Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 3-4/2021

29.10.2020

Trade or raid: Acadian settlers and native Americans before 1755

verfasst von: Rosolino A. Candela, Vincent J. Geloso

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 3-4/2021

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Could North America have been settled more peacefully, with fewer property rights violations against Native Americans? To answer this question, we utilize the case of French colonists of Atlantic Canada (the Acadians) and a Native American tribe (the Mi’kmaq) between the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries in the areas around the Bay of Fundy in the modern provinces of Nova Scotia and New Brunswick. Under a relative state of anarchy, both the Acadians and the Mi’kmaq were able to minimize the relative returns to using violence by adopting rules of collective decision-making that favored consensus-building. By prioritizing consensus, distributional coalitions were faced with higher decision-making costs, making it difficult for concentrated interest groups within each society to capture the gains from fighting and spilling them over as external costs over the rest of the population. As a result, both the Acadians and the Mi’kmaq were able to reap the benefits of productive specialization and social cooperation under the division of labor.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
Similar to the United States, relations between Native Americans and settlers in Canada, which had worsened gradually and mildly between 1776 and 1867 (Surtess 1988), deteriorated rapidly after independence in 1867. Akin to the American colonial era, Native American policy for colonial Canada was mostly managed from the British capital, as it was the British who would shoulder the burden of conflict through sending troops. After American independence in 1776, the British were even keener on avoiding conflicts between Native Americans and Canadian settlers as they needed the Native Americans to supplement their own troops on the Canadian frontier (see Allen 1996). In terms of violence, the Handbook of North American Indians (Vol.4 on relations between settlers and natives, and Vol. 13 on Plains tribes) makes it clear that conflicts in Canada prior to 1867 were fewer and less intense than in the United States during the same period. Only after Canada became a country did violence increase. These differences between Canada and the United States from 1776 to 1867 suggest the possibility that in the presence of an involved and capable state, management by a colonial power imposes some restraints on the ability to raid. However, we leave this topic for future research.
 
2
The plural of Mi’kmaw is Mi’kmaq. Most of the literature uses these terms, although older historians and anthropologists used the Micmac/Micmacs convention for writing.
 
3
This is similar to the case of Medieval Iceland studied by Friedman (1979) and Solvason (1993). While the label of pure statelessness did not strictly apply, the state was weak enough that one could argue it was a close approximation. Acadia seems to have been a similar close approximation of statelessness.
 
4
Few papers in that literature have attempted to measure the outcomes from anarchy. They tend to concentrate on the conditions that made statelessness an equilibrium. There are exceptions however. For example, Friedman (1979) uses a limited quantity of information to document living standards. Geloso and expand. Another exception concerns the case of Somalia (Leeson 2007a; Powell et al. 2008). We add to these exceptions.
 
5
For a version of this argument that is better embedded in economic history, one should consult Ogilvie and Carus (2014). It can also be framed in terms of the recent contribution of Acemoglu and Robinson (2019) where societies that want to achieve growth and development must remain narrow corridor between lawlessness and authoritarianism. In that corridor, rulers provide security but they are constrained (either de jure or de facto) from abusing the tools that allow them to provide security. Related to this point, see also Piano (2019), Boettke and Candela (2020), Geloso and Salter (2020), and Piano and Salter (2020).
 
6
One may conjecture that if such a situation is inefficient, then as Leeson (2020) would suggest, this raises another question: why will this situation prevail as the status quo? As Holcombe (2018, p. 253) argues, the point of the Coase Theorem applied to government (or the PCT) is not to conclude that transaction costs are low and that resources are allocated to their highest valued uses, but rather that when resources are not allocated to their highest-valued uses, the reason is that transaction costs stand in the way. In politics, special interest groups face low transaction costs of bargaining with each other and therefore can make public policy for their benefit. Because the masses face high transaction costs in organizing as an interest group, this excludes them from the political bargaining process. As a result, the “efficient” outcome in this case will be for resources to be allocated to the highest valued uses among individuals in the low-transaction-cost group, but costs are dispersed among those in the high-transaction-cost group, who cannot bargain to mitigate them. None of this necessarily implies that there is not the possibility for the high-transaction-cost group to bargain with the low-transaction-cost group to allocate resources more efficiently. As Coase (1960, p. 34) states, “Pigovian analysis shows us that it is possible to conceive of better worlds than the one in which we live. But the problem is to devise practical arrangements which will correct defects in one part of the system without causing more serious harm.” For example, it has historically been the case that authoritarian political elites have ceded power to a parliament as form of political exchange and unintendedly created a path toward the rule of law, which has reduced the transaction costs of devising more inclusive political institutions as well as greater security of the property rights among the masses of the population (see Kiser and Barzel 1991; Barzel 2000, 2002; Congleton 2011; Candela 2020).
 
7
Anderson and McChesney (1994) use “negotiating” in their work, but we use the term “trade,” hence our modification of the terminology.
 
8
Under the constraint that α and β must be between 0 and 1, that α > (1 − α) and β > (1 − β).
 
9
The narrower (wider) the distribution of the gains (costs) from violence, the greater the chances of violence being used. The wider (narrower) the distribution of the gains (costs) from violence, the greater the chances of using trade.
 
10
Bouchard (1999, p. 81) priced muskets in New France (modern day Quebec) at somewhere between 10 and 30 livres between 1720 and 1740 while Geloso finds that incomes per person during the era fluctuated between 93 and 136 livres (2016, p. 131). This fails to include the cost of maintaining a working firearm.
 
11
It is also important to point out that none of the colonies during the eighteenth century were net fiscal contributors to their empires: metropolitan governments expended more on them than they extracted in revenues (Davis and Huttenback 1982; Desbarats 1997).
 
12
One such example is the deportation of the Acadians in 1755. This was pushed for by the Massachusetts colony, and though London had explicitly disapproved, they ended up paying for it nonetheless (Geloso 2015). See more in Sect. 4.3.
 
13
Gregg and Wishart (2012) considered the social cost of the removal of the Cherokees from the areas they occupied in Alabama, Tennessee, North Carolina and Georgia during the 1830s. This is an important example, as popular imagination concentrates largely on the postbellum era as the era of violence towards Native Americans. However, as Gregg and Wishart show, the budgetary cost alone represented 3% of the US GDP in 1830. For Cherokees, direct costs represented 17.13% of their GDP. For comparative purposes, another costly war in American history, World War Two, constituted a burden equal to 1.88% of GDP. The social costs for Cherokees were even higher.
 
14
Such conflicts between settlers and natives occurred in regions such as Quebec, New England and New York in spite of a much larger fur trade than in Acadia (Delâge 1970; Leach 1988). This suggests that comparative advantage was in itself not sufficient.
 
15
The reduction in population is largely attributable to the introduction of diseases to which First Nations had never been exposed. However, the magnitude of their population decline places the Mi’kmaq among the groups that suffered least from this problem.
 
16
See Leeson (2014, pp. 155–169) for other examples.
 
17
Historians recognize that Acadia was a much less hierarchical society than Quebec was Heaman (2015). Historians also extend this judgment to the American colonies even though the comparative body of literature is smaller on this front (Griffiths 1992; Hodson 2012). In addition, attempts to impose formal rules were impeded by the lack of “administrative stability” and the inability to erect an “efficient bureaucracy” (Harris 2008, p. 56).
 
18
Which earned the Acadians the nickname of the “neutrals.” The British also were aware that they held no grip on the Acadian countryside (Harris 2008, p. 56).
 
19
The seigneur could impose the frontage tax of the cens, the conceded land area tax of the rente, the land sale tax of the lods et ventes, as well as a wide array of ancillary taxes that depended on the features of his estate. The seigneur also imposed the mandatory minimum labor provision of two to three days of work per year (known as the corvée) which could be avoided by paying a fee amounting to twice the daily wage rate for unskilled workers.
 
20
In 1720, after the cession of the region to the British, governor Richard Philipps claimed that trade between Acadia and New England stood at 10,000 £—a large part of which consisted of fur pelts. There is uncertainty as to which type of monetary units Philipps was referring to (New England currency, Halifax currency, Sterling currency or French currency. Simultaneously, the Acadians also traded with the French colony of Cape Breton, situated in the northern part of Nova Scotia. In 1740, it is believed that they traded for 26,939 livres (roughly 3.87 livres per person in Acadia) of which 20.1% was from skins, hides or furs (Clark 1968, pp. 207, 255–259).
 
21
We use the British spelling of dyke because it is the one used in the Canadian economic history literature on the topic (Saunders 1935; Clark 1968; Upton 1979; Wynn 1979; Griffiths 1992; Gwyn 1998; Faragher 2006, 2014; Kennedy 2008, 2013, 2014; Harris 2008; Hodson 2012; Caron 2015) and in the wider literature on farming in the area of New Brunswick and Nova Scotia (Longley 1936). We prefer to respect established conventions on the topic by using the British spelling.
 
22
They hunted seal in January. In February and March, they hunted otter, beaver, moose, bear and caribou. As of April, they fished (smelt, herring, shad, sturgeon and cod later in the summer). During the summer, they also hunted pigeon, partridge, hare and rabbit. Foraging and gathering yielded such edibles as roots, blueberries, beechnuts, wild pears and cranberries.
 
23
The sources are not always precise as to which grain is being discussed, but wheat tended to be the main crop in both Quebec and Acadia.
 
24
A good illustration of this relative wealth is exemplified in the work of Griffiths (1984) where the period from 1713 to 1748 is labelled as a golden age. The Acadian data provided by (Leblanc 1979) suggest a compounded growth rate for Acadia of 4.73% per year between 1710 and 1755. The data for Massachusetts and the whole of the thirteen colonies provided by Rabushka (2008) suggest slower growth rates of 2.57% and 3.25%, respectively.
 
25
Geloso (2015) observes that the reaction in London to the deportation generated a backlash that pushed colonial officials, when they took over the larger French colony of Quebec in 1760, to tolerate the French-Canadians (their faith, their institutions, and their customs) and to eschew any talk of deportation.
 
26
This is unsurprising given the Mi’kmaq were outnumbered by more than 20 to 1 (Bock 1978, p. 117; Upton 1979, p. 78).
 
27
There was a notable incident in 1779, when a group of Mi’kmaq attacked local British settlers in Miramichi, raised a French flag and asserted support for the American revolutionaries. The uprising was subdued by British troops and the British forced the Mi’kmaq tribe of the area to change chiefs (Patterson 2009, p. 50).
 
28
There was a fear in 1793 that there would be a French invasion (Upton 1793, p. 83), and fears of an American invasion in the early 1800s (Upton 1979, p. 86).
 
29
Andrew Nurse (2004, p. 128) describes the post-1760 decisions of the Mi’kmaq in the following terms: “By 1760 the Mi'kmaq leadership had little option but to accept whatever deal was offered (…) the British Crown, in the form of the colonial administration (…) held sole legal authority over Nova Scotia with the legitimate right to make law unilaterally, including the regulation of the Mi'kmaq economy.” From there, the British established Mi’kmaq reservations which they gradually reduced in size at the behest of local settlers (notably after the migration of Empire loyalists to Canada) and granted themselves the right to confirm the selection of chiefs (Bock 1978, pp. 117–119).
 
30
There are other pieces of supporting evidence as well. Using import per capita figures, which are frequently used as a proxy for income growth, Gwyn suggests that the region stagnated economically until the mid-nineteenth century (1998, p. 168), while available evidence for Quebec suggests that the region experienced mild growth up until the 1850s (Paquet and Wallot 2007; Geloso and Bédard 2018; Geloso and Lindert 2020).
 
31
The 1701 census is available in the 1871 census of Canada, fourth volume, which compiles summaries for most censuses prior to that point (Public Archives of Canada 1874). The census of 1707 is detailed in the work of Clark (1968, pp. 234–235) but does contains some errors in calculation. Readers should consult the compilations available here (https://​139.​103.​17.​56/​cea/​livres/​doc.​cfm?​ident=​R0231&​cform=​T), which are drawn directly from Library and Archives Canada (Series G1, Vol. 466–1).
 
32
This approach is known as the welfare ratio approach. One should consult Allen (2001) for details about this approach, which is meant to create purchasing power parities that are superior to using exchange rates.
 
33
Geary-Khamis dollars estimates do not exist for the American colonies. For Britain, estimates of income exist in both forms.
 
34
See notably Gerschenkron (1947) for a detailed methodological discussion of this approach.
 
35
French cords are smaller: 48 cubic feet as opposed to 128 cubic feet.
 
36
The plural of a quintal which weighs 48.95 kg.
 
37
Lunn (1942, p. 118) suggests 70 to 80 lb, but it is important to note that she is referring to the French pound (489.5 g) as opposed to the British pound (453.6 g).
 
38
To arrive at this estimate, we took the population figure of 8,600 from the middle of the eighteenth century for this region as given by Carlos and Lewis (s2011, p. 72).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Abad, L. A., & van Zanden, J. L. (2016). Growth under extractive institutions? Latin American percapita GDP in colonial times. The Journal of Economic History, 76(4), 1182–1215.CrossRef Abad, L. A., & van Zanden, J. L. (2016). Growth under extractive institutions? Latin American percapita GDP in colonial times. The Journal of Economic History, 76(4), 1182–1215.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D. (2003). Why not a political Coase theorem? Social conflict, commitment, and politics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 620–652.CrossRef Acemoglu, D. (2003). Why not a political Coase theorem? Social conflict, commitment, and politics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 620–652.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2019). The narrow corridor: states, societies, and the fate of liberty. New York: Penguin Press. Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2019). The narrow corridor: states, societies, and the fate of liberty. New York: Penguin Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Allen, R. S. (1996). His Majesty’s Indian allies: British Indian policy in the defence of Canada 1774–1815. London: Dundurn. Allen, R. S. (1996). His Majesty’s Indian allies: British Indian policy in the defence of Canada 1774–1815. London: Dundurn.
Zurück zum Zitat Allen, R. C. (2001). The great divergence in European wages and prices from the middle ages to the first world war. Explorations in Economic History, 38(4), 411–447.CrossRef Allen, R. C. (2001). The great divergence in European wages and prices from the middle ages to the first world war. Explorations in Economic History, 38(4), 411–447.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Altman, M. (1988). Economic growth in Canada, 1695–1739: Estimates and analysis. William and Mary Quarterly, 45(4), 684–711.CrossRef Altman, M. (1988). Economic growth in Canada, 1695–1739: Estimates and analysis. William and Mary Quarterly, 45(4), 684–711.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Altman, M. (1998). Land tenure, ethnicity, and the condition of agricultural income and productivity in mid-nineteenth century Quebec. Agricultural History, 72(4), 708–762. Altman, M. (1998). Land tenure, ethnicity, and the condition of agricultural income and productivity in mid-nineteenth century Quebec. Agricultural History, 72(4), 708–762.
Zurück zum Zitat Anderson, T. L., & Hill, P. J. (1979). An American experiment in anarcho capitalism: the not so wild, wild west. Journal of Libertarian Studies, 3(1), 9–29. Anderson, T. L., & Hill, P. J. (1979). An American experiment in anarcho capitalism: the not so wild, wild west. Journal of Libertarian Studies, 3(1), 9–29.
Zurück zum Zitat Anderson, T. L., & Hill, P. J. (2004). The not so wild, wild west: property rights on the frontier. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Anderson, T. L., & Hill, P. J. (2004). The not so wild, wild west: property rights on the frontier. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Anderson, T. L., & McChesney, F. S. (1994). Raid or trade? An economic model of Indianwhite relations. Journal of Law and Economics, 37(1), 39–74.CrossRef Anderson, T. L., & McChesney, F. S. (1994). Raid or trade? An economic model of Indianwhite relations. Journal of Law and Economics, 37(1), 39–74.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Balcom, B. A. (1984). The cod fishery of Isle Royale, 1713–58. Ottawa: National Historic Parks and Sites Branch, Parks Canada. Balcom, B. A. (1984). The cod fishery of Isle Royale, 1713–58. Ottawa: National Historic Parks and Sites Branch, Parks Canada.
Zurück zum Zitat Barzel, Y. (2000). Property rights and the evolution of the state. Economics of Governance, 1, 25–51. Barzel, Y. (2000). Property rights and the evolution of the state. Economics of Governance, 1, 25–51.
Zurück zum Zitat Barzel, Y. (2002). A theory of the state: economic rights, legal rights, and the scope of the state. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Barzel, Y. (2002). A theory of the state: economic rights, legal rights, and the scope of the state. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Bennett, M. K. (1955). The food economy of the New England Indians, 1605–75. Journal of Political Economy, 63(5), 369–397.CrossRef Bennett, M. K. (1955). The food economy of the New England Indians, 1605–75. Journal of Political Economy, 63(5), 369–397.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. L. (1989). The spontaneous evolution of commercial law. Southern Economic Journal, 55(3), 644–661.CrossRef Benson, B. L. (1989). The spontaneous evolution of commercial law. Southern Economic Journal, 55(3), 644–661.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bock, P.K. (1978). Micmacs. In B.G. Trigger (Ed.), Handbook of North American Indians, Vol. 15: Northeast. Washington, D.C.: Smithsonian Institution. Bock, P.K. (1978). Micmacs. In B.G. Trigger (Ed.), Handbook of North American Indians, Vol. 15: Northeast. Washington, D.C.: Smithsonian Institution.
Zurück zum Zitat Boettke, P. J., & Candela, R. A. (2020). Productive specialization, peaceful cooperation, and the problem of the predatory state: lessons from comparative historical political economy. Public Choice, 182(3–4), 331–352.CrossRef Boettke, P. J., & Candela, R. A. (2020). Productive specialization, peaceful cooperation, and the problem of the predatory state: lessons from comparative historical political economy. Public Choice, 182(3–4), 331–352.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Broadberry, S., Campbell, B. M. S., Klein, A., Overton, M., & van Leeuwen, B. (2015). British economic growth, 1270–1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Broadberry, S., Campbell, B. M. S., Klein, A., Overton, M., & van Leeuwen, B. (2015). British economic growth, 1270–1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Candela, R. A. (2020). The political economy of insecure property rights: insights from the Kingdom of Sicily. Journal of Institutional Economic, 16(2), 233–249.CrossRef Candela, R. A. (2020). The political economy of insecure property rights: insights from the Kingdom of Sicily. Journal of Institutional Economic, 16(2), 233–249.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carlos, A. (2018). Global trade and development: the good, bad, and unanticipated 1600–1800. Essays in Economic and Business History, 36(1), 95–120. Carlos, A. (2018). Global trade and development: the good, bad, and unanticipated 1600–1800. Essays in Economic and Business History, 36(1), 95–120.
Zurück zum Zitat Carlos, A. M., & Lewis, F. D. (2001). Trade, consumption, and the native economy: lessons from York factory, Hudson Bay. Journal of Economic History, 61(4), 1037–1064.CrossRef Carlos, A. M., & Lewis, F. D. (2001). Trade, consumption, and the native economy: lessons from York factory, Hudson Bay. Journal of Economic History, 61(4), 1037–1064.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carlos, A. M., & Lewis, F. D. (2010). Commerce by a frozen sea: native Americans and the European fur trade. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.CrossRef Carlos, A. M., & Lewis, F. D. (2010). Commerce by a frozen sea: native Americans and the European fur trade. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chute, J. E. (1999). Frank G Speck’s contributions to the understanding of the Mi’kmaq land use, leadership and land management. Ethnohistory, 46(3), 481–540. Chute, J. E. (1999). Frank G Speck’s contributions to the understanding of the Mi’kmaq land use, leadership and land management. Ethnohistory, 46(3), 481–540.
Zurück zum Zitat Clark, A. H. (1968). Acadia: the geography of early Nova Scotia to 1760. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press. Clark, A. H. (1968). Acadia: the geography of early Nova Scotia to 1760. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.CrossRef Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Congleton, R. (2011). Perfecting parliament: constitutional reform, liberalism, and the rise of western democracy. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Congleton, R. (2011). Perfecting parliament: constitutional reform, liberalism, and the rise of western democracy. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Crafts, N. F. R., & Harley, C. K. (1992). Output growth and the British industrial revolution: a restatement of the Crafts-Harley view. Economic History Review, 45(4), 703–730.CrossRef Crafts, N. F. R., & Harley, C. K. (1992). Output growth and the British industrial revolution: a restatement of the Crafts-Harley view. Economic History Review, 45(4), 703–730.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Davis, L. E., & Huttenback, R.A. (1982). The cost of empire. In R.L. Ransom, R. Sutch, & G.M. Walton, (Eds.), Explorations in the new economic history: essays in honor of DouglassC. North. New York: Academic Press. Davis, L. E., & Huttenback, R.A. (1982). The cost of empire. In R.L. Ransom, R. Sutch, & G.M. Walton, (Eds.), Explorations in the new economic history: essays in honor of DouglassC. North. New York: Academic Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Dechêne, L. (1992). Habitants and merchants in seventeenth-century Montreal. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press. Dechêne, L. (1992). Habitants and merchants in seventeenth-century Montreal. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Demsetz, H. (1967). Toward a theory of property rights. American Economic Review, 57(2), 347–359. Demsetz, H. (1967). Toward a theory of property rights. American Economic Review, 57(2), 347–359.
Zurück zum Zitat Desbarats, C. M. (1997). France in North America: the net burden of empire during the first half of the eighteenth century. French History, 11(1), 1–28.CrossRef Desbarats, C. M. (1997). France in North America: the net burden of empire during the first half of the eighteenth century. French History, 11(1), 1–28.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dickinson, J. A. (1982). Justice et justiciables: La procédure civile à la prévôté deQuébec, 1667–1759. Quebec: Les Presses de l’Université Laval. Dickinson, J. A. (1982). Justice et justiciables: La procédure civile à la prévôté deQuébec, 1667–1759. Quebec: Les Presses de l’Université Laval.
Zurück zum Zitat Dippel, C. (2014). Forced coexistence and economic development: evidence from Native American reservations. Econometrica, 82(6), 2131–2165.CrossRef Dippel, C. (2014). Forced coexistence and economic development: evidence from Native American reservations. Econometrica, 82(6), 2131–2165.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ellickson, R. C. (1991). Order without law: how neighbors settle disputes. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Ellickson, R. C. (1991). Order without law: how neighbors settle disputes. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Faragher, J. M. (2006). “A great and noble acheme”: thoughts on the expulsion of the Acadians. Acadiensis, 36(1), 82–92. Faragher, J. M. (2006). “A great and noble acheme”: thoughts on the expulsion of the Acadians. Acadiensis, 36(1), 82–92.
Zurück zum Zitat Faragher, J. M. (2014). Commentary: settler colonial studies and the North American frontier. Settler Colonial Studies, 4(2), 181–191.CrossRef Faragher, J. M. (2014). Commentary: settler colonial studies and the North American frontier. Settler Colonial Studies, 4(2), 181–191.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Friedman, D. (1979). Private creation and enforcement of law: a historical case. Journal of Legal Studies, 8(2), 399–415.CrossRef Friedman, D. (1979). Private creation and enforcement of law: a historical case. Journal of Legal Studies, 8(2), 399–415.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Garneau, F. (1859). Histoire du Canada: Depuis sa découverte jusqu’à nos jours. Québec: P. Lamoreaux. Garneau, F. (1859). Histoire du Canada: Depuis sa découverte jusqu’à nos jours. Québec: P. Lamoreaux.
Zurück zum Zitat Gélinas, C. (2000). Note de recherche: L’aventure de la North West Company en Mauricie, 1799–1814. Revue d’histoire de l’Amérique française, 53(3), 401–419.CrossRef Gélinas, C. (2000). Note de recherche: L’aventure de la North West Company en Mauricie, 1799–1814. Revue d’histoire de l’Amérique française, 53(3), 401–419.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Geloso, V. (2015). Toleration of catholics in Quebec and British Public Finances, 1760 to1775. Essays in Economic and Business History, 33, 51–81. Geloso, V. (2015). Toleration of catholics in Quebec and British Public Finances, 1760 to1775. Essays in Economic and Business History, 33, 51–81.
Zurück zum Zitat Geloso, V. (2016). The seeds of divergence: The economy of French North America, 1688 to 1760. Ph.D. Dissertation. London: London School of Economics and Political Science. Geloso, V. (2016). The seeds of divergence: The economy of French North America, 1688 to 1760. Ph.D. Dissertation. London: London School of Economics and Political Science.
Zurück zum Zitat Geloso, V. (2019). Distinct within North America: Living standards in French Canada, 1688–1775. Cliometrica, 13(2), 277–321.CrossRef Geloso, V. (2019). Distinct within North America: Living standards in French Canada, 1688–1775. Cliometrica, 13(2), 277–321.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Geloso, V. (2020). Predation, seigneurial tenure and development in French Colonial America. Social Science History, 44(3), pages undetermined. Geloso, V. (2020). Predation, seigneurial tenure and development in French Colonial America. Social Science History, 44(3), pages undetermined.
Zurück zum Zitat Geloso, V., & Bédard, M. (2018). Was economic growth likely in lower Canada? Journal of Private Enterprise, 33(3), 1–23. Geloso, V., & Bédard, M. (2018). Was economic growth likely in lower Canada? Journal of Private Enterprise, 33(3), 1–23.
Zurück zum Zitat Geloso, V., Hinton, M., & Kufenko, V. (2017). The equally “bad” French and English Farmers of Quebec: new TFP measures from the 1831 census. Historical Methods: A Journal of Quantitative and Interdisciplinary History, 50(3), 170–189.CrossRef Geloso, V., Hinton, M., & Kufenko, V. (2017). The equally “bad” French and English Farmers of Quebec: new TFP measures from the 1831 census. Historical Methods: A Journal of Quantitative and Interdisciplinary History, 50(3), 170–189.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Geloso, V., & Lacombe, A. (2016). Why was flour of poor quality? The impact of seigneurial laws and price controls on flour in Quebec during the colonial era. Agricultural History Review, 64(2), 181–195. Geloso, V., & Lacombe, A. (2016). Why was flour of poor quality? The impact of seigneurial laws and price controls on flour in Quebec during the colonial era. Agricultural History Review, 64(2), 181–195.
Zurück zum Zitat Geloso, V., & Leeson, P.T. (2020). Are anarcho-capitalists insane? Living standards under medieval Icelandic conflict institutions. Working Paper. Geloso, V., & Leeson, P.T. (2020). Are anarcho-capitalists insane? Living standards under medieval Icelandic conflict institutions. Working Paper.
Zurück zum Zitat Geloso, V., & Lindert, P. (2020). Relative costs of living, for richer and poorer, 1688–1914. Cliometrica. Geloso, V., & Lindert, P. (2020). Relative costs of living, for richer and poorer, 1688–1914. Cliometrica.
Zurück zum Zitat Geloso, V., & Salter, A. W. (2020). State capacity and economic development: Causal mechanism or correlative filter? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 170, 372–385.CrossRef Geloso, V., & Salter, A. W. (2020). State capacity and economic development: Causal mechanism or correlative filter? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 170, 372–385.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gerschenkron, A. (1947). The Soviet indices of industrial production. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 29(4), 217–226.CrossRef Gerschenkron, A. (1947). The Soviet indices of industrial production. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 29(4), 217–226.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gregg, M. T., & Wishart, D. M. (2012). The price of Cherokee removal. Explorations in Economic History, 49(4), 423–442.CrossRef Gregg, M. T., & Wishart, D. M. (2012). The price of Cherokee removal. Explorations in Economic History, 49(4), 423–442.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Greif, A. (1989). Reputation and coalitions in medieval trade: Evidence on the Maghribi traders. The Journal of Economic History, 49(4), 857–882.CrossRef Greif, A. (1989). Reputation and coalitions in medieval trade: Evidence on the Maghribi traders. The Journal of Economic History, 49(4), 857–882.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Greif, A. (1993). Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: the Maghribi Traders’ Coalition. The American Economic Review, 83(3), 525–548. Greif, A. (1993). Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: the Maghribi Traders’ Coalition. The American Economic Review, 83(3), 525–548.
Zurück zum Zitat Grenier, B. (2012). Brève histoire du régime seigneurial. Montréal: Boréal. Grenier, B. (2012). Brève histoire du régime seigneurial. Montréal: Boréal.
Zurück zum Zitat Griffiths, N. E. S. (1992). Contexts of Acadian history, 1686–1784. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press. Griffiths, N. E. S. (1992). Contexts of Acadian history, 1686–1784. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Griffiths, N. (2004). The golden age: Acadian life, 1713–1748. Histoire Sociale-Social History, 17(33), 21–34. Griffiths, N. (2004). The golden age: Acadian life, 1713–1748. Histoire Sociale-Social History, 17(33), 21–34.
Zurück zum Zitat Griffiths, N. E. S. (2004). From Migrant to Acadian: A North American Border People, 1604–1755. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press. Griffiths, N. E. S. (2004). From Migrant to Acadian: A North American Border People, 1604–1755. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Gwyn, J. (2003). The Mi’kmaq, poor settlers, and the Nova Scotia fur trade, 1783–1853. Journal of the Canadian Historical Association, 14(1), 65–91.CrossRef Gwyn, J. (2003). The Mi’kmaq, poor settlers, and the Nova Scotia fur trade, 1783–1853. Journal of the Canadian Historical Association, 14(1), 65–91.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Harris, C. ([1966] 1984). Seigneurial system in early Canada: a geographical study. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press. Harris, C. ([1966] 1984). Seigneurial system in early Canada: a geographical study. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Harris, C. (2008). The reluctant land: society, space, and environment in Canada before Confederation. Vancouver: UBC Press. Harris, C. (2008). The reluctant land: society, space, and environment in Canada before Confederation. Vancouver: UBC Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Heaman, E. A. (2015). A short history of the state in Canada. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.CrossRef Heaman, E. A. (2015). A short history of the state in Canada. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hodson, C. (2012). The Acadian diaspora: an eighteenth-century history. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hodson, C. (2012). The Acadian diaspora: an eighteenth-century history. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Holcombe, R. G. (2015). Political capitalism. Cato Journal, 35(1), 41–66. Holcombe, R. G. (2015). Political capitalism. Cato Journal, 35(1), 41–66.
Zurück zum Zitat Holcombe, R. G. (2018). The Coase theorem, applied to markets and government. The Independent Review, 23(2), 249–266. Holcombe, R. G. (2018). The Coase theorem, applied to markets and government. The Independent Review, 23(2), 249–266.
Zurück zum Zitat Hughes, J. R. T. (1991). The governmental habit redux: economic controls from colonial times to the present. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRef Hughes, J. R. T. (1991). The governmental habit redux: economic controls from colonial times to the present. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jacobs, W.R. (1988). British Indian Policies to 1783. In W.E. Washburn (Ed.), Handbook of North American Indians, Volume 4: history of Indian-White relations. Washington DC: Smithsonian Institution. Jacobs, W.R. (1988). British Indian Policies to 1783. In W.E. Washburn (Ed.), Handbook of North American Indians, Volume 4: history of Indian-White relations. Washington DC: Smithsonian Institution.
Zurück zum Zitat Jefferson, C. (1994). Conquest by Law. Ottawa: Solicitor General of Canada. Jefferson, C. (1994). Conquest by Law. Ottawa: Solicitor General of Canada.
Zurück zum Zitat Jones, D. R. (2004). From frontier to borderland: the Acadian community in a comparative context, 1605–1710. Journal of the Royal Nova Scotia Historical Society, 7, 15–37. Jones, D. R. (2004). From frontier to borderland: the Acadian community in a comparative context, 1605–1710. Journal of the Royal Nova Scotia Historical Society, 7, 15–37.
Zurück zum Zitat Kennedy, G. M. W. (2008). The parish assembly and its delegates in the Loudunais and Acadia, 1650–1755. Journal of The Western Society for French History, 36, 21–35. Kennedy, G. M. W. (2008). The parish assembly and its delegates in the Loudunais and Acadia, 1650–1755. Journal of The Western Society for French History, 36, 21–35.
Zurück zum Zitat Kennedy, G. (2013). Marshland colonization in Acadia and Poitou during the 17th Century. Acadiensis, 42(1), 37–66. Kennedy, G. (2013). Marshland colonization in Acadia and Poitou during the 17th Century. Acadiensis, 42(1), 37–66.
Zurück zum Zitat Kennedy, G. M. W. (2014). Something of a peasant paradise?: Comparing rural societies in Acadie and the Loudunais 1604–1755. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press. Kennedy, G. M. W. (2014). Something of a peasant paradise?: Comparing rural societies in Acadie and the Loudunais 1604–1755. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Kiser, E., & Barzel, Y. (1991). The origins of democracy in England. Rationality and Society, 3(4), 396–422.CrossRef Kiser, E., & Barzel, Y. (1991). The origins of democracy in England. Rationality and Society, 3(4), 396–422.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kostelnik, J., & Skarbek, D. (2013). The governance institutions of a drug trafficking organization. Public Choice, 156(1/2), 95–103.CrossRef Kostelnik, J., & Skarbek, D. (2013). The governance institutions of a drug trafficking organization. Public Choice, 156(1/2), 95–103.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leach, D.E. (1988). Colonial Indian wars. In W.E. Washburn (Ed.), Handbook of North American Indians, Volume 4: History of Indian-White relations. Washington, DC: Smithsonian Institution. Leach, D.E. (1988). Colonial Indian wars. In W.E. Washburn (Ed.), Handbook of North American Indians, Volume 4: History of Indian-White relations. Washington, DC: Smithsonian Institution.
Zurück zum Zitat Leblanc, R. A. (1979). Les migrations Acadiennes. Cahiers de géographie du Québec, 23(58), 99–124.CrossRef Leblanc, R. A. (1979). Les migrations Acadiennes. Cahiers de géographie du Québec, 23(58), 99–124.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2007a). Better off stateless: Somalia before and after collapse. Journal of Comparative Economics, 35(4), 689–710.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2007a). Better off stateless: Somalia before and after collapse. Journal of Comparative Economics, 35(4), 689–710.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2007b). Trading with bandits. Journal of Law and Economics, 50(2), 303–321.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2007b). Trading with bandits. Journal of Law and Economics, 50(2), 303–321.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2007c). An-arrgh-chy: the law and economics of pirate organization. Journal of Political Economy, 115(6), 1049–1094.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2007c). An-arrgh-chy: the law and economics of pirate organization. Journal of Political Economy, 115(6), 1049–1094.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2007d). Efficient anarchy. Public Choice, 130(1/2), 41–53.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2007d). Efficient anarchy. Public Choice, 130(1/2), 41–53.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2008). Social distance and self-enforcing exchange. The Journal of Legal Studies, 37(1), 161–188.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2008). Social distance and self-enforcing exchange. The Journal of Legal Studies, 37(1), 161–188.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2009). The laws of lawlessness. Journal of Legal Studies, 38(2), 471–503.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2009). The laws of lawlessness. Journal of Legal Studies, 38(2), 471–503.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2014). Anarchy unbound: why self-governance works better than you think. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2014). Anarchy unbound: why self-governance works better than you think. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2020). Logic is a harsh mistress: welfare economics for economists. Journal of Institutional Economics, 16(2), 145–150.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2020). Logic is a harsh mistress: welfare economics for economists. Journal of Institutional Economics, 16(2), 145–150.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lewis, F., & McInnis, M. (1984). Agricultural output and efficiency in Lower Canada, 1851. Research in Economic History, 9, 45–87. Lewis, F., & McInnis, M. (1984). Agricultural output and efficiency in Lower Canada, 1851. Research in Economic History, 9, 45–87.
Zurück zum Zitat Lindert, P. H., & Williamson, J. G. (2016). Unequal gains: American growth and inequality since 1700. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRef Lindert, P. H., & Williamson, J. G. (2016). Unequal gains: American growth and inequality since 1700. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Longley, W. V. (1936). Land utilization in Nova Scotia. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 18(3), 533–542. Longley, W. V. (1936). Land utilization in Nova Scotia. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 18(3), 533–542.
Zurück zum Zitat Lunn, A.J. (1942). Economic development of New France, 1713–1757. PhD dissertation. Montreal: McGill University. Lunn, A.J. (1942). Economic development of New France, 1713–1757. PhD dissertation. Montreal: McGill University.
Zurück zum Zitat Maddison, A. (2007). The world economy, two-in-one edition, volume 1: a millennial perspective, volume 2: Historical statistics. Paris: Development Centre of the Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development. Maddison, A. (2007). The world economy, two-in-one edition, volume 1: a millennial perspective, volume 2: Historical statistics. Paris: Development Centre of the Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development.
Zurück zum Zitat Mahon, J. K. (1988). Indian-United States Military Situation. In W. E. Washburn (Ed.), Handbook of North American Indians, Volume 4: history of Indian-white relations (pp. 1775–1848). Washington, DC: Smithsonian Institution. Mahon, J. K. (1988). Indian-United States Military Situation. In W. E. Washburn (Ed.), Handbook of North American Indians, Volume 4: history of Indian-white relations (pp. 1775–1848). Washington, DC: Smithsonian Institution.
Zurück zum Zitat Mazé, A., & Ménard, C. (2010). Private ordering, collective action, and the self-enforcing range of contracts. European Journal of Law and Economics, 29(1), 131–153.CrossRef Mazé, A., & Ménard, C. (2010). Private ordering, collective action, and the self-enforcing range of contracts. European Journal of Law and Economics, 29(1), 131–153.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Murray, J. E. (1938). The early fur trade in New France and New Netherland. Canadian Historical Review, 19(4), 365–377.CrossRef Murray, J. E. (1938). The early fur trade in New France and New Netherland. Canadian Historical Review, 19(4), 365–377.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nurse, A. (2004). History, law and the Mi’kmaq of Atlantic Canada. Acadiensis, 33(2), 126–133. Nurse, A. (2004). History, law and the Mi’kmaq of Atlantic Canada. Acadiensis, 33(2), 126–133.
Zurück zum Zitat Paquet, G., & Wallot, J. (2007). Un Québec moderne, 1760–1840: Essai d’histoire économique et sociale. Montréal: Éditions Hurtubise HMH. Paquet, G., & Wallot, J. (2007). Un Québec moderne, 1760–1840: Essai d’histoire économique et sociale. Montréal: Éditions Hurtubise HMH.
Zurück zum Zitat Parmenter, J., & Robison, M. P. (2007). The perils and possibilities of wartime neutrality on the edges of empire: Iroquois and Acadians between the French and British in North America, 1744–1760. Diplomatic History, 31(2), 167–206.CrossRef Parmenter, J., & Robison, M. P. (2007). The perils and possibilities of wartime neutrality on the edges of empire: Iroquois and Acadians between the French and British in North America, 1744–1760. Diplomatic History, 31(2), 167–206.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Patterson, S. (1994). 1744–1763: colonial wars and aboriginal peoples. In P.A. Buckner & J.G. Reid (Eds.), The Atlantic region to confederation: a history. Toronto: University of oronto Press. Patterson, S. (1994). 1744–1763: colonial wars and aboriginal peoples. In P.A. Buckner & J.G. Reid (Eds.), The Atlantic region to confederation: a history. Toronto: University of oronto Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Patterson, S. (2009). Eighteenth-century treaties: the Mi’kmaq, Maliseet, and Passamaquoddy experience. Native Studies Review, 18(1), 25–52. Patterson, S. (2009). Eighteenth-century treaties: the Mi’kmaq, Maliseet, and Passamaquoddy experience. Native Studies Review, 18(1), 25–52.
Zurück zum Zitat Piano, E. E. (2019). State capacity and public choice: a critical survey. Public Choice, 178(1–2), 289–309.CrossRef Piano, E. E. (2019). State capacity and public choice: a critical survey. Public Choice, 178(1–2), 289–309.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Piano, E. E., & Salter, A. W. (2020). The fundamental Coase of development: property rights foundations of the effective state. Journal of Institutional Economics, 1–16, 38. Piano, E. E., & Salter, A. W. (2020). The fundamental Coase of development: property rights foundations of the effective state. Journal of Institutional Economics, 1–16, 38.
Zurück zum Zitat Powell, B., Ford, R., & Nowrasteh, A. (2008). Somalia after state collapse: chaos or improvement? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 67(3/4), 657–670.CrossRef Powell, B., Ford, R., & Nowrasteh, A. (2008). Somalia after state collapse: chaos or improvement? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 67(3/4), 657–670.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Powell, B., & Stringham, E. P. (2009). Public choice and the economic analysis of anarchy. Public Choice, 140(3/4), 503–538.CrossRef Powell, B., & Stringham, E. P. (2009). Public choice and the economic analysis of anarchy. Public Choice, 140(3/4), 503–538.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Public Archives of Canada. (1874). Censuses of Canada, 1665 to 1871. Ottawa: Department of Agriculture. Public Archives of Canada. (1874). Censuses of Canada, 1665 to 1871. Ottawa: Department of Agriculture.
Zurück zum Zitat Rabushka, A. (2008). Taxation in colonial America. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Rabushka, A. (2008). Taxation in colonial America. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Redish, A. (2019). Treaty of Paris vs. treaty of Niagara: rethinking Canadian economic history in the 21st century. Canadian Journal of Economics, 52(4), 1325–1348. Redish, A. (2019). Treaty of Paris vs. treaty of Niagara: rethinking Canadian economic history in the 21st century. Canadian Journal of Economics, 52(4), 1325–1348.
Zurück zum Zitat Richter, D. K. (1992). The ordeal of the longhouse: the peoples of the Iroquois League in the era of European colonization. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press. Richter, D. K. (1992). The ordeal of the longhouse: the peoples of the Iroquois League in the era of European colonization. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Richter, D. K. (2013). Trade, land, power: the struggle for eastern North America. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.CrossRef Richter, D. K. (2013). Trade, land, power: the struggle for eastern North America. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ridolfi, L. (2017). The French economy in the longue durée. A study on real wages, working days and economic performance from Louis IX to the revolution (1250–1789), Ph.D. Dissertation. Lucca: IMT Institute for Advanced Studies Lucca. Ridolfi, L. (2017). The French economy in the longue durée. A study on real wages, working days and economic performance from Louis IX to the revolution (1250–1789), Ph.D. Dissertation. Lucca: IMT Institute for Advanced Studies Lucca.
Zurück zum Zitat Roback, J. (1992). Exchange, sovereignty, and indian-anglo relations. In T.L. Anderson, (Ed.), Property Rights and Indian Economies. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield. Roback, J. (1992). Exchange, sovereignty, and indian-anglo relations. In T.L. Anderson, (Ed.), Property Rights and Indian Economies. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield.
Zurück zum Zitat Saunders, R. M. (1935). The first introduction of European plants and animals into Canada. Canadian Historical Review, 16(4), 388–406.CrossRef Saunders, R. M. (1935). The first introduction of European plants and animals into Canada. Canadian Historical Review, 16(4), 388–406.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shepherd, J. F., & Walton, G. R. (1972). Shipping, maritime trade, and the economic development of colonial North America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Shepherd, J. F., & Walton, G. R. (1972). Shipping, maritime trade, and the economic development of colonial North America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Skarbek, D. (2011). Governance and prison gangs. American Political Science Review, 105(4), 702–716.CrossRef Skarbek, D. (2011). Governance and prison gangs. American Political Science Review, 105(4), 702–716.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Skarbek, D. (2016). Covenants without the sword? Comparing prison self-governance globally. American Political Science Review, 110(4), 845–862.CrossRef Skarbek, D. (2016). Covenants without the sword? Comparing prison self-governance globally. American Political Science Review, 110(4), 845–862.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Solvason, B. T. R. (1993). Institutional evolution in the Icelandic Commonwealth. Constitutional Political Economy, 4(1), 97–125.CrossRef Solvason, B. T. R. (1993). Institutional evolution in the Icelandic Commonwealth. Constitutional Political Economy, 4(1), 97–125.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stigler, G. J. (1966). The theory of price (3rd ed.). New York: Macmillan. Stigler, G. J. (1966). The theory of price (3rd ed.). New York: Macmillan.
Zurück zum Zitat Stringham, E. (2002). The emergence of the London Stock Exchange as a self-policing club. Journal of Private Enterprise, 17(2), 1–19. Stringham, E. (2002). The emergence of the London Stock Exchange as a self-policing club. Journal of Private Enterprise, 17(2), 1–19.
Zurück zum Zitat Stringham, E. (2003). The extralegal development of securities trading in seventeenth century Amsterdam. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 43(2), 321–344.CrossRef Stringham, E. (2003). The extralegal development of securities trading in seventeenth century Amsterdam. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 43(2), 321–344.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stringham, E. P. (2015). Private governance: creating order in economic and social life. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRef Stringham, E. P. (2015). Private governance: creating order in economic and social life. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Surtees, R.J. (1988). Canadian Indian policies. In W.E. Washburn (Ed.), Handbook of North American Indians, Volume 4: history of Indian-White relations. Washington, DC: Smithsonian Institution. Surtees, R.J. (1988). Canadian Indian policies. In W.E. Washburn (Ed.), Handbook of North American Indians, Volume 4: history of Indian-White relations. Washington, DC: Smithsonian Institution.
Zurück zum Zitat Sutter, D. (1995). Asymmetric power relations and cooperation in anarchy. Southern Economic Journal, 61(3), 602–613.CrossRef Sutter, D. (1995). Asymmetric power relations and cooperation in anarchy. Southern Economic Journal, 61(3), 602–613.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Thwaites, R.G. (Ed.). ([1898] 1959). The Jesuit relations and allied documents: travels and explorations of the Jesuit missionaries in New France 1610—1791, Vol. III: Acadia 1611–1616. Cleveland: The Burrows Brothers. Thwaites, R.G. (Ed.). ([1898] 1959). The Jesuit relations and allied documents: travels and explorations of the Jesuit missionaries in New France 1610—1791, Vol. III: Acadia 1611–1616. Cleveland: The Burrows Brothers.
Zurück zum Zitat Trigger, B. G. (1989). The Indians and the heroic age of New France (revised). Ottawa: Canadian Historical Association. Trigger, B. G. (1989). The Indians and the heroic age of New France (revised). Ottawa: Canadian Historical Association.
Zurück zum Zitat Umbeck, J. (1981). Might makes rights: a theory of the formation and initial distribution of property rights. Economic Inquiry, 19(1), 38–59.CrossRef Umbeck, J. (1981). Might makes rights: a theory of the formation and initial distribution of property rights. Economic Inquiry, 19(1), 38–59.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Upton, L. F. S. (1979). Micmacs and colonists: Indian-white Relations in the maritimes, 1713–1867. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press. Upton, L. F. S. (1979). Micmacs and colonists: Indian-white Relations in the maritimes, 1713–1867. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Vaughan, A.T. ([1965] 1995). New England frontier: Puritans and Indians, 1620–1675. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press. Vaughan, A.T. ([1965] 1995). New England frontier: Puritans and Indians, 1620–1675. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Verney, J. (1991). The good regiment: the Carignan-Saliéres regiment in Canada, 1665–1668. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press. Verney, J. (1991). The good regiment: the Carignan-Saliéres regiment in Canada, 1665–1668. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Wade, M. (1988). French Indian policies. In W.E. Washburn (Ed.), Handbook of North American Indians, Volume 4: History of Indian-White relations. Washington, DC: Smithsonian Institution. Wade, M. (1988). French Indian policies. In W.E. Washburn (Ed.), Handbook of North American Indians, Volume 4: History of Indian-White relations. Washington, DC: Smithsonian Institution.
Zurück zum Zitat Wien, T. (1990). Selling beaver skins in North America and Europe, 1720–1760: the uses of fur trade imperialism. Journal of the Canadian Historical Association, 1(1), 293–317.CrossRef Wien, T. (1990). Selling beaver skins in North America and Europe, 1720–1760: the uses of fur trade imperialism. Journal of the Canadian Historical Association, 1(1), 293–317.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wynn, G. (1979). Late eighteenth-century agriculture on the Bay of Fundy marshlands. Acadiensis, 8(2), 80–89. Wynn, G. (1979). Late eighteenth-century agriculture on the Bay of Fundy marshlands. Acadiensis, 8(2), 80–89.
Zurück zum Zitat Zanella, F. C., Ekelund, R. B., & Laband, D. N. (2003). Monarchy, monopoly and mercantilism: Brazil versus the United States in the 1800s. Public Choice, 116(3–4), 381–398.CrossRef Zanella, F. C., Ekelund, R. B., & Laband, D. N. (2003). Monarchy, monopoly and mercantilism: Brazil versus the United States in the 1800s. Public Choice, 116(3–4), 381–398.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Trade or raid: Acadian settlers and native Americans before 1755
verfasst von
Rosolino A. Candela
Vincent J. Geloso
Publikationsdatum
29.10.2020
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 3-4/2021
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-020-00853-y

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3-4/2021

Public Choice 3-4/2021 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner