Udell (2002) who address theoretically the interplay between organizational structure and financial intermediation, arriving at a common conclusion: flatter bank hierarchies represent better fits for small business lending. As described in Liberti and Petersen (2019), information comprises two distinct types, hard and soft. The former is quantifiable—think, for example, of financial ratios and credit scores (Udell 2008)—and, hence, transmissible by technology such as internet banking or other mediums (Petersen and Rajan 2002; Berger et al. 2005; Hertzberg et al. 2010). Conversely, soft information neither fits in numbers nor can it be evaluated separately from the physical setting which generates it; for instance, loan officers’ conviction that a certain small business owner is liable to deliver because of character and innate aversion to delinquency. Table 1 Panel A summarizes the main characteristics of each information type; Table 1 Panel B illustrates how the ability to process soft information differentiates relationship lending from all other lending technologies. The description provided explains why a clean measure of soft information is unattainable. Harder to explain is why, although soft information is exclusive to in-person communication, the empirical literature evaluates relationship effects without taking into account the mode of communication.
Table 1
Information types and lending technologies
Panel A: Information types (Source: Berger and Udell 2002; Stein 2002; Liberti and Petersen 2019)
 
Hard information
Soft information
Nature
Quantitative: typically recorded as numbers
Qualitative: communicated in-person
Content
Financial ratios, numbers, etc
Opinions, rumors, market commentary, etc
Collection medium
Could be collected, stored electronically, e.g. by computers, databases, etc. Personal and impersonal transmission is possible
Interpersonal communication is essential
Standardization
Standardized format
Flexible format
Third party
Easily transmitted to a third party
Costly to be transmitted to a third party
Panel B: Lending technologies (Source: Berger and Udell 2006; Udell 2008)
 
Descriptor
Nature
Information
Characteristics
Relationship lending
Based on borrower-lender relationship
Relationship-based
Soft
Soft information transmission over time
Financial statement lending
Based on financial statements
Transaction-based
Hard
Should be audited by a CPA; suitable for transparent firms
Asset-based lending
Secured by receivables and inventories
Transaction-based
Hard
High monitoring costs
Factoring
Secured by receivables
Transaction-based
Hard
Lenders’ ownership of the receivables
Leasing
Based on assets purchased by the lender
Transaction-based
Hard
Lenders’ ownership of the assets
Credit scoring
For micro-businesses
Transaction-based
Hard
Small loan amount
Equipment/real estate—based lending
Collateral
Transaction-based
Hard
Based on collateral value
This table identifies soft information as a unique input of relationship banking and describes its main differences with hard information. Panel A summarizes the distinguishing characteristics of each information type. Panel B presents an overview of the available lending technologies
We note three studies attentive to the physical setting of the bank-firm interactions,4 two of which using survey-based evidence from Japan: Uchida et al. (2012) and Hattori et al. (2015). The former study finds that in-person contact improves firms’ perceptions about: (i) access to credit and (ii) the extent to which their idiosyncrasy and needs become apprehensible by banks. The latter study documents that face-to-face interactions with clients are among the key factors which enable branch managers to act as information repositories, more so than loan officers do. Taken together, this evidence, while subjective and of limited generalizability due to the special (keiretsu) character of the Japanese capital market, supports the capacity of in-person communication to reduce friction in the borrower-lender relationship.
From the Italian setting, Gabbi et al. (2020) document an inverse association between the cost of bank loans and the frequency of face-to-face meetings, especially when these are held at the firm’s headquarters. Our research is similar to theirs in that we relate the communication mode to actual banking outcomes rather than firms’ perceptions of them, yet different in a number of ways. First, we present the first evidence, to date, from the world’s largest economy, the U.S, using the same data that the Federal Reserve collects via a nationwide census and relies upon to form policy. Second, the time period in Gabbi et al. spans from 2009 to 2011, consistent with the study’s focus on gauging the effects of credit tightening in the aftermath of the subprime mortgage crisis. By contrast, the recurring nature of the SSBF survey enables us to capture a period extending longer than a decade, including the booming stock market of the 1990s, the subsequent crush, and the recovery in the early 2000s, a through-the-cycle approach which is not exclusively tied to a specific economic environment. Third, our interest lies in developing a symmetric understanding of both the determinants and implications of in-person banking. On the implications side, while borrowing cost is one of our outcome variables, so is an array of other important dimensions including duration, exclusivity, number of financial services purchased, loan maturity, and the phenomenon of discouraged borrowing. The next section delves into the causal mechanism explaining how the communication mode can exert a multifaceted influence on the relationship.

3 Hypothesis development

3.1 In-person banking: determinants

Our first set of hypotheses relates to small firms’ incentives to contact their primary bank in-person. We associate these with a quantifiable component, which is the cost of hardening information, and a subjective component, which is the appeal of face-to-face interactions to small business owners.
Consider the production of hard information first. Within the small business taxonomy, certain firms are smaller than others, possessing even less resources to commit to it. From a complementary perspective, Lang and Lundholm (1993) view the pertinent cost as an increasing function of informational opacity. Berger et al. (2001) indicate multiple reasons (poor accounting records, lack of skill, a lower public profile) in support of an inverse association between firm size and opacity. Consequently, the smaller a firm, the greater its disadvantage at hardening information for external users, rendering interpersonal communication more probable. Formally, we state our first testable hypothesis as follows:
H.1.
In small business, the likelihood of contacting the primary bank in-person is inversely associated with firm size.
When information becomes standardized and available to multiple users, transaction costs decrease (Liberti and Petersen 2019). Scale economies in information production, however, depend on the structure of the local banking market. A smaller number of banks as well as fewer hierarchical layers within the banks limit the scope for information reusability. Rural areas typify both conditions, making interpersonal communication a cost-effective alternative. The converse relates to metropolitan areas. From the perspective of the bank, this distinction has a profound effect on how hard and soft information reflect on customer evaluation. In particular, character is prioritized when the social and civic fabric of the local community can readily supply pertinent information. By contrast, in settings which naturally preclude this possibility, the adherence to formal financial criteria and the cookie cutter approach prevail (Cole et al. 2004; DeYoung et al. 2012). Thus, we formulate our next hypothesis as follows:
H.2.
Small businesses are more likely to contact the primary bank in-person in rural areas.
Naturally, the mode of communication may also be subject to individual choices. Prior research affirms that, due to their size, small firms echo owners’ human capital and antecedent traits. While plenty could find an application in our context, certain demographics—age, gender, and education—are of particular relevance. Accordingly, the in-person approach is compatible with small business owners who are:
  • Older Further to the recognition that these individuals have relied on low-tech processes for a longer period of time, aging begets deterioration in cognitive ability as well as in self-efficacy (i.e. the conviction that one is capable of performing a given task). Hence, tradition and simplicity in processes are preferred to innovation and complexity. For example, there is evidence of a negative association between R&D spending and CEO age (Barker III and Mueller 2002).
  • Female Similar to older individuals, females value simplicity. Venkatesh and Morris (2000), investigating workplace acceptance of information technology, find that the usage decision for female (male) employees depends on the perceived ease of use (functional capabilities). Moreover, females have a natural proclivity to form personal relationships, invoking network-oriented communication with less adherence to social hierarchies (Chai et al. 2011).
  • Less educated Literature widely uses education as a proxy for cognitive ability, implying a positive relation between academic attainment and the ability to manage complexity (e.g. Miller et al. 2015; King et al. 2016). In addition, Shoda et al. (1990) and Parker and Fischoff (2005) provide the more subtle insight that a growing intellect holds back impulsive behaviour. Drawing parallels with small business banking, less educated owners appear less likely to embrace technology and prone to visit the bank more often than is necessary.
In sum, we derive the following hypotheses:
H.3.a.
In small business, the likelihood of contacting the primary bank in-person is positively associated with the owner’s age.
H.3.b.
In small business, the likelihood of contacting the primary bank in-person increases when the owner is female.
H.3.c.
In small business, the likelihood of contacting the primary bank in-person increases for less educated owners.

3.2 In-person banking: implications

Our remaining hypotheses relate to the impact of in-person banking, which we investigate at three distinct levels.
The first level comprises the breadth and depth of banking relationships which we collectively refer to as ‘strength’. As noted earlier, soft information is imparted gradually over multiple (face-to-face) interactions, whereas its nature makes re-verification costly and uncertain (Stein 2002; Liberti and Petersen 2019). Thus, if a small business has already transmitted a large amount of soft information to a bank, it is likely that it will stay within the relationship, as switching to another bank implies the elimination of the value of the accumulated soft information. Formally, we develop the following hypothesis:
H.4.
Small firms which contact the primary bank in-person build stronger banking relationships.
The second level of our investigation concerns contractual features of the relationship, i.e. loan interest rate and maturity. Due to acute information asymmetries, these typically entail disadvantageous terms for small businesses. On the cost side, loan rates increase in order to reflect the additional resources committed to monitoring and information acquisition. On the maturity side, a shorter loan duration enables lenders to assess borrower-specific information period by period, which allows for timely interventions should the default risk changes. In support of the conservative stance, Berger and Frame (2007) document a negative association between maturity and information opacity proxied by firm size, age, R&D, and depreciation. For borrowers, however, a shorter maturity begets inflexibility and capital rationing which might preclude investment opportunities with a longer life cycle (Ortiz-Molina and Penas 2008).
Because the in-person approach offers a more complete picture of the small business customer and, hence, a partial treatment to the information asymmetry problem, the contractual terms of the banking relationship should improve. Parallel to this framework, Liberti and Petersen (2019 p. 13) speculate that an auxiliary behavioral mechanism might come into play, whereby “loan officers can also use their discretion to put a thumb on the scale and influence a loan decision for their own benefit”. Whether involving a fully rational decision making or not, face-to-face communication is predicted to have an empirically equivalent effect on the cost and availability of credit, supporting our next set of hypotheses:
H.5.a.
Small firms which contact the primary bank in-person have access to loans with lower interest rates.
H.5.b.
Small firms which contact the primary bank in-person have access to loans with longer maturities.
At a third and final level, we look at the role of in-person banking in efficient capital allocation using the paradigm of discouraged borrowers, i.e. small firms which are in need of funds and yet refrain from submitting a loan application due to fear of rejection. As per the seminal study of Kon and Storey (2003), self-rationing incentives emanate from the double recognition that, under imperfect information, banks are vulnerable to screening errors and applications costs can be considerable. Kon and Storey also acknowledge a nonmonetary cost component which relates to entrepreneurs’ discomfort about sharing sensitive data about themselves and their enterprises with a third party.
We argue that imparting borrower-specific intelligence in a direct and interpersonal fashion may not only allay the need for expensive hard information but also make entrepreneurs less hesitant to assert their financing needs. Moreover, there should be an asymmetric effect between good and bad quality borrowers as only the former stand to benefit from the leveling of the informational playing field. Hence, we develop our hypotheses as follows:
H.6.a.
In-person banking reduces the probability of discouragement for good quality borrowers.
H.6.b.
In-person banking does not relate to the probability of discouragement for bad quality borrowers.

4 Data

All data comes from the Federal Reserve’s 1993, 1998 and 2003 Survey of Small Business Finances (1993 NSSBF, 1998 SSBF and 2003 SSBF)5 covering the period 1993–2005. Because of its credibility and thoroughness, the SSBF continues to be a leading data source for a host of recent studies in small business (e.g. Berger et al. 2011; Cassar et al. 2015; Cole and Sokolyk 2016; Dai et al. 2017; Durguner 2017; Han et al. 2017). The survey participants comprise 12,438 enterprises (4637 from 1993 NSSBF, 3561 from 1998 and 4240 SSBF) with less than 500 employees, and represent every U.S. region and industry with the exception of agricultural businesses, non-profit organizations, government entities and subsidiaries. In addition, the SSBF provides sampling weights so that the data correctly represents the population of small businesses, overcoming bias due to disproportionate sampling and nonresponse. Echoing the call in prior literature for research designs attentive to this adjustment, we fully incorporate the sampling weights in all analysis in the study.
Table 2 defines the SSBF variables used in the study and presents key descriptive statistics. Confirming the preponderance of face-to-face interactions in small business finance, 77% of firms are shown to interact with their primary financial institution most frequently in-person. Table 3 Panel A identifies the proportion of in-person banking for each category of the independent binary variables (X) in the subsequent regressions and univariately compares the differences in means. As shown, in-person banking is most prevalent in rural areas, when the primary financial institution is a commercial bank, and for owners who are female or lack a university degree. Table 3 Panel B compares the mean value of each dependent variable (Y) based on the communication dichotomy. The two groups systematically differ along most dimensions. In-person communicators, on average, give rise to longer and more exclusive banking relationships, while they also purchase more services from the primary financial institution. Their loyalty appears to result in longer maturity loans.
Table 2
Variable definitions and summary statistics
Variable
Definition
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Mean
SD
Mean
SD
Mean
SD
Mean
SD
In-person
 = 1 if the communication with the primary financial institution is most frequently in-person; 0 otherwise
0.7671
0.4227
0.7686
0.4217
0.7933
0.4050
0.7437
0.4367
Firm and owner characteristics
Female
 = 1 if at least 50% of total ownership belongs to a female; 0 otherwise
0.2648
0.4412
0.2323
0.4223
0.2648
0.4413
0.3009
0.4587
Below degree
 = 1 if the owner lacks a university (bachelor’s) degree; 0 otherwise
0.4892
0.4999
0.4805
0.4997
0.4782
0.4999
0.5083
0.5000
Owner’s age§
The owner’s age in years
51.2949
11.2254
50.1684
11.3525
50.7153
11.2680
53.0378
10.8324
Employees§
Total number of employees
29.8134
58.5813
31.5562
61.9421
25.5268
54.6001
31.5076
57.8551
Corporation
 = 1 if the firm is a corporation; 0 otherwise
0.5718
0.4949
0.6056
0.4888
0.4933
0.5000
0.5983
0.4903
Startup
 = 1 if the firm age is no more than 2 years; 0 otherwise
0.0613
0.2400
0.0410
0.1983
0.0803
0.2718
0.0677
0.2512
Recent failure
 = 1 if the firm or the owner declared bankruptcy in the last 7 years or if the firm had a delinquent record lasting longer than 60 days in the last 3 years; 0 otherwise
0.1864
0.3894
0.2137
0.4100
0.1623
0.3688
0.1767
0.3814
Discouragement
 = 1 if the firm was in need of finance in the last 3 years but did not apply for finance due to fear of rejection; 0 otherwise
0.2353
0.4477
0.2418
0.4283
0.3573
0.4794
0.1571
0.3640
Business environment characteristics
In-person environment
The proportion of firms using in-person communication as the main way of contacting their primary financial institution in the same region and business sector
0.7684
0.1151
0.7696
0.1127
0.7945
0.1059
0.7451
0.1201
Rural area
 = 1 if the firm locates in a non-metropolitan statistical area; 0 if the firm locates in a metropolitan statistical area
0.2112
0.4082
0.2016
0.4013
0.2252
0.4178
0.2099
0.4073
Relationship characteristics
Relationship length#§
The length of the relationship with the primary financial institution in months
112.7700
106.6947
106.2450
97.4020
94.9499
94.7532
134.7666
121.1491
Banking relations
Total number of banking relationships
2.5441
1.7952
2.4699
1.7507
2.3637
1.7322
2.7769
1.8698
Services concentration
 = Number of financial services purchased from the primary financial institution/total financial services utilized by the firm
0.6756
0.2748
0.6701
0.2798
0.6931
0.2716
0.6671
0.2713
Commercial Bank
 = 1 if the primary financial institution is a commercial bank; 0 otherwise
0.8566
0.3505
0.8711
0.3351
0.8558
0.3513
0.8413
0.3654
Exclusivity
 = 1 if the firm maintains one banking relationship; 0 for multiple banking relationships
0.3105
0.4627
0.3376
0.4729
0.3538
0.4782
0.2446
0.4299
Loan characteristics
Interest rate
The interest rate (%) on the most recently approved loan
8.2229
2.5149
8.7865
2.0779
10.1962
2.0280
6.7782
2.3614
Prime rate
The U.S. prime rate (%) at the time of the loan application
5.9456
1.4609
6.4676
0.6954
8.1893
0.3366
4.3147
0.5022
Loan amount§
The loan application amount in $US
748,239
3,242,985
887,367
3,895,793
328,115
1,105,050
715,390
2,728,318
Maturity§
The maturity in months of the most recently approved loan
45.4702
59.0269
40.1042
53.8319
56.8688
67.5882
47.7664
60.9292
This table presents definitions and descriptive statistics (mean and standard deviation) for all variables used in the paper. The sample includes 12,438 U.S. firms which participated in the 1993, 1998 and 2003 Federal Reserve’s Survey of Small Business Finances (1993 NSSBF, 1998 SSBF and 2003 SSBF)
§We use the logarithmic form of Ln(1 + variable) in the regression analysis
#We winsorize the variable at the 1st and 99th percentiles
For approved loans with a reported interest rate in excess of the prime rate
Table 3
Mean comparisons and univariate analysis
Panel A: Mean proportion of in-person banking by variable (X) category
Variable (X)
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
X = 0
X = 1
Diff
X = 0
X = 1
Diff
X = 0
X = 1
Diff
X = 0
X = 1
Diff
Rural area
0.7499 (0.0102)
0.8316 (0.0198)
 − 0.0817***
0.7491 (0.0166)
0.8461 (0.0330)
 − 0.0969***
0.7787 (0.0193)
0.8437 (0.0359)
 − 0.0649
0.7273 (0.0174))
0.8055 (0.0339)
 − 0.0783**
Corporation
0.8145 (0.0141)
0.7334 (0.0119)
0.0811***
0.8247 (0.0239)
0.7335 (0.0189)
0.0911***
0.8307 (0.0244)
0.7578 (0.0240)
0.0730**
0.7864 (0.0249)
0.7164 (0.0199)
0.0699**
Startup
0.7658 (0.0094)
0.7879 (0.0371)
 − 0.0221
0.7684 (0.0151)
0.7742 (0.0733)
 − 0.0058
0.7902 (0.0177)
0.8308 (0.0613)
 − 0.0407
0.7428 (0.0161)
0.7555 (0.0604)
 − 0.0126
Recent failure
0.7693 (0.0101)
0.7578 (0.0209)
0.0115
0.7704 (0.0167)
0.7621 (0.0320)
0.0084
0.7994 (0.0186)
0.7623 (0.0420)
0.0371
0.7426 (0.0171)
0.7487 (0.0367)
 − 0.0061
Commercial bank
0.6054 (0.0240)
0.7948 (0.0098)
 − 0.1894***
0.5538 (0.0413)
0.8020 (0.0159)
 − 0.2481***
0.6305 (0.0448)
0.8207 (0.0184)
 − 0.1902***
0.6322 (0.0390)
0.7647 (0.0169)
 − 0.1325***
Female
0.7524 (0.0106)
0.8133 (0.0178)
 − 0.0609***
0.7515 (0.0169)
0.8251 (0.0307)
 − 0.0736**
0.7813 (0.0197)
0.8279 (0.0335)
 − 0.0466
0.7278 (0.0186)
0.7922 (0.0288)
 − 0.0644*
Below degree
0.7243 (0.0127)
0.8148 (0.0130)
 − 0.0904***
0.7272 (0.0205)
0.8140 (0.0215)
 − 0.0868***
0.7540 (0.0234)
0.8373 (0.0248)
 − 0.0834**
0.6940 (0.0223)
0.7979 (0.0219)
 − 0.1039***
Panel B: Mean comparison of variable (Y) by communication mode
Variable (Y)
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
In-person = 0
In-person = 1
Diff
In-person = 0
In-person = 1
Diff
In-person = 0
In-person = 1
Diff
In-person = 0
In-person = 1
Diff
Employees
53.5534 (1.5509)
23.4593 (0.4945)
30.0941***
57.1516 (2.6386)
24.5628 (0.8655)
32.5888***
50.3809 (3.1157)
19.9733 (0.8232)
30.4076***
52.1232 (2.4145)
25.3058 (0.8552)
26.8175***
Owner’s age
51.3963 (0.2060)
51.2025 (0.1171)
0.1938
50.2196 (0.3446)
50.0283 (0.1919)
0.1913
51.2269 (0.3987)
50.5402 (0.2176)
0.6867
52.7092 (0.3313)
53.1412 (0.1965)
 − 0.4320
Relationship length#
97.8710 (1.8863)
117.2929 (1.1203)
 − 19.4220***
88.4487 (2.7393)
111.6017 (1.6784)
 − 23.1531***
80.0406 (3.0891)
98.8350 (1.8593)
 − 18.7944***
119.1722 (3.5852)
140.1417 (2.1994)
 − 20.9695***
Banking relations
3.1665 (0.0391)
2.4344 (0.0169)
0.7321***
3.0960 (0.0618)
2.3451 (0.0271)
0.7509***
3.1092 (0.0768)
2.2617 (0.0298)
0.8476***
3.2747 (0.0666)
2.6890 (0.0304)
0.5857***
Exclusivity
0.1966 (0.0188)
0.3450 (0.0104)
 − 0.1484***
0.1930 (0.0308)
0.3811 (0.0169)
 − 0.1882***
0.2101 (0.0374)
0.3912 (0.0191)
 − 0.1812***
0.1911 (0.0307)
0.2631 (0.0180)
 − 0.0719***
Services concentration
0.5953 (0.0052)
0.6999 (0.0028)
 − 0.1045***
0.5788 (0.0084)
0.6973 (0.0047)
 − 0.1185***
0.5923 (0.0103)
0.7193 (0.0051)
 − 0.1270***
0.6136 (0.0086)
0.6855 (0.0048)
 − 0.0719***
Interest rate
8.2868 (0.0842)
8.1975 (0.0516)
0.0893
8.8358 (0.0946)
8.7664 (0.0650)
0.0694
10.2616 (0.1200)
10.1732 (0.1143)
0.0884
6.7918 (0.1508)
6.7727 (0.0706)
0.0474
Maturity
40.7793 (1.7874)
47.3361 (1.2843)
 − 6.5569***
38.5023 (2.5189)
40.7582 (1.6681)
 − 2.2559
50.4380 (5.0380)
59.1308 (3.8449)
 − 8.6928
40.2515 (2.9183)
50.7972 (2.1737)
 − 10.5457***
Discouragement
0.2058 (0.0242)
0.2455 (0.0149)
 − 0.0397
0.2347 (0.0373)
0.2441 (0.0206)
 − 0.0094
0.2828 (0.0540)
0.3674 (0.0306)
 − 0.0846
0.1317 (0.0396)
0.1622 (0.0256)
 − 0.0305
This table univariately compares the mean values of key variables used in subsequent regressions. Panel A compares the proportion of in-person banking for each category of the independent (X) binary variables. Panel B displays the mean comparisons for the dependent (Y) variables based on the communication mode (i.e. in-person vs. impersonal banking). The standard errors are reported in parentheses. All variables are defined in Table 2
#We winsorize the variable at the 1th and 99th percentiles
For all approved loans with a reported interest rate in excess of the prime rate

5 Empirical analysis

We investigate our hypotheses in a multivariate regression framework using several estimation methods. Central to all subsequent analyses is the variable in-person, set equal to 1 if the firm communicates most frequently with the primary financial institution face-to-face, and zero otherwise. The variable coding is based on the respective SSBF question requesting the identification of the main (most frequent) banking method from a list of options that includes in-person and a variety of impersonal ways (e.g. by post, internet, ATM, etc.). Unfortunately, the survey requires no further clarification on the number of bank-firm interactions and it therefore becomes impossible to distinguish firms using in-person communication exclusively from firms which utilize a blend of in-person and impersonal ways of banking. Even so, our research design can ensure not only that soft information transmission has taken place but also that the method which makes this possible, i.e. face-to face interaction, has been used more times than any other mode of communication with the primary financial institution. In line with our study’s dual aim, this section proceeds in two steps. First, we use in-person as the dependent variable to gauge the key determinants. Subsequently, we place it on the right-hand side to assess its explanatory power over the banking outcomes of relationship strength (i.e. length of relationship, exclusivity, services concentration), loan contracting (i.e. interest rate, maturity of loans), and discouraged borrowing. To fully exploit our dataset, we run each regression using pooled data from 1993 NSSBF, 1998 SSBF, and 2003 SSBF as in Berger et al. (2011), and supplement these results with separate evidence drawn from each individual round as in Cole and Sokolyk (2016).

5.1 The decision to contact the primary bank in-person

Starting from the determinants, our ex ante expectation was that the propensity for face-to-face communication increases with a smaller firm size (H1) and a rural banking market (H2). As a joint test to these hypotheses, we specify the following probit model:
$$\begin{aligned} Probit\left( {in{\text{-}}person_{i} } \right) & = \beta_{0} + \beta_{1} employees_{i} + \beta_{2} rural\;area_{i} + \beta_{3} corporation_{i} \\ & \quad + \;\beta_{4} startup_{i} + \beta_{5} recent\;failure_{i} + \beta_{6} commercial\;bank_{i} \\ & \quad + \;fixed\;effects + \varepsilon_{i} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(1)
where in-person is regressed on our firm size proxy employees (Wagner 2001; Angelini and Generale 2008) and rural area which is coded as 1 if a firm locates in a non-metropolitan statistical area, and 0 otherwise (Berger et al. 2011). Firm-specific variables as well as other factors might exert a confounding influence on selecting the interaction mode with the main bank; we account for this possibility by the inclusion of covariates regularly appearing in studies utilizing the SSBF dataset (see, e.g., Cole and Sokolyk 2016; Dai et al. 2017). Specifically, we employ the dichotomous variables of: corporation indicating whether or not the firm has attained a corporate form; startup flagging an age of 2 years or younger; recent failure evidenced either by a bankruptcy within the last 7 years or firm’s delinquent behavior within the last 3 years; and commercial bank indicating whether the firm’s primary financial provider is a commercial bank or another institution. The fixed effects control for the SIC division and geographic region. Finally, ε denotes the error term.
As predicted by H3, owners’ personal attributes are more likely to be discernible in the organizational choices of small businesses, claiming an incremental effect on our dependent variable. To test this hypothesis, we complement the set of covariates in Model 1 with variables capturing the principal owner’s gender, education (i.e. whether the owner’s highest educational qualification is below the level of a bachelor’s degree) and age. Accordingly, we specify Model 2 as follows:
$$\begin{aligned} Probit\left( {in{\text{-}}person_{i} } \right) & = \beta_{0} + \beta_{1} employees_{i} + \beta_{2} rural\;area_{i} + \beta_{3} corporation_{i} \\ & \quad + \;\beta_{4} startup_{i} + \beta_{5} recent\;failure_{i} + \beta_{6} commercial\;bank_{i} + \beta_{7} female_{i} \\ & \quad + \;\beta_{8} below\;degree_{i} + \beta_{9} owner^{\prime}s\;age_{i} + fixed\;effects + \varepsilon_{i} . \\ \end{aligned}$$
(2)
Table 4 presents the results from both models. Model 1 confirms that employees and rural area reflect on the decision about the physical setting of the communication with the primary bank. The coefficients on the two variables, both statistically significant at the 1% level, display the theoretically predicted signs: smaller firms as well as those operating in rural areas favor the in-person approach supporting H1 and H2, respectively. Based on the pooled data, the marginal effect of employees is -6.33%, becoming − 1.06% at the variable’s median value (5 employees) estimated as -6.33% / (1 + 5). Simply put, the likelihood of contacting the primary financial institution in-person decreases by 1.06% for every additional employee. The marginal effect of rural area indicates that, in a non-metropolitan statistical area, the in-person method is 7.13% more likely than in a metropolitan area. The highest marginal effect, 23.57%, relates to commercial bank, which suggests that firms tend to contact banks in-person more often than other financial providers, alluding to the formers’ ability to process soft information (Berger and Udell 2006; Liberti and Petersen 2019). Overall, the model yields a pseudo-R2 of 8.89%.
Table 4
Determinants of in-person banking
 
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
Model 4
Model 5
Model 6
Model 7
Model 8
Employees
 − 0.2180*** (0.0107)
 − 0.2090*** (0.0111)
 − 0.1619*** (0.0279)
 − 0.1543*** (0.0284)
 − 0.1299*** (0.0308)
 − 0.1227*** (0.0312)
 − 0.1280*** (0.0302)
 − 0.1284*** (0.0313)
Rural area
0.2617*** (0.0345)
0.2314*** (0.0349)
0.2104*** (0.0769)
0.1893** (0.0774)
0.2488*** (0.0793)
0.2254*** (0.0796)
0.2789*** (0.0790)
0.2330*** (0.081)
Corporation
0.0001 (0.0315)
0.0230 (0.0318)
 − 0.0778 (0.0659)
 − 0.0570 (0.0663)
 − 0.0906 (0.0691)
 − 0.0721 (0.0693)
0.0822 (0.0696)
0.0972 (0.0698)
Startup
 − 0.0207 (0.0571)
0.0216 (0.0584)
0.0149 (0.1359)
0.0425 (0.1396)
0.0680 (0.1146)
0.0837 (0.1158)
0.0052 (0.1018)
0.1121 (0.1069)
Recent failure
0.0166 (0.0336)
0.0106 (0.0339)
 − 0.0557 (0.0696)
 − 0.0655 (0.0701)
 − 0.0392 (0.0790)
 − 0.0383 (0.0791)
 − 0.0159 (0.0804)
 − 0.0127 (0.0806)
Commercial bank
0.6966*** (0.0357)
0.7075*** (0.0359)
0.848*** (0.0756)
0.8535*** (0.0762)
0.6906*** (0.0788)
0.7024*** (0.0791)
0.4907*** (0.0746)
0.5044*** (0.0750)
Female
 
0.0913*** (0.0318)
 
0.0307 (0.0690)
 
0.0718 (0.0738)
 
 − 0.0197 (0.0659)
Below degree
 
0.2357*** (0.0278)
 
0.1908*** (0.0600)
 
0.1652** (0.0653)
 
0.2625*** (0.0647)
Owner’s age
 
0.1841*** (0.0636)
 
0.0292 (0.1350)
 
0.1047 (0.1378)
 
0.5655*** (0.1464)
Year dummies
Yes
Yes
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
U.S. region dummies
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
SIC division dummies
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Constant
0.5305*** (0.0541)
 − 0.3279 (0.2505)
0.6492*** (0.1237)
0.4394 (0.5272)
0.4451*** (0.1021)
 − 0.0755 (0.5426)
0.2585** (0.1029)
 − 2.0726*** (0.5887)
Observations
12,108
12,049
4539
4539
3422
3422
4146
4087
Pseudo R2
0.0889
0.0949
0.0868
0.0906
0.0652
0.0687
0.0515
0.0638
This table analyzes the factors underlying the firm’s decision to communicate with the primary financial provider in-person. Models 1 to 8 present the results from probit regressions where the dependent variable is in-person. To correct for nonresponse and disproportionate sampling, the SSBF-provided weights are applied in each survey round. The robust standard errors feature in parentheses. All variables are defined in Table 2 and have variance inflation factors (VIFs) substantially lower than 5. ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively
If in-person banking simply mirrors the personal choice of small business owners, the above results should disappear with the inclusion of the additional variables in Model 2. This, however, is not the case, as all Model 1 findings remain qualitatively similar. Net of firm and banking market characteristics, the evidence in support of owners’ fixed effects leads to three main insights. First, owners lacking a bachelor’s degree are 6.77% more likely to visit the bank premises compared with university graduates. Second, the resulting coefficient on female is significantly positive, indicating that female owners are more likely to choose in-person banking with a marginal effect of 2.58%. Third, the older the individual, the stronger the appeal of in-person banking, which highlights the element of simplicity embedded into face-to-face interactions. The marginal effect is 5.30%, implying that the probability of in-person banking increases by 0.10%6 for each additional year of owner’s age. Jointly, the variables on the owners’ characteristics increase the pseudo-R2 to 9.49% and sketch a profile for in-person communicators which is compatible with hypotheses H.3.a, H.3.b, and H.3.c. The clear implication of this evidence is that impersonal technologies or other banking automations, if applied indiscriminately, might alienate an important clientele which would otherwise generate considerable soft information.
Extending the above analysis to each individual SSBF round, in Models 3 to 8, the results are largely consistent with the pooled data, particularly with regard to rural area, firm size and owners’ education.

5.2 The impact of contacting the primary bank in-person

Because the capacity to inform decisions with soft information remains exclusive to in-person contact, the latter should also entail unique implications. To gauge these, we specify equations which draw the dependent variable from a large pool of banking outcomes but use a common set of independent variables: in-person and the covariates which previously entered into the determinants regressions.
In estimating the equations, we are confronted with the problem of endogeneity which might arise from factors potentially correlating with the communication decision but remaining unobservable to the SSBF survey. Indicatively, Uchida et al. (2012) caution that loan officers’ turnover undermines the bank’s ability to act as an information repository and Schoar (2012) finds that bonding (or lack thereof) with bank relationship managers explains some of the variation in borrowers’ delinquency. To allay such concerns, all findings are subjected to a rigorous treatment for endogeneity which is described in detail in the appendices to this paper.

5.2.1 In-person contact and strength of banking relationship

To test H4, we introduce four relationship strength proxies and consider the following associations.
5.2.1.1 In-person contact and length of banking relationship
Our first proxy, relationship length, is measured by the number of months that the firm has been receiving services from the primary bank, following Berger et al. (2005). We examine the interplay of this variable with the communication dichotomy by means of ordinary least squares (OLS) and treatment effects (TE) estimation (“Appendix 1”). In the latter procedure, our instrument in the 1st-stage regressions is the variable in-person environment, defined as the proportion of firms using face-to-face communication with their primary bank within the firm’s geographic region and business sector. Intuitively, a preference for this communication mode from the firm’s peer group strongly correlates with in-person; at the same time, the exogenous nature of the former variable precludes it from exerting a bearing on the dependent variable in the 2nd-stage, which is a necessary condition for satisfying the exclusion restriction.
The results are reported in Table 5. The positive and statistically significant (at 1% level) coefficient on in-person affirms that face-to-face interactions enhance the longevity of the relationship. In assessing the magnitude of the effect, we note the statistical significance of both the inverse Mills ratio (IMR) and the χ2 statistic derived from the Wald test. This evidence substantiates the endogeneity concerns, attaching increased validity to the TE method over OLS (Greene 2012; Guo and Fraser 2015). Based on the endogeneity-corrected estimates (Model 5), the average length of the primary banking relationship for in-person communicators is 76.43 months, decreasing to 58.55 months for the rest of the sample firms. The difference, about one-fifth, is substantial and aligned with the notion that once a significant amount of soft information has been transmitted, the firm typically commits to the incumbent banking relationship due to the high verification cost of this type of information for a third party (Bertomeu and Marinovic 2016). Models 6 to 8 provide separate evidence from each individual round in support of this conclusion.
Table 5
In-person banking and relationship length
 
OLS
TE
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
Model 4
Model 5
Model 6
Model 7
Model 8
    
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
In-person
0.2683*** (0.0231)
0.4283*** (0.0602)
0.2268*** (0.0537)
0.2341*** (0.0457)
0.4886*** (0.0985)
 
0.9072*** (0.2050)
 
1.1368*** (0.2355)
 
1.4571*** (0.0945)
 
In-person environment
     
2.3179*** (0.1650)
 
2.5619*** (0.4667)
 
2.8683*** (0.5016)
 
2.0676*** (0.4549)
Rural area
0.2259*** (0.0220)
0.2281*** (0.0473)
0.1617*** (0.0503)
0.1439*** (0.0471)
0.2088*** (0.0230)
0.0832** (0.0366)
0.2065*** (0.0482)
0.0160 (0.0861)
0.1162** (0.0548)
0.0740 (0.0879)
0.0611 (0.0522)
0.0981 (0.0777)
Commercial bank
0.2898*** (0.0290)
0.6366*** (0.0723)
0.0878 (0.0539)
0.1529*** (0.0467)
0.2420*** (0.0334)
0.7105*** (0.0354)
0.5157*** (0.0920)
0.8799*** (0.0761)
 − 0.0941 (0.0741)
0.6912*** (0.0790)
 − 0.0315 (0.0568)
0.4839*** (0.0739)
Other firm-aspect characteristics
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Constant
3.7346*** (0.0477)
3.2059*** (0.1161)
3.8298*** (0.0731)
4.2861*** (0.0679)
3.5881*** (0.0778)
 − 1.5059*** (0.1471)
2.8675*** (0.1810)
 − 1.6857*** (0.4309)
3.2168*** (0.1777)
 − 1.9352*** (0.4338)
3.5387*** (0.0956)
 − 6.0768*** (0.5726)
Inverse Mills ratio
    
 − 0.1342** (0.0593)
 
 − 0.2685** (0.1170)
 
 − 0.5711*** (0.1617)
 
 − 0.9042*** (0.0833)
 
Observations
12,108
4539
3422
4147
12,108
4539
3422
4147
Wald test of endogeneity (χ2)
    
5.61**
5.27**
12.48***
117.92***
This table presents the regression results of the relationship length (dependent variable) with the primary financial institution on in-person and other control variables. Models 1 to 4 report the OLS estimates and Models 5 to 8 feature the treatment effects (TE) regression estimates. All regressions include SIC division and U.S. region dummies, Models 1 and 5 also include year fixed effects. To correct for nonresponse and disproportionate sampling, the SSBF-provided weights are applied in each survey round. The robust standard errors are displayed in parentheses. All variables are defined in Table 2 and have variance inflation factors (VIFs) substantially lower than 5. ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively
5.2.1.2 In-person contact and exclusivity of banking relationship
A host of studies identify the firm’s network of banking relationships by counting the number of different financial services providers (e.g. Han et al. 2008; Iturralde et al. 2010; Castelli et al. 2012; Yu et al. 2015). Other studies focus on whether or not the firm maintains a sole (exclusive) banking relationship (Elsas 2005; Berger et al. 2008). For our purpose, we exploit both proxies to apply two methodologically disparate procedures: (1) a regression with treatment effects (TE) on the count variable of banking relations; and (2) a recursive bivariate probit (RBP) on the dummy variable of exclusivity (“Appendix 2”). Both methods instrument in-person with the exogenous variable in-person environment, which does not directly relate to banking relations or exclusivity.
The results are reported in Tables 6 and 7. As displayed in Table 6, the TE model suggests that firms contacting the primary bank in-person maintain fewer banking ties than firms applying impersonal communication. The RBP model, in Table 7, concludes similarly by showing that—based on the pooled data (Model 5)—in-person communicators are 24.46% more likely to develop an exclusive banking relationship. The regression results from the individual survey rounds (Models 6–8) are consistent with the inferences supported by the pooled data. Overall, the results in Tables 6 and 7 complement the findings on the duration of the bank-firm collaboration, highlighting loyalty as an additional dimension of the relationship.
Table 6
In-person banking and number of banking relationships
 
OLS
TE
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
Model 4
Model 5
Model 6
Model 7
Model 8
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
In-person
 − 0.2961*** (0.0388)
 − 0.2779*** (0.0664)
 − 0.3339*** (0.071)
 − 0.1933*** (0.0708)
 − 0.5045*** (0.1077)
 
 − 1.6341*** (0.3359)
 
 − 1.6617*** (0.2117)
 
 − 1.3097*** (0.3986)
 
In-person environment
     
2.7917*** (0.1974)
 
2.4905*** (0.4228)
 
2.0365*** (0.4659)
 
2.6482*** (0.5645)
Rural area
0.0394 (0.0355)
 − 0.083 (0.0541)
0.1005 (0.063)
 − 0.032 (0.0639)
0.0551 (0.036)
0.0408 (0.0378)
 − 0.022 (0.06)
0.0253 (0.0787)
0.1669** (0.0666)
0.1863** (0.0819)
0.0414 (0.0720)
0.1679** (0.0806)
Commercial bank
 − 0.3999*** (0.0411)
 − 0.4273*** (0.0711)
 − 0.2389*** (0.0736)
 − 0.3845*** (0.0737)
 − 0.3552*** (0.0471)
0.7011*** (0.0354)
 − 0.0848 (0.1218)
0.8381*** (0.0761)
0.0266 (0.0947)
0.2267*** (0.0855)
 − 0.2148*** (0.1037)
0.2070*** (0.0800)
Other firm-aspect characteristics
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Constant
1.6477*** (0.0656)
1.7135*** (0.114)
1.704*** (0.1063)
1.6029*** (0.1018)
1.7875*** (0.0961)
 − 1.5371*** (0.3555)
2.6718*** (0.2485)
 − 1.6704*** (0.3862)
2.5984*** (0.1671)
 − 1.9761*** (0.4091)
2.2887*** (0.2552)
 − 2.4191*** (0.4423)
Inverse Mills ratio
    
0.0779** (0.0392)
 
0.6375*** (0.1920)
 
0.6836*** (0.1370)
 
0.5276*** (0.2051)
 
Observations
12,108
4539
3422
4147
12,108
4539
3422
4147
Wald test of endogeneity (χ2)
    
4.25**
5.27**
24.88***
6.62**
This table analyzes the effect of in-person and other control variables on the number of banking relationships. Banking relations is the dependent variable in the OLS and treatment effects (TE) estimation presented in Models 1 to 4 and Models 5 to 8, respectively. All regressions include SIC division and U.S. region dummies, Models 1 and 5 also include year fixed effects. To correct for nonresponse and disproportionate sampling, the SSBF-provided weights are applied in each survey round. The robust standard errors are shown in parentheses. All variables are defined in Table 2 and have variance inflation factors (VIFs) substantially lower than 5. ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively
Table 7
In-person banking and exclusivity of banking relationships
 
Probit
RBP
Pooled Data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
Model 4
Model 5
Model 6
Model 7
Model 8
    
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
In-person
0.2364*** (0.0337)
0.3362*** (0.0713)
0.2831*** (0.0770)
0.1304* (0.0719)
0.8012*** (0.1805)
 
1.2330*** (0.3284)
 
1.1284*** (0.3149)
 
1.3035*** (0.1392)
 
In-person environment
     
2.2343*** (0.1817)
 
2.3250*** (0.4794)
 
2.7937*** (0.5567)
 
2.8441*** (0.5592)
Rural area
0.0213 (0.0311)
0.1069* (0.0605)
 − 0.0500 (0.0666)
0.0706 (0.0680)
 − 0.0165 (0.0331)
0.0808 (0.0367)
0.0589 (0.0627)
0.0526 (0.0834)
 − 0.0915 (0.0670)
0.0617 (0.0848)
 − 0.0242 (0.0647)
0.1041 (0.0820)
Commercial bank
0.3227*** (0.0374)
0.4680*** (0.0774)
0.1599** (0.0763)
0.2757*** (0.0741)
0.1894*** (0.0594)
0.7038*** (0.0358)
0.1992 (0.1458)
0.8385*** (0.0751)
 − 0.0262 (0.1076)
0.6905*** (0.0786)
0.0214 (0.0805)
0.5029*** (0.0749)
Other firm-aspect characteristics
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
U.S. region dummies
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
SIC division dummies
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Year dummies
Yes
N/A
N/A
N/A
Yes
Yes
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
Constant
0.0487 (0.0589)
 − 0.1983*** (0.1257)
0.0539 (0.1101)
0.2408*** (0.1128)
 − 0.3440*** (0.1371)
 − 2.6039*** (0.2982)
 − 0.8289*** (0.2552)
 − 2.0753*** (0.6502)
 − 0.5197** (0.2455)
 − 2.8221*** (0.6687)
 − 0.5101*** (0.1446)
 − 4.3819*** (0.6837)
Fisher’s z transformed correlation
    
 − 0.3516** (0.1239)
 
 − 0.5936** (0.2883)
 
 − 0.5473** (0.2572)
 
 − 0.9471*** (0.2035)
 
Observations
12,106
4539
3422
4144
12,106
4539
3422
4145
Wald test of endogeneity (χ2)
    
8.05***
4.24**
4.53**
21.66***
This table analyzes the effect of in-person and other control variables on the exclusivity of banking relationships. Exclusivity is the dependent variable in the probit and recursive bivariate probit (RBP) estimation presented in Models 1 to 4 and Models 5 to 8, respectively. To correct for nonresponse and disproportionate sampling, the SSBF-provided weights are applied in each survey round. The robust standard errors are shown in parentheses. All variables are defined in Table 2 and have variance inflation factors (VIFs) substantially lower than 5. ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively
5.2.1.3 In-person contact and financial services concentration
As a fourth and final proxy for banking relationship strength, we introduce a novel measure to the literature, services concentration, defined as the ratio of services provided by the primary financial institution to the total number of services the firm utilizes. The descriptive statistics revealed that sample firms, on average, purchase 68% of financial services from the primary institution. We investigate the extent to which this behavior depends on the contacting approach by means of OLS and TE estimation, as in previous analysis.
Table 8 reports the regression results. The positive and statistically significant (p = 1%) coefficient on in-person is common in both estimation models. Significant are also the inverse Mills ratio and the χ2 statistic in the Wald test, underlining, once again, the need to control for endogeneity. This association, surviving in the individual survey rounds, implies that, when relationships are built on face-to-face communication, the primary bank acts as a one-stop shop for the totality of the small firm’s financial needs. In turn, this positively impacts the entire range of available services. Together, the evidence from all four proxies for relationship strength supports H4, elucidating how in-person banking results into loyal customers who generate more revenue—this is clearly valuable from the bank’s perspective.
Table 8
In-person banking and services concentration
 
OLS
TE
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
Model 4
Model 5
Model 6
Model 7
Model 8
    
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
In-person
0.0549*** (0.0059)
0.0811*** (0.0142)
0.0821*** (0.0154)
0.0568*** (0.0151)
0.1488*** (0.0541)
 
0.4363*** (0.1164)
 
0.4775*** (0.0315)
 
0.2753*** (0.1039)
 
In-person environment
     
2.7155*** (0.2183)
 
1.6944*** (0.5086)
 
1.1253*** (0.3909)
 
2.2585*** (0.8107)
Rural area
0.0053 (0.0058)
0.0330*** (0.0122)
 − 0.0091 (0.0132)
0.0187 (0.0139)
 − 0.0015 (0.0071)
0.0515 (0.0376)
0.0156 (0.0145)
0.0514 (0.0771)
 − 0.0286* (0.0147)
0.2304*** (0.0750)
0.0044 (0.0155)
0.1509* (0.0821)
Commercial bank
0.1256*** (0.0073)
0.1334*** (0.0156)
0.0818*** (0.0163)
0.1161*** (0.0162)
0.1049*** (0.0136)
0.6991*** (0.0352)
0.0457 (0.0336)
0.8151*** (0.0797)
0.0024 (0.0191)
0.1576* (0.0884)
0.0829*** (0.0225)
0.4891*** (0.0747)
Other firm-aspect characteristics
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
U.S. region dummies
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
SIC division dummies
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Year dummies
Yes
N/A
N/A
N/A
Yes
Yes
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
Constant
0.6530*** (0.0115)
0.6463*** (0.0250)
0.6924*** (0.0234)
0.6979*** (0.0233)
0.5821*** (0.0390)
 − 1.6147*** (0.3674)
0.3909*** (0.0849)
 − 1.6475*** (0.6120)
0.4257*** (0.0329)
 − 1.2799*** (0.3512)
0.5637*** (0.0680)
 − 1.3682** (0.6172)
Inverse Mills ratio
    
 − 0.2132** (0.1025)
 
 − 0.8265*** (0.3102)
 
 − 1.0955*** (0.0944)
 
 − 0.4815** (0.2377)
 
Observations
12,098
4539
3416
4143
12,098
4539
3416
4143
Wald test of endogeneity (χ2)
    
4.05**
7.10***
134.82***
4.10**
This table analyzes the effect of in-person and other control variables on the extent to which a firm’s consumption of financial services is concentrated. The dependent variable is services concentration defined as the ratio of financial services purchased from the primary financial institution to the total financial services used by the firm. Models 1 to 4 report the OLS estimates and Models 5 to 8 the treatment effects (TE) regression estimates. To correct for nonresponse and disproportionate sampling, the SSBF-provided weights are applied in each survey round. The robust standard errors are shown in parentheses. All variables are defined in Table 2 and have variance inflation factors (VIFs) substantially lower than 5. ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively

5.2.2 In-person contact and loan contracting

To examine whether value also accrues to the other end of the relationship, as predicted by our fifth hypothesis, we collect additional information on borrowing cost and maturity from individual loan contracts made between the firms and their primary financial institution. This gives rise to the proxy variables of interest rate7 and maturity measured in months. In addition, we use loan amount and prime rate, both measured at the time of the loan application, as the loan-specific controls in the subsequent regressions. We restrict the analysis to the most recently approved loans with interest rates in excess of prime rate, which leaves a total of 3,264 observations (1,497 from NSSBF 1993, 500 from SSBF1998, and 1,267 from SSBF2003).
5.2.2.1 In-person contact and borrowing cost
To test H.5.a., we conduct OLS and TE regressions, reporting the results in Table 9. In the TE regressions, we instrument in-person, as before, by the exogenous variable in-person environment, which does not associate with interest rate. According to the pooled data regressions, our evidence suggests that the interest rate on the loans obtained by firms contacting their primary financial institution mainly in-person is, on average, 11 basis points lower than the interest rate on loans issued to the rest of the firms (the difference is 22 basis points according to the OLS estimate which we, however, discard due to endogeneity). The individual survey rounds yield qualitatively similar results. On this basis, in-person communicators’ access to cheaper credit proves robust. Furthermore, borrowing cost inversely relates to the loan amount (Degryse and Cayseele 2000; Lian 2018) as well as owners’ age and educational attainment (Wu and Chua 2012).
To further strengthen our interpretation that borrowing cost declines because of face-to-face communication mitigating the informational wedge with the primary financial institution, we next focus on two types of firms that have a greater disadvantage at hardening information: young firms, due to limited organizational experience, and firms owned by individuals without a university degree, due to lack in educational capital. For this analysis, we create two augmented forms of the borrowing cost specification: the first includes the interaction term in-person × startup and the second the interaction in-person × below degree. Table 10 reports the 2nd-stage results of instrumental variables estimation for both specifications. Models 1 to 4 show that while start-up firms are, in general, associated with a higher borrowing cost, they are able to borrow cheaper when adhering to in-person banking. Analogously, in Models 5 to 8, the borrowing cost is higher for non-university graduate owners, however, cheaper loans are attainable if these owners shift to predominantly in-person communication. Jointly, these results confirm the capacity of in-person communication to compensate for a firm’s heightened information opacity.
Table 9
In-person banking and cost of loans
 
OLS
TE
Pooled Data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
Model 4
Model 5
Model 6
Model 7
Model 8
    
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
In-person
 − 0.2241** (0.0914)
 − 0.1956** (0.0961)
 − 0.3055** (0.1501)
 − 1.0443*** (0.3869)
 − 2.0474*** (0.1832)
 
 − 2.5240*** (0.1679)
 
 − 3.2130*** (0.3916)
 
 − 2.1857*** (0.6910)
 
In-person environment
     
1.6914*** (0.2670)
 
1.4176*** (0.3863)
 
1.8426** (0.7231)
 
2.8477*** (0.7785)
Rural area
 − 0.2307*** (0.0791)
0.0222 (0.1756)
 − 0.7807*** (0.2221)
 − 0.4613* (0.2468)
 − 0.0960 (0.0900)
0.1198* (0.0649)
0.0844 (0.1355)
0.1115 (0.0969)
 − 0.6177** (0.2601)
 − 0.1227 (0.1547)
 − 0.4213* (0.2457)
0.0092 (0.1468)
Commercial bank
 − 0.1952 (0.1274)
 − 0.5698* (0.3118)
0.0658 (0.3416)
 − 0.3284 (0.4037)
0.2436** (0.1236)
0.2830*** (0.0835)
0.2366 (0.1872)
0.4147*** (0.1289)
1.3123*** (0.4157)
0.9051*** (0.2102)
 − 0.0665 (0.4431)
0.3410* (0.1781)
Prime rate
0.7255*** (0.0607)
0.8335*** (0.1529)
0.4116 (0.3266)
0.4859*** (0.1518)
0.7223*** (0.0642)
 − 0.0067 (0.0428)
0.7392*** (0.0791)
 − 0.0271 (0.0514)
0.6123 (0.3816)
0.0365 (0.2085)
0.5260*** (0.1523)
0.2042* (0.1113)
Loan amount
 − 0.2953*** (0.0276)
 − 0.4058*** (0.0761)
 − 0.3965*** (0.0759)
 − 0.6189*** (0.0932)
 − 0.3601*** (0.0263)
 − 0.1012*** (0.0168)
 − 0.3527*** (0.0374)
 − 0.1066*** (0.0236)
 − 0.4861*** (0.0946)
 − 0.2524*** (0.0457)
 − 0.6444*** (0.0973)
 − 0.0813* (0.0447)
Female
 − 0.0582 (0.0916)
 − 0.2199 (0.1738)
 − 0.0198 (0.2414)
 − 0.1708 (0.2693)
 − 0.0209 (0.0931)
0.0816 (0.0640)
 − 0.0639 (0.1426)
 − 0.0482 (0.0945)
0.2440 (0.2999)
0.2940* (0.1772)
 − 0.1469 (0.2683)
0.0819 (0.3102)
Below degree
0.2173*** (0.0790)
0.1283** (0.0601)
0.4668** (0.2265)
0.7809*** (0.2355)
0.3467*** (0.0817)
0.2399*** (0.0541)
0.3417*** (0.1205)
0.1545* (0.0791)
0.3913** (0.1982)
 − 0.0377 (0.1526)
0.8693*** (0.2445)
0.3328** (0.1308)
Owner’s age
 − 0.6238*** (0.1817)
 − 0.3958 (0.4163)
 − 0.0342 (0.4599)
 − 1.0751* (0.5567)
 − 0.5234*** (0.1895)
0.2500** (0.1268)
 − 0.1666 (0.2775)
0.3203* (0.1822)
 − 0.1809 (0.5738)
0.0873 (0.0457)
 − 0.9193* (0.5582)
0.8199*** (0.3102)
Other firm-aspect characteristics
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
U.S. region dummies
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
SIC division dummies
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Year dummies
Yes
N/A
N/A
N/A
Yes
Yes
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
Constant
11.0676*** (0.8587)
10.1744*** (1.7036)
12.1716*** (3.0740)
18.4384*** (2.7385)
12.3776*** (0.8866)
 − 1.6953*** (0.6462)
11.0589*** (1.2453)
 − 1.1656 (0.8875)
13.4808*** (3.7167)
0.2879 (2.0367)
18.5477*** (2.7694)
 − 6.5395*** (1.5786)
Inverse Mills ratio
    
0.6083*** (0.0599)
 
0.9084*** (0.0609)
 
1.7944*** (0.2103)
 
0.2968** (0.1326)
 
Observations
3241
1497
498
1246
3241
1497
498
1246
Wald test of endogeneity (χ2)
    
103.03***
222.80***
72.77***
5.00**
This table presents the regressions results of the interest rate on the firm’s most recently approved loan (dependent variable) on in-person and other control variables. Models 1 to 4 report the OLS regression estimates and Models 5 to 8 report the estimates from the treatment effects (TE) regressions. To correct for nonresponse and disproportionate sampling, the SSBF-provided weights are applied in each survey round. The robust standard errors are presented in parentheses. All variables are defined in Table 2 and have variance inflation factors (VIFs) substantially lower than 5. ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively
Table 10
In-person banking and cost of loans under heightened information asymmetry
 
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
Model 4
Model 5
Model 6
Model 7
Model 8
In-person
 − 0.2060** (0.0886)
 − 0.1976** (0.0929)
 − 0.3144** (0.1533)
 − 0.9662** (0.3869)
 − 0.2318** (0.0917)
 − 0.1970** (0.0934)
 − 0.3027** (0.1521)
 − 0.9851*** (0.3155)
In-person × startup
 − 0.4182** (0.1899)
 − 0.3973** (0.1826)
 − 0.3893** (0.1768)
 − 0.7982** (0.4023)
    
In-person × below degree
    
 − 0.1785** (0.0810)
 − 0.1363** (0.0691)
 − 0.3723** (0.1897)
 − 0.4978** (0.2512)
Startup
0.5470** (0.2471)
0.5386** (0.2566)
0.5985*** (0.2274)
1.3368** (0.6048)
0.2732** (0.1382)
0.2784** (0.1359)
0.3013** (0.1502)
0.5067** (0.2362)
Below degree
0.2166*** (0.0788)
0.1281** (0.0633)
0.4682** (0.2256)
0.7573*** (0.2369)
0.2152*** (0.0763)
0.1262** (0.0608)
0.4597** (0.2162)
0.7518*** (0.2402)
Control variables
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
U.S. region and SIC division dummies
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Year dummies
Yes
N/A
N/A
N/A
Yes
N/A
N/A
N/A
Observations
3241
1497
498
1246
3241
1497
498
1246
Endogeneity test (LM statistic χ2)
6.82***
3.93**
5.68**
7.13***
8.52***
4.58**
5.21**
9.08***
This table presents the regressions results of the interest rate on the firm’s most recently approved loan (dependent variable) on in-person and its interaction with variables associated with heightened information asymmetry. Models 1 to 4 use the interaction term in-person × startup and Models 5 to 8 the interaction term in-person × below degree. All regressions are based on instrumental variables (IV) estimation and employ the same set of control variables used in Table 9 regressions; in the interest of space, the resulting coefficients on these variables and the 1st-stage regression results are suppressed but remain available upon request. To correct for nonresponse and disproportionate sampling, the SSBF-provided weights are applied in each survey round. The robust standard errors are presented in parentheses. All variables are defined in Table 2 and have variance inflation factors (VIFs) substantially lower than 5. ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively
5.2.2.2 In-person contact and loan maturity
We test H.5.b. in an identical procedure with H.5.a. and report the results in Table 11. Again, a highly endogenous relationship between the dependent variable and in-person surfaces. The TE model indicates that the maturity of the most recently issued loan to firms contacting their primary financial institution in-person is, according to the pooled data results, on average, 3.37 months longer than the maturity granted to firms opting for impersonal banking. The longer maturity, also evident in each individual SSBF round, substantiates the positive effect of soft information on credit availability.
Table 11
In-person banking and maturity of loans
 
OLS
TE
Pooled Data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
Model 4
Model 5
Model 6
Model 7
Model 8
    
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
In-person
0.1389*** (0.0421)
0.1246** (0.0617)
0.3040** (0.1522)
0.2036** (0.1027)
0.9365*** (0.1612)
 
0.5849*** (0.2135)
 
1.2474*** (0.4308)
 
1.0531*** (0.2417)
 
In-person environment
     
1.8024*** (0.2800)
 
1.8009*** (0.4720)
 
1.8931* (1.0192)
 
2.2799*** (0.4537)
Rural area
 − 0.0093 (0.0440)
0.0385 (0.0797)
 − 0.1621 (0.1451)
 − 0.1135 (0.1037)
 − 0.0678 (0.0465)
0.1616** (0.0664)
 − 0.0289 (0.0649)
0.1651 (0.1058)
 − 0.2121 (0.1461)
0.3040 (0.221)
 − 0.0599 (0.0748)
0.0416 (0.1054)
Commercial bank
 − 0.1665*** (0.0606)
 − 0.3397*** (0.1117)
0.1455 (0.1909)
 − 0.1368 (0.1423)
 − 0.3579*** (0.0705)
0.7421*** (0.0743)
 − 0.4655*** (0.1028)
0.3407** (0.1415)
 − 0.1523 (0.2160)
0.3544 (0.2800)
 − 0.2624** (0.1070)
0.6161*** (0.1248)
Prime rate
 − 0.0069 (0.0325)
 − 0.0633 (0.0562)
0.1531 (0.2050)
0.1612** (0.0660)
 − 0.0059 (0.0321)
0.0035 (0.0425)
 − 0.0800** (0.037)
 − 0.0361 (0.0534)
0.0954 (0.2094)
0.5721** (0.2480)
0.1596*** (0.0614)
0.0186 (0.0844)
Loan amount
0.1052*** (0.0129)
0.1726*** (0.0276)
0.2954*** (0.0490)
0.1462*** (0.0350)
0.1335*** (0.0141)
 − 0.1060*** (0.0170)
0.1277*** (0.0192)
 − 0.1103*** (0.0246)
0.3129*** (0.0497)
 − 0.0662 (0.0586)
0.0925*** (0.0236)
 − 0.0980*** (0.0289)
Female
0.0944** (0.0463)
0.1511* (0.0869)
0.3266** (0.1460)
0.1360 (0.0944)
0.0824* (0.0473)
0.0303 (0.0649)
0.0667 (0.0668)
 − 0.0700 (0.0999)
0.2668* (0.1518)
0.2101 (0.2533)
0.0929 (0.0757)
0.0489 (0.1032)
Below degree
 − 0.0496** (0.0203)
 − 0.0824** (0.0357)
 − 0.2483** (0.1147)
 − 0.1199* (0.0722)
 − 0.0401** (0.0182)
0.2362*** (0.0547)
 − 0.0746*** (0.0275)
0.2037** (0.0830)
 − 0.2013** (0.1017)
0.1515 (0.1871)
 − 0.1487** (0.0758)
0.3842*** (0.0886)
Owner’s age
 − 0.1887** (0.0951)
 − 0.5519*** (0.1780)
 − 0.0077 (0.3394)
 − 0.0915 (0.2304)
 − 0.2421** (0.0967)
0.2757** (0.1302)
 − 0.2415* (0.1307)
0.3261* (0.1926)
 − 0.0227 (0.3455)
0.2200 (0.4288)
 − 0.2942* (0.1673)
0.3657 (0.2227)
Other firm-aspect characteristics
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
U.S. region dummies
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
SIC division dummies
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Year dummies
Yes
N/A
N/A
N/A
Yes
YES
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
Constant
3.0403*** (0.4391)
4.2952*** (0.8758)
 − 0.7582 (1.9226)
1.6736* (0.9820)
2.5007*** (0.4572)
 − 1.3441** (0.6485)
3.3689*** (0.6024)
 − 1.6740* (0.9657)
 − 0.8920 (2.0351)
 − 6.8568** (2.7407)
2.3217*** (0.7526)
 − 2.2396** (1.0839)
Inverse Mills ratio
    
 − 0.4924*** (0.1002)
 
 − 0.3159*** (0.1365)
 
 − 0.6314** (0.2715)
 
 − 0.5660*** (0.1564)
 
Observations
3132
1497
463
1172
3132
1497
463
1172
Wald test of endogeneity (χ2)
    
24.14***
5.35**
5.41**
13.10**
This table presents the regressions results of the maturity of the firm’s most recently approved loan (dependent variable) on in-person and other control variables. Models 1 to 4 report the OLS regression estimates and Models 5 to 8 report the estimates from the treatment effects (TE) regressions. To correct for nonresponse and disproportionate sampling, the SSBF-provided weights are applied in each survey round. The robust standard errors are presented in parentheses. All variables are defined in Table 2 and have variance inflation factors (VIFs) substantially lower than 5. ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively
If firms most severely plagued by information opacity are able to attain lower interest rates by face-to-face communication, we also expect a favorable effect on loan maturity. We, therefore, interact in-person with both start-up and below degree to gauge whether a more level informational playing field can further prolong maturity. Table 12 reports the 2nd-stage regression results of our instrumental variables estimation. Confirming our predictions, the results in Models 1–4 indicate that the maturity for start-up firms is shorter, however, it can be substantially extended by in-person communication. Models 5–8 convey similar insight based on owners’ education. Owners lacking a university degree are generally granted a shorter maturity, with credit becoming available for a longer period of time should they choose to address the branch people face-to-face. Combined with our evidence on borrowing cost, we see face-to-face communication influencing two important loan contracting terms8 in a direction which creates value for the small firm; the higher the information asymmetry with the primary financial institution, the greater the value-added.
Table 12
In-person banking and maturity of loans under heightened information asymmetry
 
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Pooled data
1993 NSSBF
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
Model 4
Model 5
Model 6
Model 7
Model 8
In-person
0.1502*** (0.0425)
0.1708** (0.0801)
0.2197** (0.0950)
0.2793** (0.1200)
0.1369*** (0.0526)
0.1685** (0.0838)
0.2518*** (0.0875)
0.2851** (0.1281)
In-person × startup
0.1172** (0.0582)
0.1698** (0.0821)
0.2281** (0.1081)
0.2392** (0.1213)
    
In-person × below degree
    
0.0491** (0.0212)
0.0566** (0.0278)
0.1379** (0.0698)
0.1839** (0.0891)
Startup
 − 0.1705*** (0.0606)
 − 0.1813** (0.0919)
 − 0.2320** (0.1101)
 − 0.3033** (0.1521)
 − 0.0976** (0.0472)
 − 0.2097*** (0.0751)
 − 0.2574** (0.1087)
 − 0.2791** (0.1320)
Below degree
 − 0.0494*** (0.0181)
 − 0.0807** (0.0391)
 − 0.2478** (0.1156)
 − 0.1379** (0.0702)
 − 0.0559*** (0.0165)
 − 0.0792** (0.0352)
 − 0.1595** (0.0637)
 − 0.1933** (0.0808)
Control variables
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
U.S. region dummies
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
SIC division dummies
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Year dummies
Yes
N/A
N/A
N/A
Yes
N/A
N/A
N/A
Observations
3132
1497
463
1172
3132
1497
463
1172
Endogeneity test (LM statistic χ2)
8.31***
7.17***
4.34**
9.25***
9.32***
5.10**
7.29***
8.17***
This table presents the regression results of the maturity of the firm’s most recently approved loan (dependent variable) on in-person and its interaction with variables associated with heightened information asymmetry. Models 1 to 4 use the interaction term in-person × startup and Models 5 to 8 use the interaction term in-person × below degree. All regressions are based on instrumental variables (IV) estimation and employ the same set of control variables used in Table 11 regressions; in the interest of space, the resulting coefficients on these variables and the 1st-stage regression results are suppressed but remain available upon request. To correct for nonresponse and disproportionate sampling, the SSBF-provided weights are applied in each survey round. The robust standard errors are presented in parentheses. All variables are defined in Table 2 and have variance inflation factors (VIFs) substantially lower than 5. ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively

5.2.3 In-person contact and discouraged borrowing

A dark side of in-person contact might be that it undermines objectivity in the lending decision as, for example, by being conducive to bonding or manipulation. In such a case, our previous findings on the strength of banking relationships and advantageous contractual terms attained by in-person communicators, could substantiate a market friction whereby banks are incapable of properly filtering the available supply of soft information. In this respect, we test our final hypothesis in the paper about the differential effect of in-person contact on Kon and Storey’s (2003) concept of discouraged borrowing based on borrowers’ quality. Conceivably, evidence showing less discouragement among good quality borrowers with no such effect on bad quality borrowers would be pivotal in ruling out this alternative interpretation of our results.
We assemble the discoursed borrowing sample in a twofold process. First, we scrutinize our baseline sample for firms which refrained from submitting a loan application when they were actually in need of bank credit. As we find, out of 3604 firms that identified themselves as capital seekers (i.e. pursued financing within the 3-year period preceding the survey), 853 conceded self-rationing due to fear of rejection.9 We flag such cases with the dummy variable discouragement. Second, we follow Han et al. (2009) and factor in differences in prospective borrowers’ quality as captured by Dun and Bradstreet’s credit scores. Specifically, we classify10 capital seekers into two (good and bad quality) types of borrowers and draw separate evidence from each subsample. Intuition and some empirical evidence (Ferrando and Mulier 2014; Bhaird et al. 2016) suggest that discouraged borrowers are usually of higher operating risk, attaching a non-random component to the phenomenon. To account for possible selection bias, we supplement probit estimation with an RBP model where the first-stage instrument, consistent with previous analyses, is the exogenous variable in-person environment.
The regression estimates provide empirical validation to our subsampling approach. In Table 13, good borrowers display: (1) a negative coefficient on in-person which is statistically significant at 5% level (RBP model); and (2) strong evidence of endogeneity with both the Fisher’s z transformed correlation and the χ2 in the Wald test to attain significance at the 5% level. The effect is economically important with the probability of discouragement to subside by 13.19% (Model 4). Table 14 reports the results obtained from the bad borrowers’ sample. Of note is that both the Fisher’s z transformed correlation and the χ2 in the Wald test suggest the exogeneity of in-person in the RBP models. Consequently, we rely on probit estimation which generates insignificant coefficients on in-person. Based on these results, lower quality firms are shown to lack an apparent incentive to self-select into a certain communication method with the primary bank. Because the effect remains exclusive to good borrowers, i.e. the type of firms which stand to benefit from the leveling of the informational playing field, we infer that the latter function comprises the prime mechanism by which in-person banking influences discouraged borrowing. Han et al. (2009) describe discouragement as an efficient self-rationing process which encourages good borrowers and precludes those of dubious quality. We show that the process can further gain in efficiency from face-to-face communication. More generally, we prove that the positive influence of in-person contact is extensible from the firm-bank system to the economy-wide capital allocation.
Table 13
In-person banking and probability of discouragement among good borrowers
 
Probit
RBP
Pooled data
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Pooled data
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
Model 4
Model 5
Model 6
   
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
In-person
 − 0.1350 (0.1061)
 − 0.0988 (0.2315)
 − 0.1952 (0.1690)
 − 0.4226** (0.2117)
 
 − 0.2701** (0.1253)
 
 − 0.9708** (0.3965)
 
In-person environment
    
2.5588*** (0.3890)
 
2.5824** (1.2807)
 
3.0743*** (0.6831)
Rural area
 − 0.2286** (0.1095)
 − 0.3498* (0.2094)
 − 0.5036*** (0.1680)
 − 0.2133* (0.1112)
0.0392 (0.0889)
 − 0.3367 (0.2132)
0.0673 (0.2547)
 − 0.5548*** (0.1642)
 − 0.0439 (0.1700)
Commercial bank
 − 0.1933 (0.1206)
 − 0.1946 (0.2357)
 − 0.1748 (0.1897)
 − 0.1363 (0.1300)
0.1143 (0.1179)
 − 0.1386 (0.3146)
0.3441 (0.2913)
 − 0.1282 (0.1998)
0.3867** (0.1638)
Female
0.1288 (0.0949)
0.2966 (0.2117)
0.1402 (0.1466)
0.1433 (0.0958)
0.1609* (0.0875)
0.2990 (0.2119)
 − 0.0095 (0.2459)
0.1410 (0.1414)
0.0541 (0.1339)
Below degree
0.3827*** (0.0975)
0.4924** (0.1947)
0.3727** (0.1530)
0.4074*** (0.1011)
0.4337*** (0.0729)
0.4966** (0.1954)
0.2740 (0.1878)
0.3084** (0.1555)
0.5337*** (0.1316)
Owner’s age
 − 0.2111 (0.2304)
0.5958 (0.4290)
 − 0.7779** (0.3692)
 − 0.1827 (0.2309)
0.4238** (0.1885)
0.6200 (0.4345)
0.5457 (0.4437)
 − 0.5142 (0.3517)
0.9049*** (0.3264)
Other firm-aspect characteristics
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Constant
0.9670 (0.9075)
 − 2.3322 (1.6344)
3.5736** (1.4535)
1.0156 (0.9032)
 − 4.2586*** (0.8391)
 − 2.3240 (1.6389)
 − 4.4795** (2.2102)
2.7549** (1.3353)
 − 5.7521*** (1.4444)
Fisher’s z transformed correlation
   
0.1820** (0.0921)
 
0.1065** (0.0518)
 
0.4862** (0.2459)
 
Observations
1697
403
1294
1706
405
1301
Wald test of endogeneity (χ2)
   
3.8963**
3.8729**
3.9110**
This table presents the regressions results of the incidence of discouraged borrowing (dependent variable) on in-person and other control variables. The analysis is based on the subsample of good borrowers, i.e. firms in need of finance in the three most recent years with a Dun & Bradstreet credit assessment less risky than average. Models 1 to 3 present the probit coefficients and Models 4 to 6 the recursive bivariate probit (RBP) regression results. All regressions include SIC division and U.S. region dummies, Models 1 and 4 also include year fixed effects. The SSBF-provided weights are applied to correct for nonresponse and disproportionate sampling. The robust standard errors are in parentheses. All variables are defined in Table 2 and have VIFs substantially lower than 5. ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively
Table 14
In-person banking and probability of discouragement among bad borrowers
 
Probit
RBP
Pooled data
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Pooled data
1998 SSBF
2003 SSBF
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
Model 4
Model 5
Model 6
   
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
2nd Stage
1st Stage
In-person
0.0221 (0.0822)
0.1009 (0.1298)
0.0559 (0.1560)
0.3235 (1.7975)
 
1.5646*** (0.2251)
 
1.2861*** (0.4133)
 
In-person environment
    
2.1317*** (0.5094)
 
2.7342*** (0.7934)
 
2.5556** (1.0854)
Rural area
 − 0.2225*** (0.0833)
 − 0.2868** (0.1262)
 − 0.3108* (0.1707)
 − 0.2386* (0.1232)
0.1494 (0.0957)
 − 0.3293*** (0.1172)
0.2061 (0.1528)
 − 0.3615** (0.1533)
0.2287 (0.1794)
Commercial bank
0.0228 (0.0898)
0.0779 (0.1367)
0.0877 (0.1710)
 − 0.0519 (0.4558)
0.7836*** (0.0868)
 − 0.3801** (0.1520)
0.8681*** (0.1372)
 − 0.2476 (0.2145)
0.7464*** (0.1654)
Female
0.1319* (0.0725)
0.1047 (0.1121)
0.4126*** (0.1354)
0.1247 (0.0860)
0.0460 (0.0793)
 − 0.0049 (0.1083)
0.2295* (0.1266)
0.3403** (0.1451)
 − 0.0257 (0.1491)
Below degree
0.0104 (0.0699)
 − 0.0205 (0.1046)
0.0163 (0.1437)
 − 0.0060 (0.1187)
0.1976*** (0.0718)
 − 0.0873 (0.0966)
0.1965* (0.1149)
 − 0.0023 (0.1325)
0.0103 (0.1413)
Owner’s age
0.1993 (0.1537)
0.7563*** (0.2316)
 − 0.5977** (0.2725)
0.2141 (0.1722)
 − 0.1063 (0.1688)
0.7741*** (0.2108)
 − 0.1679 (0.2611)
 − 0.6396** (0.2550)
0.5021 (0.3185)
Other firm-aspect characteristics
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Constant
 − 0.6248 (0.6225)
 − 2.5498*** (0.9230)
2.3840** (1.1093)
 − 0.8590 (1.5038)
 − 1.0951 (0.7844)
 − 3.4692*** (0.8587)
 − 1.6536 (1.2035)
1.8425* (1.0546)
 − 3.5957** (1.4850)
Fisher’s z transformed correlation
   
 − 0.1801 (1.0969)
 
 − 1.5366 (1.0001)
 
 − 0.9933 (0.6381)
 
Observations
1814
997
815
1814
997
817
Wald test of endogeneity (χ2)
   
0.0270
2.3575
2.4233
This table presents the regressions results of the incidence of discouraged borrowing (dependent variable) on in-person and other control variables. The analysis is based on the subsample of bad borrowers, i.e. firms in need of finance in the three most recent years with a Dun & Bradstreet credit assessment more risky than average. Models 1 to 3 present the probit coefficients and Models 4 to 6 the recursive bivariate probit (RBP) regression results. All regressions include SIC division and U.S. region dummies, Models 1 and 4 also include year fixed effects. The SSBF-provided weights are applied to correct for nonresponse and disproportionate sampling. The robust standard errors feature in parentheses. All variables are defined in Table 2 and have VIFs substantially lower than 5. ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively

6 Summary and concluding remarks

Relationship banking is distinguished by the capacity to operationalize soft information—an impossibility under alternative banking technologies. This capacity is valuable to the extent that soft information adds efficiency to financial processes and, indeed, theory suggests that it does. Absent is, however, the empirical evidence that could put the postulated benefits in perspective, with the extant studies tracing relationship banking effects at an aggregate level only. Addressing this void, our study offers a rigorous analysis of the mechanism that actually generates soft information, in-person communication.
Using data from the Federal Reserve’s 1993, 1998 and 2003 Survey of Small Business Finances, we first develop the profile of firms opting for face-to-face interactions with their main bank. This is compatible with informationally opaque organizations and firms operating in rural areas. We also find that small business owners are more likely to visit the bank premises if they are female, older, and less educated. Next, we direct our attention to the implications of in-person communication and document incremental value for both ends of the bank-firm relationship. From the small business perspective, borrowing becomes cheaper and available for a longer period of time, reducing the likelihood of self-imposed rationing among firms of good quality. From the bank perspective, not only client loyalty increases but also firms tend to purchase a wider range of financial services. In light of this evidence, we caution that technological automation in the banking industry should aim to supplement, not obviate, interpersonal communication.
Future research, among other possible directions, can blend our findings with those of previous studies to develop a more symmetrical understanding of soft information production: if loan officers and branch managers impact differently on the recipient end of the process (Berger and Udell 2002; Uchida et al. 2012; Hattori et al. 2015), it is likely that heterogeneity also resides on the transmitting end. Conditional on data availability, it would be interesting to compare the effects of soft information generated by different stakeholders communicating on the firm’s behalf (e.g. owner and family, employees, business partners, members of the local community).

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to Ross Brown, Santiago Carbó-Valverde, Jean Chen, Arman Eshraghi, Linh Nguyen, George Saridakis, Elias Tzavalis, John Wilson, and Rafal Wojakowski for their helpful comments and suggestions.

Declarations

Conflict of interest

No potential conflict of interest was declared by the authors.
Open AccessThis article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Anhänge

Appendix 1: Regression with treatment effects (TE)

The length of the banking relationship (relationship length) can be expressed as follows:
$$relationship\;length_{i} = \alpha + \beta X_{i} + \gamma \;in{\text{-}}person_{i} + \varepsilon_{i}$$
(3)
where X represents a vector of banking market and firm-specific characteristics; in-person is a dichotomous variable; and ε stands for the residual term, ε ~ [0, σ2]. In-personi itself is determined by a set of variables Zi which comprise the instrumental variable (in-person environment) and the Xi vector. We further assume that there is a continuous variable in-person*i, where:
$$in{\text{-}}person_{i}^{*} = \omega \;Z_{i} + \xi_{i}$$
(4)
and ξ ~ [0, 1].
So that in-personi = \(\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {1,} \hfill & {if\;in{\text{-}}person_{i}^{*} > 0 } \hfill \\ {0,} \hfill & {if\;in{\text{-}}person_{i}^{*} \le 0} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right..\)
Heckman (1979) suggests that the selection bias in OLS estimates may be rectified with the inclusion of the inverse Mills ratio through the 2-stage procedure described below:
$$\begin{aligned} E\left( {relationship\;length} \right)|in{\text{-}}person = 1) & = \alpha + X + \gamma + E\left( {\varepsilon |in{\text{-}}person = 1} \right) \\ & = \alpha + \beta^{\prime } \;X + \gamma + \rho \sigma_{\varepsilon } \frac{{\varphi \left( { - \omega Z^{\prime } } \right)}}{{1 - \Phi \left( { - \omega Z^{\prime } } \right)}} \\ & = \alpha + \beta^{\prime } \;X + \gamma + \rho \sigma_{\varepsilon } \frac{{\varphi \left( {\omega Z^{\prime } } \right)}}{{\Phi \left( {\omega Z^{\prime } } \right)}}. \\ \end{aligned}$$
(5)
Similarly,
$$\begin{aligned} E\left( {relationship\;length} \right)|in{\text{-}}person = 0) & = \alpha + \beta^{\prime } \;X + \gamma + E\left( {\varepsilon |in{\text{-}}person = 0} \right) \\ & = \upalpha + \beta^{\prime } \;{\text{X}} + {\uprho \sigma }_{\varepsilon } \frac{{ - \varphi \left( { - {\upomega {\rm Z}}^{\prime } } \right)}}{{\Phi \left( { - {\upomega {\rm Z}}^{\prime } } \right)}} \\ & = \upalpha + \beta^{\prime } \;{\text{X}} + {\uprho \sigma }_{\varepsilon } \frac{{ - \varphi \left( { - {\upomega {\rm Z}}^{\prime } } \right)}}{{1 - \Phi \left( { - {\upomega {\rm Z}}^{\prime } } \right)}}. \\ \end{aligned}$$
(6)
Subtracting Eq. (6) from Eq. (5), the treatment effects (TE) are:
$$\begin{aligned} TE & = E\left( {relationship\;length} \right)\left| {in{\text{-}}person = 1) - E\left( {relationship\;length} \right)} \right|in{\text{-}}person = 0) \\ & = \gamma + \rho \sigma_{\varepsilon } \frac{{\varphi \left( {\omega Z^{\prime } } \right)}}{{\Phi \left( {\omega Z^{\prime } } \right)\left( {1 - \Phi \left( {\omega Z^{\prime } } \right)} \right)}} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(7)
where φ denotes the standard normal density function and Φ the standard normal cumulative distribution function. Thus, including the inverse Mills ratio (λ) into Eqs. (3) and (4), with λ = \(\frac{{\varphi \left( {{\upomega {\rm Z}}^{\prime } } \right)}}{{\Phi \left( {{\upomega {\rm Z}}^{\prime } } \right)}}\) if in-person = 1 and λ = \(\frac{{ - \varphi \left( {{\upomega {\rm Z}}^{\prime } } \right)}}{{1 - \Phi \left( {{\upomega {\rm Z}}^{\prime } } \right)}}\) if in-person = 0, the resulting coefficients become least affected by selection bias (Greene 2012; Gounopoulos et al. 2017).

Appendix 2: Recursive bivariate probit (RBP) regression

We use the recursive bivariate probit (RBP) method to estimate the regression on the exclusivity of banking relationships. In accord with the binary nature of the dependent variable, we specify the following equation:
$$Probit\;(exclusivity_{i} ) = \alpha + \beta X_{i} + \omega \;in{\text{-}}person_{i} + u_{i}$$
(8)
where X represents a vector of banking market and firm-specific characteristics; in-person is a dichotomous variable; and u stands for the residual term, u ~ [0, σ2]. Let \(exclusivity_{i}^{*}\) represent a latent continuous variable as follows:
$$\begin{aligned} & exclusivity_{i} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {1,} \hfill & {if\;exclusivity_{i}^{*} > 0 } \hfill \\ {0,} \hfill & {if\;exclusivity_{i}^{*} \le 0} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. \\ & {\text{where}}\;exclusivity_{i}^{*} = \beta^{\prime } X_{i} + \omega^{\prime } \;in{\text{-}}person + u_{i}^{\prime } . \\ \end{aligned}$$
(9)
In addition, we specify the in-personi equation as:
$$Probit\;(in{\text{-}}person_{i} ) =\uptau + \gamma Z_{i} + \varepsilon_{i}$$
(10)
where Z includes the X vector of Eq. (8) and the instrumental variable (in-person environment).
We further assume a latent continuous variable \(in{\text{-}}person_{i}^{*}\) as follows:
$$in{\text{-}}person_{i} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {1,} \hfill & {if\;in{\text{-}}person_{i}^{*} > 0 } \hfill \\ {0,} \hfill & {if\;in{\text{-}}person_{i}^{*} \le 0} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.,{\text{where}}\;in{\text{-}}person_{i}^{*} = \gamma^{\prime } Z_{i} + \varepsilon_{i}^{\prime } .$$
(11)
Jointly, the error terms of Eqs. (9) and (11) can be expressed as: \(\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\varepsilon^{\prime } } \\ {u^{\prime } } \\ \end{array} |Z, X} \right)\) ~ N \(\left[ {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} 0 \\ 0 \\ \end{array} } \right)\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} 1 \\ \rho \\ \end{array} \begin{array}{*{20}c} \rho \\ 1 \\ \end{array} } \right)} \right]\). Using F(·,·)11 to denote the joint distribution function of (\(u^{\prime }\), \(\varepsilon^{\prime }\)) and assuming symmetric distributions for the error terms of Eqs. (9) and (11), the expected probability distribution is given below:
$$\begin{aligned} P_{11} & = Prob\left( {exclusivity = 1,\;in{\text{-}}person = 1} \right) = F\left( {\beta^{\prime } X + \omega^{\prime } ,\gamma^{\prime } Z,\rho } \right) \\ P_{10} & = Prob\left( {exclusivity = 1,\;in{\text{-}}person = 0} \right) = F\left( {\beta^{\prime } X,\gamma^{\prime } Z, - \rho } \right) \\ P_{01} & = Prob\left( {exclusivity = 0,\;in{\text{-}}person = 1} \right) = F\left( { - \beta^{\prime } X - \omega^{\prime } ,\gamma^{\prime } Z, - \rho } \right) \\ P_{00} & = Prob\left( {exclusivity = 0,\;in{\text{-}}person = 0} \right) = F\left( { - \beta^{\prime } X, - \gamma^{\prime } Z,\rho } \right). \\ \end{aligned}$$
(12)
Accordingly, the likelihood function to be maximized is:
$$L\left( {\omega ,\gamma ,\beta } \right) = \prod \left( {P_{11}^{{exclusivity*in{\text{-}}person}} P_{10}^{{exclusivity*\left( {1 - in{\text{-}}person} \right)}} P_{01}^{{\left( {1 - {\text{exclusivity}}} \right){\text{*in - person}}}} P_{00}^{{\left( {1 - {\text{exclusivity}}} \right){*}\left( {1 - {\text{in - person}}} \right)}} } \right)$$
(13)
Hence, by maximizing the loglikelihood function, least biased estimates are attainable (Maddala 1983, pp. 122–124; Greene 2012, pp 778–789).
Fußnoten
1
The relationship with the primary financial institution, being less transaction-oriented and conducive to private information acquisition, serves as a focal point for much of the empirical work in relationship banking (e.g. Berger and Udell 1998; Berger et al. 2001; Ono et al. 2014).
 
2
The International Data Corporation (IDC) estimates the aggregate investment of U.S. retail banks in information technology at $20.2 billion in 2017, forecasting an increase at an annual growth rate of about 10.5% into 2019.
 
3
Hart and Oulton come up with an interesting rule of thumb whereby the probability of corporate death declines by 5% for every doubling in size until the firm attains a critical threshold of 1000 employees.
 
4
The lender-firm, as opposed to the bank-firm, method of communication features as a covariate in Petersen and Rajan (2002), where lenders indiscriminately include relationship-oriented primary lenders and transaction-oriented non-primary lenders.
 
6
0.10% = \(\frac{{5.30{\text{\% }}}}{1 + 51.00}\), where 51.00 is the median value of owner’s age.
 
7
This represents the marginal borrowing cost, following Wu and Chua (2012).
 
8
Loan covenants could yield additional insight, unfortunately the survey questions exclude this feature.
 
9
Both numbers are based on the 1998 and 2003 survey rounds, the only rounds for which Dun and Bradstreet’s credit score data is available.
 
10
In SSBF 1998, the score ranges from 1 (lowest risk) to 5 (highest risk) with a mean value of 2.99. We define as good (bad) borrowers the finance seekers below (above) this average. In SSBF 2003, the score ranges from 1 (highest risk) to 6 (lowest risk) with an average of 3.61. We define as good (bad) borrowers the finance seekers with a credit score above (below) this average.
 
11
Here, F(Z, X, ρ) = \(\frac{{e^{{ - 0.5*\sqrt {\frac{{Z^{2} + X^{2} - 2\uprho ZX}}{{1 -\uprho ^{2} }}} }} }}{{2\pi \sqrt {1 -\uprho ^{2} } }}.\)
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Ang JS (1991) Small business uniqueness and the theory of financial management. J Small Bus 1:1–13 Ang JS (1991) Small business uniqueness and the theory of financial management. J Small Bus 1:1–13
Zurück zum Zitat Angelini P, Generale A (2008) On the evolution of firm size distributions. Am Econ Rev 98:426–438CrossRef Angelini P, Generale A (2008) On the evolution of firm size distributions. Am Econ Rev 98:426–438CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Baptista G, Oliveira T (2015) Understanding mobile banking: the unified theory of acceptance and use of technology combined with cultural moderators. Comput Hum Behav 50:418–430CrossRef Baptista G, Oliveira T (2015) Understanding mobile banking: the unified theory of acceptance and use of technology combined with cultural moderators. Comput Hum Behav 50:418–430CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barker VL III, Mueller GC (2002) CEO characteristics and firm R&D spending. Manag Sci 48:782–801CrossRef Barker VL III, Mueller GC (2002) CEO characteristics and firm R&D spending. Manag Sci 48:782–801CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bates T (2005) Analysis of young, small firms that have closed: delineating successful from unsuccessful closures. J Bus Ventur 20:343–358CrossRef Bates T (2005) Analysis of young, small firms that have closed: delineating successful from unsuccessful closures. J Bus Ventur 20:343–358CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Beck T, Degryse H, De Haas R, Van Horen N (2018) When arm’s length is too far: Relationship banking over the credit cycle. J Financ Econ 127:174–196CrossRef Beck T, Degryse H, De Haas R, Van Horen N (2018) When arm’s length is too far: Relationship banking over the credit cycle. J Financ Econ 127:174–196CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berger AN, Frame WS (2007) Small business credit scoring and credit availability. J Small Bus Manag 45:5–22CrossRef Berger AN, Frame WS (2007) Small business credit scoring and credit availability. J Small Bus Manag 45:5–22CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berger AN, Udell GF (1995) Relationship lending and lines of credit in small firm finance. J Bus 68:351–381CrossRef Berger AN, Udell GF (1995) Relationship lending and lines of credit in small firm finance. J Bus 68:351–381CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berger AN, Udell GF (1998) The economics of small business finance: the roles of private equity and debt markets in the financial growth cycle. J Bank Finance 22:613–673CrossRef Berger AN, Udell GF (1998) The economics of small business finance: the roles of private equity and debt markets in the financial growth cycle. J Bank Finance 22:613–673CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berger AN, Udell GF (2002) Small business credit availability and relationship lending: the importance of bank organisational structure. Econ J 112:F32–F53CrossRef Berger AN, Udell GF (2002) Small business credit availability and relationship lending: the importance of bank organisational structure. Econ J 112:F32–F53CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berger AN, Udell GF (2006) A more complete conceptual framework for SME finance. J Bank Finance 30:2945–2966CrossRef Berger AN, Udell GF (2006) A more complete conceptual framework for SME finance. J Bank Finance 30:2945–2966CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berger AN, Klapper LF, Udell GF (2001) The ability of banks to lend to informationally opaque small businesses. J Bank Finance 25:2127–2167CrossRef Berger AN, Klapper LF, Udell GF (2001) The ability of banks to lend to informationally opaque small businesses. J Bank Finance 25:2127–2167CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berger AN, Miller NH, Petersen MA, Rajan RG, Stein JC (2005) Does function follow organizational form? Evidence from the lending practices of large and small banks. J Financ Econ 76:237–269CrossRef Berger AN, Miller NH, Petersen MA, Rajan RG, Stein JC (2005) Does function follow organizational form? Evidence from the lending practices of large and small banks. J Financ Econ 76:237–269CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berger AN, Klapper LF, Martinez Peria MS, Zaidi R (2008) Bank ownership type and banking relationships. J Financ Intermed 17:37–62CrossRef Berger AN, Klapper LF, Martinez Peria MS, Zaidi R (2008) Bank ownership type and banking relationships. J Financ Intermed 17:37–62CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berger AN, Cerqueiro G, Penas MF (2011) Does debtor protection really protect debtors? Evidence from the small business credit market. J Bank Finance 35:1843–1857CrossRef Berger AN, Cerqueiro G, Penas MF (2011) Does debtor protection really protect debtors? Evidence from the small business credit market. J Bank Finance 35:1843–1857CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berger AN, Goulding W, Rice T (2014) Do small businesses still prefer community banks? J Bank Finance 44:264–278CrossRef Berger AN, Goulding W, Rice T (2014) Do small businesses still prefer community banks? J Bank Finance 44:264–278CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bertomeu J, Marinovic I (2016) A theory of hard and soft information. Account Rev 91:1–20CrossRef Bertomeu J, Marinovic I (2016) A theory of hard and soft information. Account Rev 91:1–20CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bhaird CM, Vidal JS, Lucey B (2016) Discouraged borrowers: evidence for Eurozone SME’s. J Int Finans Mark Inst Money 44:46–55CrossRef Bhaird CM, Vidal JS, Lucey B (2016) Discouraged borrowers: evidence for Eurozone SME’s. J Int Finans Mark Inst Money 44:46–55CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bharath ST, Dahiya S, Saunders A, Srinivasan A (2011) Lending relationships and loan contract terms. Rev Financ Stud 24:1141–1203CrossRef Bharath ST, Dahiya S, Saunders A, Srinivasan A (2011) Lending relationships and loan contract terms. Rev Financ Stud 24:1141–1203CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Boot AWA (2000) Relationship banking: What do we know? J Financ Intermed 9:7–25CrossRef Boot AWA (2000) Relationship banking: What do we know? J Financ Intermed 9:7–25CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Boot AWA, Thakor AV (2000) Can relationship banking survive competition? J Financ 55:679–713CrossRef Boot AWA, Thakor AV (2000) Can relationship banking survive competition? J Financ 55:679–713CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cassar G, Ittner CD, Cavalluzzo KS (2015) Alternative information sources and information asymmetry reduction: evidence from small business debt. J Account Econ 59:242–263CrossRef Cassar G, Ittner CD, Cavalluzzo KS (2015) Alternative information sources and information asymmetry reduction: evidence from small business debt. J Account Econ 59:242–263CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Casson M, Giusta MD (2007) Entrepreneurship and social Capital. Analysing the impact of social networks on entrepreneurial activity from a rational action perspective. Int Small Bus J 25:220–244CrossRef Casson M, Giusta MD (2007) Entrepreneurship and social Capital. Analysing the impact of social networks on entrepreneurial activity from a rational action perspective. Int Small Bus J 25:220–244CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Castelli A, Dwyer GP, Hasan I (2012) Bank relationships and firms’ financial performance: the Italian experience. Eur Financ Manag 18:28–67CrossRef Castelli A, Dwyer GP, Hasan I (2012) Bank relationships and firms’ financial performance: the Italian experience. Eur Financ Manag 18:28–67CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chai S, Das S, Rao HR (2011) Factors affecting bloggers’ knowledge sharing: an investigation across gender. J Manag Inf Syst 28:309–342CrossRef Chai S, Das S, Rao HR (2011) Factors affecting bloggers’ knowledge sharing: an investigation across gender. J Manag Inf Syst 28:309–342CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chakravarty S, Xiang M (2013) The international evidence on discouraged small businesses. J Empir Financ 20:63–82CrossRef Chakravarty S, Xiang M (2013) The international evidence on discouraged small businesses. J Empir Financ 20:63–82CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cole R, Sokolyk T (2016) Who needs credit and who gets credit? Evidence from the surveys of small business finances. J Financ Stab 24:40–60CrossRef Cole R, Sokolyk T (2016) Who needs credit and who gets credit? Evidence from the surveys of small business finances. J Financ Stab 24:40–60CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cole RA, Goldberg LG, White LJ (2004) Cookie cutter vs. character: the micro structure of small business lending by large and small banks. J Financ Quant Anal 39:227–251CrossRef Cole RA, Goldberg LG, White LJ (2004) Cookie cutter vs. character: the micro structure of small business lending by large and small banks. J Financ Quant Anal 39:227–251CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dai N, Ivanov V, Cole RA (2017) Entrepreneurial optimism, credit availability, and cost of financing: evidence from U.S. small businesses. J Corp Finance 44:289–307CrossRef Dai N, Ivanov V, Cole RA (2017) Entrepreneurial optimism, credit availability, and cost of financing: evidence from U.S. small businesses. J Corp Finance 44:289–307CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Datta S, Iskandar-Datta M, Patel A (1999) Bank monitoring and the pricing of corporate public debt. J Financ Econ 51:435–449CrossRef Datta S, Iskandar-Datta M, Patel A (1999) Bank monitoring and the pricing of corporate public debt. J Financ Econ 51:435–449CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat D’Aurizio L, Oliviero T, Romano L (2015) Family firms, soft information and bank lending in a financial crisis. J Corp Finance 33:279–292CrossRef D’Aurizio L, Oliviero T, Romano L (2015) Family firms, soft information and bank lending in a financial crisis. J Corp Finance 33:279–292CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Degryse H, van Cayseele PV (2000) Relationship lending within a bank-based system: evidence from European small business data. J Financ Intermed 9:90–109CrossRef Degryse H, van Cayseele PV (2000) Relationship lending within a bank-based system: evidence from European small business data. J Financ Intermed 9:90–109CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat DeYoung R, Glennon D, Nigro P, Spong K (2012) Small business lending and social capital: Are rural relationships different? University of Kansas Center for Banking Excellence Research paper, 1. DeYoung R, Glennon D, Nigro P, Spong K (2012) Small business lending and social capital: Are rural relationships different? University of Kansas Center for Banking Excellence Research paper, 1.
Zurück zum Zitat Durguner S (2017) Do borrower-lender relationships still matter for small business loans? J Int Financ Mark Inst Money 50:98–118CrossRef Durguner S (2017) Do borrower-lender relationships still matter for small business loans? J Int Financ Mark Inst Money 50:98–118CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Elsas R (2005) Empirical determinants of relationship lending. J Financ Intermed 14:32–57CrossRef Elsas R (2005) Empirical determinants of relationship lending. J Financ Intermed 14:32–57CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ferrando A, Mulier K (2014) The real effects of credit constraints: evidence from discouraged borrowers in the Euro area. SSRN Working Paper. SSRN ID: 2518980. Ferrando A, Mulier K (2014) The real effects of credit constraints: evidence from discouraged borrowers in the Euro area. SSRN Working Paper. SSRN ID: 2518980.
Zurück zum Zitat Gabbi G, Giammarino M, Matthias M, Monferrà S, Sampagnaro G (2020) Does face-to-face contact matter? Evidence on loan pricing. Eur J Finance 26:820–836CrossRef Gabbi G, Giammarino M, Matthias M, Monferrà S, Sampagnaro G (2020) Does face-to-face contact matter? Evidence on loan pricing. Eur J Finance 26:820–836CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Greene WH (2012) Econometric Analysis, 7th edn. Pearson Education Limited, Harlow Greene WH (2012) Econometric Analysis, 7th edn. Pearson Education Limited, Harlow
Zurück zum Zitat Gounopoulos D, Kallias A, Kallias K, Tzeremes PG (2017) Political money contributions of U.S. IPOs. J Corp Finance 43:19–38CrossRef Gounopoulos D, Kallias A, Kallias K, Tzeremes PG (2017) Political money contributions of U.S. IPOs. J Corp Finance 43:19–38CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guo S, Fraser MW (2015) Propensity score analysis, 2nd edn. SAGE Publications Inc., Thousand Oaks Guo S, Fraser MW (2015) Propensity score analysis, 2nd edn. SAGE Publications Inc., Thousand Oaks
Zurück zum Zitat Han L, Storey DJ, Fraser S (2008) The concentration of creditors: evidence from small businesses. Appl Financ Econ 18:1647–1656CrossRef Han L, Storey DJ, Fraser S (2008) The concentration of creditors: evidence from small businesses. Appl Financ Econ 18:1647–1656CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Han L, Fraser S, Storey DJ (2009) Are good or bad borrowers discouraged from applying for loans? Evidence from U.S. small business credit markets. J Bank Finance 33:415–424CrossRef Han L, Fraser S, Storey DJ (2009) Are good or bad borrowers discouraged from applying for loans? Evidence from U.S. small business credit markets. J Bank Finance 33:415–424CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Han L, Zhang S, Greene F (2017) Bank market concentration, relationship banking, and small business liquidity. Int Small Bus J 35:365–384CrossRef Han L, Zhang S, Greene F (2017) Bank market concentration, relationship banking, and small business liquidity. Int Small Bus J 35:365–384CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hart PE, Oulton N (1996) Growth and size of firms. Econ J 106:1242–1252CrossRef Hart PE, Oulton N (1996) Growth and size of firms. Econ J 106:1242–1252CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hattori M, Shintani K, Uchida H (2015) The repository of soft information within bank organizations. J Money Credit Bank 47:737–770CrossRef Hattori M, Shintani K, Uchida H (2015) The repository of soft information within bank organizations. J Money Credit Bank 47:737–770CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hauswald R, Marquez R (2006) Competition and strategic information acquisition in credit markets. Rev Financ Stud 19:967–1000CrossRef Hauswald R, Marquez R (2006) Competition and strategic information acquisition in credit markets. Rev Financ Stud 19:967–1000CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Heckman JJ (1979) Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 47:153–161CrossRef Heckman JJ (1979) Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 47:153–161CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hernández-Cánovas G, Martínez-Solano P (2010) Relationship lending and SME financing in the continental European bank-based system. Small Bus Econ 34:465–482CrossRef Hernández-Cánovas G, Martínez-Solano P (2010) Relationship lending and SME financing in the continental European bank-based system. Small Bus Econ 34:465–482CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hernández-Murillo R, Llobet G, Fuentes R (2010) Strategic online banking adoption. J Bank Finance 34:1650–1663CrossRef Hernández-Murillo R, Llobet G, Fuentes R (2010) Strategic online banking adoption. J Bank Finance 34:1650–1663CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hertzberg A, Liberti JM, Paravisini D (2010) Information and incentives inside the firm: evidence from loan officer rotation. J Financ 65:795–828CrossRef Hertzberg A, Liberti JM, Paravisini D (2010) Information and incentives inside the firm: evidence from loan officer rotation. J Financ 65:795–828CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Iturralde T, Maseda A, San-Jose L (2010) Empirical evidence of banking relationships for Spanish SMEs. Int Small Bus J 28:274–295CrossRef Iturralde T, Maseda A, San-Jose L (2010) Empirical evidence of banking relationships for Spanish SMEs. Int Small Bus J 28:274–295CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat King T, Srivastav A, Williams J (2016) What’s in an education? Implications of CEO education for bank performance. J Corp Finance 37:287–308CrossRef King T, Srivastav A, Williams J (2016) What’s in an education? Implications of CEO education for bank performance. J Corp Finance 37:287–308CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kon Y, Storey DJ (2003) A theory of discouraged borrowers. Small Bus Econ 21:37–49CrossRef Kon Y, Storey DJ (2003) A theory of discouraged borrowers. Small Bus Econ 21:37–49CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lang M, Lundholm R (1993) Cross-sectional determinants of analyst ratings of corporate disclosures. J Account Res 31:246–271CrossRef Lang M, Lundholm R (1993) Cross-sectional determinants of analyst ratings of corporate disclosures. J Account Res 31:246–271CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lian Y (2018) Bank competition and the cost of bank loans. Rev Quant Financ Acc 51:253–282CrossRef Lian Y (2018) Bank competition and the cost of bank loans. Rev Quant Financ Acc 51:253–282CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Liberti JM, Petersen MA (2019) Information: hard and soft. Rev Corp Finance Stud 8:1–41CrossRef Liberti JM, Petersen MA (2019) Information: hard and soft. Rev Corp Finance Stud 8:1–41CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Maddala GS (1983) Limited-dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef Maddala GS (1983) Limited-dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Magnac T (2017) ATM foreign fees and cash withdrawals. J Bank Finance 78:117–129CrossRef Magnac T (2017) ATM foreign fees and cash withdrawals. J Bank Finance 78:117–129CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Miller D, Xu X, Mehrotra V (2015) When is human capital a valuable resource? The performance effects of Ivy League selection among celebrated CEOs. Strateg Manag J 36:930–944CrossRef Miller D, Xu X, Mehrotra V (2015) When is human capital a valuable resource? The performance effects of Ivy League selection among celebrated CEOs. Strateg Manag J 36:930–944CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mi B, Han L (2020) Banking market concentration and syndicated loan prices. Rev Quant Financ Acc 54:1–28CrossRef Mi B, Han L (2020) Banking market concentration and syndicated loan prices. Rev Quant Financ Acc 54:1–28CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ono A, Hasumi R, Hirata H (2014) Differentiated use of small business credit scoring by relationship lenders and transactional lenders: evidence from firm–bank matched data in Japan. J Bank Finance 42:371–380CrossRef Ono A, Hasumi R, Hirata H (2014) Differentiated use of small business credit scoring by relationship lenders and transactional lenders: evidence from firm–bank matched data in Japan. J Bank Finance 42:371–380CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ortiz-Molina H, Penas MF (2008) Lending to small businesses: the role of loan maturity in addressing information problems. Small Bus Econ 30:361–383CrossRef Ortiz-Molina H, Penas MF (2008) Lending to small businesses: the role of loan maturity in addressing information problems. Small Bus Econ 30:361–383CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Parker AM, Fischhoff B (2005) Decision-making competence: external validation through an individual-differences approach. J Behav Decis Mak 18:1–27CrossRef Parker AM, Fischhoff B (2005) Decision-making competence: external validation through an individual-differences approach. J Behav Decis Mak 18:1–27CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Petersen MA, Rajan RG (1994) The benefits of lending relationships: evidence from small business data. J Finance 49:3–37CrossRef Petersen MA, Rajan RG (1994) The benefits of lending relationships: evidence from small business data. J Finance 49:3–37CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Petersen MA, Rajan RG (1995) The effect of credit market competition on lending relationships. Q J Econ 110:407–443CrossRef Petersen MA, Rajan RG (1995) The effect of credit market competition on lending relationships. Q J Econ 110:407–443CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Petersen MA, Rajan RG (2002) Does distance still matter? The information revolution in small business lending. J Finance 57:2533–2570CrossRef Petersen MA, Rajan RG (2002) Does distance still matter? The information revolution in small business lending. J Finance 57:2533–2570CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Raymond L (1985) Organizational characteristics and MIS success in the context of small business. MIS Q. 9:37–52CrossRef Raymond L (1985) Organizational characteristics and MIS success in the context of small business. MIS Q. 9:37–52CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rosenfeld CM (2014) The effect of banking relationships on the future of financially distressed firms. J Corp Finance 25:403–418CrossRef Rosenfeld CM (2014) The effect of banking relationships on the future of financially distressed firms. J Corp Finance 25:403–418CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sarapaivanich N, Patterson PG (2015) The role of interpersonal communication in developing small-medium size enterprise (SME) client loyalty toward an audit firm. Int Small Bus J 33:882–900CrossRef Sarapaivanich N, Patterson PG (2015) The role of interpersonal communication in developing small-medium size enterprise (SME) client loyalty toward an audit firm. Int Small Bus J 33:882–900CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schoar A (2012) The personal side of relationship banking. MIT Working Paper Schoar A (2012) The personal side of relationship banking. MIT Working Paper
Zurück zum Zitat Schwert M (2018) Bank capital and lending relationships. J Finance 73:787–830CrossRef Schwert M (2018) Bank capital and lending relationships. J Finance 73:787–830CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shoda Y, Mischel W, Peake PK (1990) Predicting adolescent cognitive and self-regulatory competencies from preschool delay of gratification: identifying diagnostic conditions. Dev Psychol 26:978CrossRef Shoda Y, Mischel W, Peake PK (1990) Predicting adolescent cognitive and self-regulatory competencies from preschool delay of gratification: identifying diagnostic conditions. Dev Psychol 26:978CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stein JC (2002) Information production and capital allocation: decentralized versus hierarchical firms. J Finance 57:1891–1921CrossRef Stein JC (2002) Information production and capital allocation: decentralized versus hierarchical firms. J Finance 57:1891–1921CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stiglitz JE, Weiss A (1981) Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information. Am Econ Rev 71:393–410 Stiglitz JE, Weiss A (1981) Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information. Am Econ Rev 71:393–410
Zurück zum Zitat Tian L, Han L (2019) How local is local? Evidence from bank competition and corporate innovation in US. Rev Quant Finance Acc 52:289–324CrossRef Tian L, Han L (2019) How local is local? Evidence from bank competition and corporate innovation in US. Rev Quant Finance Acc 52:289–324CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Uchida H, Udell GF, Yamori N (2012) Loan officers and relationship lending to SMEs. J Financ Intermed 21:97–122CrossRef Uchida H, Udell GF, Yamori N (2012) Loan officers and relationship lending to SMEs. J Financ Intermed 21:97–122CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Udell GF (2008) What’s in a relationship? The case of commercial lending. Bus Horiz 51:93–103CrossRef Udell GF (2008) What’s in a relationship? The case of commercial lending. Bus Horiz 51:93–103CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Venkatesh V, Morris MG (2000) Why don’t men ever stop to ask for directions? Gender, social influence, and their role in technology acceptance and usage behavior. MIS Q 24:115–139CrossRef Venkatesh V, Morris MG (2000) Why don’t men ever stop to ask for directions? Gender, social influence, and their role in technology acceptance and usage behavior. MIS Q 24:115–139CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wagner J (2001) A note on the firm size–export relationship. Small Bus Econ 17:229–237CrossRef Wagner J (2001) A note on the firm size–export relationship. Small Bus Econ 17:229–237CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wu Z, Chua JH (2012) Second-order gender effects: the case of U.S. small business borrowing cost. Entrep Theory Pract 36:443–463CrossRef Wu Z, Chua JH (2012) Second-order gender effects: the case of U.S. small business borrowing cost. Entrep Theory Pract 36:443–463CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Yu HC, Sopranzetti BJ, Lee CF (2015) The impact of banking relationships, managerial incentives, and board monitoring on corporate cash holdings: an emerging market perspective. Rev Quant Finance Acc 44:353–378CrossRef Yu HC, Sopranzetti BJ, Lee CF (2015) The impact of banking relationships, managerial incentives, and board monitoring on corporate cash holdings: an emerging market perspective. Rev Quant Finance Acc 44:353–378CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
The value of in-person banking: evidence from U.S. small businesses
verfasst von
Song Zhang
Liang Han
Konstantinos Kallias
Antonios Kallias
Publikationsdatum
27.04.2021
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting / Ausgabe 4/2021
Print ISSN: 0924-865X
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7179
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-021-00982-5

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 4/2021

Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 4/2021 Zur Ausgabe