Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Social Choice and Welfare 1-2/2023

26.09.2021 | Original Paper

Voting over selfishly optimal income tax schedules with tax-driven migrations

verfasst von: Darong Dai, Guoqiang Tian

Erschienen in: Social Choice and Welfare | Ausgabe 1-2/2023

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We study majority voting over selfishly optimal nonlinear income tax schedules proposed by a continuum of workers who can migrate between two competing jurisdictions. Both skill level and migration cost are the private information of each worker who will propose an allocation schedule that maximizes the utility of her own type. We identify reasonable scenarios in which the first-order approach applies and hence the second-order sufficient condition for incentive compatibility is fulfilled; otherwise, we need to apply the ironing surgery developed by Brett and Weymark (Games Econ Behav 101:172–188, 2017). Under quasilinear-in-consumption preferences, we show that the tax schedule proposed by the median skill type is the Condorcet winner, and provide a complete characterization of this tax schedule. While this schedule features negative marginal tax rates for low-skilled workers, it features positive rates for high-skilled workers with small migration elasticities; the marginal tax rates at the bottom and top skill levels cannot be unambiguously signed. Moreover, we detail the conditions under which migration induces uniformly higher or lower equilibrium marginal tax rates facing both low- and high-skilled workers than their counterparts in autarky, which leads us to conclude that geographic mobility does not always limit the government’s ability to redistribute incomes via tax-transfer systems.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
In a sense, the equity-efficiency tradeoff governing the design of a socially optimal tax-transfer system still applies to our study. On the one hand, the international mobility of high-skilled workers in the context of globalization makes the efficiency concern more relevant, while on the other hand the rising income inequality induced by globalization calls for more public transfers and subsidies to low-skilled workers (or the socially and economically disadvantaged) — especially when the majority rule under the one-person-one-vote principle is used to select tax schedules. In practice, both the United States (e.g., Piketty 2014) and China (e.g., Huang et al. 2020, 2021) face an intensifying equity-efficiency tradeoff—i.e., maintaining grassroots political support while guaranteeing economic efficiency.
 
2
Political factors are likely to considerably affect the structure of tax and transfer systems in Western democracies in the coming years. For instance, two manifestations are (1) the rise of extreme right parties in the EU in the backdrop of labor migrants and concerns about the implications for the sustainability of the welfare state and (2) the debate on the desirable marginal tax rates levied on top earners during the 2020 US presidential elections (e.g., the proposals of Democratic Party candidates such as Senators Bernie Sanders and Elizabeth Warren). Some trends favor the wealthy, perhaps due to political lobbying and the role of certain die-hard constituencies. Our theoretical paper must adopt a political economy model that is tractable to a certain degree; hence we leave some of these issues unexplored.
 
3
There are some exceptions, such as the US and Israel, where citizens pay domestic income tax based on their global income.
 
4
There are other conceptual frameworks for income redistribution under electoral competition besides the citizen-candidate model adopted here, such as the conventional Downsian model and its basic variants (e.g., vote-share maximizing politicians, a winner-take-all system, competition among politicians who differ in a quality dimension, policy-motivated candidates with commitment problems, and endogenous entry of politicians). That is, politicians propose optimal income tax schedules and then citizens (voters) choose among these proposals according to their preferences. By addressing distributive politics, our paper complements those analyses (e.g., Laslier and Picard 2002; Bierbrauer and Boyer 2013, 2016).
 
5
Nonetheless, as pointed out by a referee, one cannot exclude the possibility that other factors may determine individual preferences regarding redistribution, such as political affinity with left- or right-wing policies, beliefs and representations about social mobility, fairness concerns, and natives’ attitudes towards (and perceptions of) immigration, as shown, for example, empirically by Alesina et al. (2018) and Alesina et al. (2019).
 
6
In a population with the majority consisting of “poor” individuals, Höchtl et al. (2012) experimentally find that redistribution outcomes appear as if all voters were exclusively motivated by self-interest. We therefore argue that it is somewhat reasonable to focus on selfishly optimal income taxes in the current political economy.
 
7
This paper thus provides theoretical support to the empirical finding of Jacobs et al. (2017) that all Dutch political parties give greater political weight to middle incomes than to the poor and rich.
 
8
Given that income taxation in the United States is based on citizenship rather than the residence principle, the migration elasticities of high incomes may not be that large. This prediction helps explains why effective marginal tax rates in the United States are negative for low incomes and positive for high incomes (see Congressional Budget Office 2012).
 
9
Meltzer and Richard (1981) and Hindriks and De Donder (2003) have also studied voting over selfishly optimal tax schedules, but the former focuses on linear taxes and the latter on quadratic tax schedules.
 
10
Morelli et al. (2012) and Bierbrauer et al. (2013) employ a simpler assumption, that migration costs and skill levels are independently distributed. Assuming that migration costs distribute identically and independently across skill levels, Blumkin et al. (2015) also show that migration elasticity increases with respect to an individual’s skill level, which seems to be consistent with the empirical finding of Doquier and Marfouk (2006) and Simula and Trannoy (2010) that higher-skilled individuals are more likely to migrate.
 
11
This assumption not only simplifies the theoretical derivation; it also seems to be empirically reasonable by eliminating the income effect on taxable income (e.g., Gruber and Saez 2002). Under risk-neutral preferences, c could be interpreted as a nonnegative wealth transfer from the government (or the mechanism designer).
 
12
This principle states that there is an equivalence between admissible allocations and those that are decentralizable via an income tax system.
 
13
If individual skills are drawn independently, Bierbrauer (2011) proves that the optimal sophisticated mechanism associated with strategic interdependence is a simple mechanism as long as individuals exhibit decreasing risk aversion.
 
14
Throughout, the superscripts “R” and “M” stand for Rawlsian (i.e., maxi-min) and maxi-max, respectively.
 
15
We use the superscripts “\(M*\)” and “\(R*\)” to differentiate the complete solution from that obtained under the first-order approach.
 
16
For example, if a worker proposes a schedule that causes only some types to relocate to the other jurisdiction, then those types do not have the chance to vote on this proposal. Moreover, if the schedules proposed by two different individuals result in different sets of types being residents, then it is more difficult to determine which types should be allowed to vote.
 
17
In some developed countries, immigrants, especially newcomers, cannot participate in the political process; only fully fledged citizens can participate in collective decision-making. Many countries adopt a delayed instead assimilation policy, with a minimum residency period as a prerequisite for citizenship, e.g., 3 years (Netherlands, Australia, and Canada) to 10 years (Switzerland).
 
18
These conditions relate to the following four indexes: (1) whether the ex post measure of workers of all skill levels is greater than, equal to, or smaller than the ex ante one; (2) whether the net labor inflow of skill levels below the ex ante median skill level is positive or not; (3) whether the net labor inflow of skill levels above the ex ante median skill level is positive or not; and (4) the relative magnitude of these two net labor inflows.
 
19
We use the superscript “MR” because this threshold of migration elasticity is associated with the comparison of maxi-max (i.e., “M”) and Rawlsian (i.e., “R”) marginal tax rates.
 
20
In what follows, the superscripts “I”, “O”, and “NI” stand for inflow, outflow, and net inflow, respectively.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Agranov M, Palfrey TR (2015) Equilibrium tax rates and income redistribution: a laboratory study. J Public Econ 130:45–58CrossRef Agranov M, Palfrey TR (2015) Equilibrium tax rates and income redistribution: a laboratory study. J Public Econ 130:45–58CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alesina A, Miano A, Stantcheva S (2018) Immigration and redistribution. NBER Working Paper No. 24733 Alesina A, Miano A, Stantcheva S (2018) Immigration and redistribution. NBER Working Paper No. 24733
Zurück zum Zitat Alesina A, Murard E, Rapoport H (2019) Immigration and preferences for redistribution in Europe. NBER Working Paper No. 25562 Alesina A, Murard E, Rapoport H (2019) Immigration and preferences for redistribution in Europe. NBER Working Paper No. 25562
Zurück zum Zitat Akcigit U, Baslandze S, Stantcheva S (2016) Taxation and the International Mobility of Inventors. American Economic Review 106(10):2930–2981CrossRef Akcigit U, Baslandze S, Stantcheva S (2016) Taxation and the International Mobility of Inventors. American Economic Review 106(10):2930–2981CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bierbrauer FJ (2011) On the optimality of optimal income taxation. J Econ Theory 146(5):2105–2116CrossRef Bierbrauer FJ (2011) On the optimality of optimal income taxation. J Econ Theory 146(5):2105–2116CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bierbrauer FJ, Boyer PC (2013) Political competition and mirrleesian income taxation: a first pass. J Public Econ 103:1–14CrossRef Bierbrauer FJ, Boyer PC (2013) Political competition and mirrleesian income taxation: a first pass. J Public Econ 103:1–14CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bierbrauer FJ, Boyer PC (2016) Efficiency, welfare, and political competition. Quart J Econ 131(1):461–518CrossRef Bierbrauer FJ, Boyer PC (2016) Efficiency, welfare, and political competition. Quart J Econ 131(1):461–518CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bierbrauer FJ, Brett C, Weymark JA (2013) Strategic nonlinear income tax competition with perfect labor mobility. Games Econ Behav 82:292–311CrossRef Bierbrauer FJ, Brett C, Weymark JA (2013) Strategic nonlinear income tax competition with perfect labor mobility. Games Econ Behav 82:292–311CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Black D (1948) On the rationale of group decision-making. J Polit Econ 56(1):23–34CrossRef Black D (1948) On the rationale of group decision-making. J Polit Econ 56(1):23–34CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blumkin T, Sadka E, Shem-Tov Y (2015) International tax competition: zero tax rate at the top re-established. Int Tax Public Financ 22(5):760–776CrossRef Blumkin T, Sadka E, Shem-Tov Y (2015) International tax competition: zero tax rate at the top re-established. Int Tax Public Financ 22(5):760–776CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bohn H, Stuart C (2013) Revenue extraction by median voters. Unpublished Manuscript. Department of Economics, University of California, Santa Barbara Bohn H, Stuart C (2013) Revenue extraction by median voters. Unpublished Manuscript. Department of Economics, University of California, Santa Barbara
Zurück zum Zitat Brett C (2016) Probabilistic voting over nonlinear income taxes with international migration. Unpublished Manuscript. Department of Economics, Mount Allison University Brett C (2016) Probabilistic voting over nonlinear income taxes with international migration. Unpublished Manuscript. Department of Economics, Mount Allison University
Zurück zum Zitat Brett C, Weymark JA (2011) How optimal nonlinear income taxes change when the distribution of the population changes. J Public Econ 95(11–12):1239–1247CrossRef Brett C, Weymark JA (2011) How optimal nonlinear income taxes change when the distribution of the population changes. J Public Econ 95(11–12):1239–1247CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brett C, Weymark JA (2016) Voting over selfishly optimal nonlinear income tax schedules with a minimum-utility constraint. J Math Econ 67:18–31CrossRef Brett C, Weymark JA (2016) Voting over selfishly optimal nonlinear income tax schedules with a minimum-utility constraint. J Math Econ 67:18–31CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brett C, Weymark JA (2017) Voting over selfishly optimal nonlinear income tax schedules. Games Econ Behav 101:172–188CrossRef Brett C, Weymark JA (2017) Voting over selfishly optimal nonlinear income tax schedules. Games Econ Behav 101:172–188CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brett C, Weymark JA (2020) Majority rule and selfishly optimal nonlinear income tax schedules with discrete skill levels. Soc Choice Welf 54:337–362CrossRef Brett C, Weymark JA (2020) Majority rule and selfishly optimal nonlinear income tax schedules with discrete skill levels. Soc Choice Welf 54:337–362CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Congressional Budget Office (2012) Effective Marginal Tax Rates for Low- and Moderate-Income Workers. Publication No.4149, Congressional Budget Office, Congress of the United States Congressional Budget Office (2012) Effective Marginal Tax Rates for Low- and Moderate-Income Workers. Publication No.4149, Congressional Budget Office, Congress of the United States
Zurück zum Zitat Corneo G, Neher F (2015) Democratic redistribution and rule of the majority. Eur J Polit Econ 40(Part A):96–109CrossRef Corneo G, Neher F (2015) Democratic redistribution and rule of the majority. Eur J Polit Econ 40(Part A):96–109CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cremer H, Pestieau P (1998) Social insurance, majority voting and labor mobility. J Public Econ 68(3):397–420CrossRef Cremer H, Pestieau P (1998) Social insurance, majority voting and labor mobility. J Public Econ 68(3):397–420CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dai D (2020) Voting over selfishly optimal tax schedules: can Pigouvian tax redistribute income? J Public Econ Theory 22(5):1660–1686CrossRef Dai D (2020) Voting over selfishly optimal tax schedules: can Pigouvian tax redistribute income? J Public Econ Theory 22(5):1660–1686CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dai D, Gao W, Tian G (2020) Relativity, mobility, and optimal nonlinear income taxation in an open economy. J Econ Behav Org 172(C):57–82CrossRef Dai D, Gao W, Tian G (2020) Relativity, mobility, and optimal nonlinear income taxation in an open economy. J Econ Behav Org 172(C):57–82CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Diamond P (1998) Optimal income taxation: an example with a u-shaped pattern of optimal marginal tax rates. Am Econ Rev 88(1):83–95 Diamond P (1998) Optimal income taxation: an example with a u-shaped pattern of optimal marginal tax rates. Am Econ Rev 88(1):83–95
Zurück zum Zitat Doquier F, Marfouk A (2006) International Migration by Educational Attainment (1990-2000) In: C. Ozden and M. Schiff (eds.) International Migration, Remittances and Development, Chapter 5, New York: Palgrave Macmillan Doquier F, Marfouk A (2006) International Migration by Educational Attainment (1990-2000) In: C. Ozden and M. Schiff (eds.) International Migration, Remittances and Development, Chapter 5, New York: Palgrave Macmillan
Zurück zum Zitat Gans JS, Smart M (1996) Majority voting with single-crossing preferences. J Public Econ 59(2):219–237CrossRef Gans JS, Smart M (1996) Majority voting with single-crossing preferences. J Public Econ 59(2):219–237CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gruber J, Saez E (2002) The elasticity of taxable income: evidence and implications. J Public Econ 84(1):1–32CrossRef Gruber J, Saez E (2002) The elasticity of taxable income: evidence and implications. J Public Econ 84(1):1–32CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gründler K, Köllner S (2017) Determinants of governmental redistribution: income distribution, development levels, and the role of perceptions. J Comp Econ 45(4):930–962CrossRef Gründler K, Köllner S (2017) Determinants of governmental redistribution: income distribution, development levels, and the role of perceptions. J Comp Econ 45(4):930–962CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guesnerie R (1995) A contribution to the pure theory of taxation. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef Guesnerie R (1995) A contribution to the pure theory of taxation. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hamilton J, Pestieau P (2005) Optimal income taxation and the ability distribution: implications for migration equilibria. Int Tax Public Financ 12(1):29–45CrossRef Hamilton J, Pestieau P (2005) Optimal income taxation and the ability distribution: implications for migration equilibria. Int Tax Public Financ 12(1):29–45CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hammond PJ (1979) Straightforward individual incentive compatibility in large economies. Rev Econ Stud 46(2):263–282CrossRef Hammond PJ (1979) Straightforward individual incentive compatibility in large economies. Rev Econ Stud 46(2):263–282CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hindriks J (2001) Mobility and redistributive politics. J Public Econ Theory 3(1):95–120CrossRef Hindriks J (2001) Mobility and redistributive politics. J Public Econ Theory 3(1):95–120CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hindriks J, De Donder P (2003) The politics of progressive income taxation with incentive effects. J Public Econ 87(11):2491–2505CrossRef Hindriks J, De Donder P (2003) The politics of progressive income taxation with incentive effects. J Public Econ 87(11):2491–2505CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Höchtl W, Sausgruber R, Tyran J-R (2012) Inequality Aversion and Voting on Redistribution. Eur Econ Rev 56(7):1406–1421CrossRef Höchtl W, Sausgruber R, Tyran J-R (2012) Inequality Aversion and Voting on Redistribution. Eur Econ Rev 56(7):1406–1421CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Huang KXD, Liu Z, Tian G (2020) Promote competitive neutrality to facilitate china’s economic development: outlook, policy simulations, and reform implementation-a summary of the annual SUFE macroeconomic report (2019–2020). Front Econ Chin 15(1):1–24 Huang KXD, Liu Z, Tian G (2020) Promote competitive neutrality to facilitate china’s economic development: outlook, policy simulations, and reform implementation-a summary of the annual SUFE macroeconomic report (2019–2020). Front Econ Chin 15(1):1–24
Zurück zum Zitat Huang KXD, Li S, Tian G (2021) Chinese Economy under the New “Dual Circulation” strategy: challenges and opportunities - a summary of the annual SUFE macroeconomic report (2020–2021). Front Econ Chin 16(1):1–29 Huang KXD, Li S, Tian G (2021) Chinese Economy under the New “Dual Circulation” strategy: challenges and opportunities - a summary of the annual SUFE macroeconomic report (2020–2021). Front Econ Chin 16(1):1–29
Zurück zum Zitat Jacobs B, Jongen ELW, Zoutman FT (2017) Revealed social preferences of dutch political parties. J Public Econ 156(C):81–100CrossRef Jacobs B, Jongen ELW, Zoutman FT (2017) Revealed social preferences of dutch political parties. J Public Econ 156(C):81–100CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kleven HJ, Landais C, Saez E (2013) Taxation and international migration of superstars: evidence from the European football market. Am Econ Rev 103(5):1892–1924CrossRef Kleven HJ, Landais C, Saez E (2013) Taxation and international migration of superstars: evidence from the European football market. Am Econ Rev 103(5):1892–1924CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kleven HJ, Landais C, Saez E, Schultz E (2014) Migration and wage effects of taxing top earners: evidence from the Foreigners’ tax scheme in Denmark. Quart J Econ 129(1):333–378CrossRef Kleven HJ, Landais C, Saez E, Schultz E (2014) Migration and wage effects of taxing top earners: evidence from the Foreigners’ tax scheme in Denmark. Quart J Econ 129(1):333–378CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Laslier J, Picard N (2002) Distributive politics and electoral competition. J Econ Theory 103(1):106–130CrossRef Laslier J, Picard N (2002) Distributive politics and electoral competition. J Econ Theory 103(1):106–130CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lehmann E, Simula L, Trannoy A (2014) Tax Me If You Can! Optimal nonlinear income tax between competing governments. Quart J Econ 129(4):1995–2030CrossRef Lehmann E, Simula L, Trannoy A (2014) Tax Me If You Can! Optimal nonlinear income tax between competing governments. Quart J Econ 129(4):1995–2030CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leite-Monteiro M (1997) Redistributive policy with labour mobility across countries. J Public Econ 65(2):229–244CrossRef Leite-Monteiro M (1997) Redistributive policy with labour mobility across countries. J Public Econ 65(2):229–244CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Meltzer AH, Richard SF (1981) A rational theory of the size of government. J Polit Econ 89(5):914–927CrossRef Meltzer AH, Richard SF (1981) A rational theory of the size of government. J Polit Econ 89(5):914–927CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mirrlees JA (1971) An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation. Rev Econ Stud 38(2):175–208CrossRef Mirrlees JA (1971) An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation. Rev Econ Stud 38(2):175–208CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mirrlees JA (1982) Migration and optimal income taxes. J Public Econ 18(3):319–341CrossRef Mirrlees JA (1982) Migration and optimal income taxes. J Public Econ 18(3):319–341CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Morelli M, Yang H, Ye L (2012) Competitive nonlinear taxation and constitutional choice. Am Econ J: Microecon 4(1):142–175 Morelli M, Yang H, Ye L (2012) Competitive nonlinear taxation and constitutional choice. Am Econ J: Microecon 4(1):142–175
Zurück zum Zitat Piketty T (2014) Capital in the twenty-first century. Belknap Press, Cambridge, MACrossRef Piketty T (2014) Capital in the twenty-first century. Belknap Press, Cambridge, MACrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Piketty T, Saez E (2013) Optimal Labor Income Taxation. In Chapter 7 of Handbook of Public Economics 5:391–474 Piketty T, Saez E (2013) Optimal Labor Income Taxation. In Chapter 7 of Handbook of Public Economics 5:391–474
Zurück zum Zitat Roberts KWS (1977) Voting over income tax schedules. J Public Econ 8(3):329–340CrossRef Roberts KWS (1977) Voting over income tax schedules. J Public Econ 8(3):329–340CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Röell AA (2012) Voting over Nonlinear Income Tax Schedules. Unpublised Manuscript, School of International and Public Affairs, Columbia University Röell AA (2012) Voting over Nonlinear Income Tax Schedules. Unpublised Manuscript, School of International and Public Affairs, Columbia University
Zurück zum Zitat Simula L, Trannoy A (2010) Optimal income tax under the threat of migration by top-income earners. J Public Econ 94(1–2):163–173CrossRef Simula L, Trannoy A (2010) Optimal income tax under the threat of migration by top-income earners. J Public Econ 94(1–2):163–173CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Simula L, Trannoy A (2012) Shall we keep the highly skilled at home? the optimal income tax perspective. Soc Choice Welf 39(4):751–782CrossRef Simula L, Trannoy A (2012) Shall we keep the highly skilled at home? the optimal income tax perspective. Soc Choice Welf 39(4):751–782CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stigler GJ (1957) The tenable range of functions of local government. In: Federal Expenditure Policy for Economic Growth and Stability: Papers Submitted by Panelists Appearing Before the Subcommittee on Fiscal Policy. Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the U.S. Washington Stigler GJ (1957) The tenable range of functions of local government. In: Federal Expenditure Policy for Economic Growth and Stability: Papers Submitted by Panelists Appearing Before the Subcommittee on Fiscal Policy. Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the U.S. Washington
Zurück zum Zitat Stigler GJ (1970) Director’s law of public income redistribution. J Law Econ 13(1):1–10CrossRef Stigler GJ (1970) Director’s law of public income redistribution. J Law Econ 13(1):1–10CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Topkis DM (1978) Minimizing a submodular function on a lattice. Oper Res 26(2):305–321CrossRef Topkis DM (1978) Minimizing a submodular function on a lattice. Oper Res 26(2):305–321CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Voting over selfishly optimal income tax schedules with tax-driven migrations
verfasst von
Darong Dai
Guoqiang Tian
Publikationsdatum
26.09.2021
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Social Choice and Welfare / Ausgabe 1-2/2023
Print ISSN: 0176-1714
Elektronische ISSN: 1432-217X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-021-01366-3

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1-2/2023

Social Choice and Welfare 1-2/2023 Zur Ausgabe