Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Journal of Economic Structures 1/2017

Open Access 01.12.2017 | Research

What has China learned from processing trade?

verfasst von: Bawoo Kim

Erschienen in: Journal of Economic Structures | Ausgabe 1/2017

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Processing trade in China has been prevalent, despite rapid economic growth and consequent structural changes. This study examines the role of the processing trade, especially as it relates to exports productivity and export variety. Our model predicts that high productivity of processing exports, which can be characterized by leverage and coverage, may enhance the productivity of the sector. An empirical analysis gives firm support to the model. It also shows a learning effect of processing exports to the productivity of ordinary exports.

1 Introduction

Chinese exports in early 1990s were specialized in labor-intensive products (Lardy 1994), as classical theory would predict. From the 1990s, the utilization of processing trade and special economic zones attracted a vast amount of foreign direct investment (FDI) and reformed export structures. ICT products, such as smartphone or laptop computer, are their representative export products now. This can be explained in the realm of new trade theory, which emphasizes the importance of product differentiation, economies of scale, and firm heterogeneity (Dixit and Norman 1980; Melitz 2003). Factor mobility and economies of scale allow China to produce almost any kind of product in the world. The biggest obstacle to China, faced with the reality of being a leading manufacturing center, is a lack of accumulated technology. FDI and consequent production activity captured by processing trade may enhance overall productivity through technology transfer and knowledge spillover. If there were no experience in the manufacturing of smartphones under provision of foreign companies, for example, China would not be able to have the original brands it has now.
Rodrik (2006) claims that China has achieved a significantly higher level of sophistication compared to other developing economies. This is due to foreign enterprises and processed exports (Xu and Lu 2009). Schott (2008) finds a higher unit value of processing trade than others.
Despite the facilitative effect and the contribution to trade stability (Fernandes and Tang 2015), there is another strand of the literature insisting on the inefficiency of processing trade compared with ordinary trade. Joining firm balance sheet data and trade data, Dai et al. (2016) argue for relatively low total factor productivity (TFP) of processing trade. Manova and Yu (2016) also point out the low profitability of processing trade measured by value added. Koopman et al. (2008) develop a calculating method for foreign shares in exports of China in support of the low profitability of processing trade.
There has been less interest in the external effects of processing trade. The literature emphasizing the low profitability of processing trade often ignores knowledge transfer from foreign enterprises and the positive externalities of processing trade. There has been less attention to the factors of processing export productivity. We will fill these gaps by investigating productivities reflected in the export basket and its interactions.
Before the investigation, we first check the stylized facts about processing trade. And we adopt the model developed by Hausmann et al. (2007), which relies on cost discovery externality. Hausman and Rodrik (2003) claim discovering costs of domestic production activities has great social externality in developing countries.
In our modified setting, entrepreneurs can achieve higher level of productivity on average by using processing trade. As in Hausmann et al. (2007), an entrepreneur can choose between imitation and self-discovery. However, individual productivity accounts into the final output even if he did an imitation. Imitation outputs are varying over individual. Also, individuals can choose another option of processing trade which guarantees a fixed outcome but also entails some uncertainty. The model predicts that overall productivity can be enhanced with processing trade in terms of average. Also, processing trade can affect the future by shifting frontier entrepreneurs’ productivity in some cases. The model implies that the high productivity of processing exports may have effects on the productivity of ordinary exports.
This research relates to the literature of processing trade in China since it shares a similar dataset (Schott 2008; Fernandes and Tang 2015; Manova and Yu 2016). Our approach is unique in emphasizing the role of the productivity gap in productivity catch-up. Also, there is another related strand of the literature on export sophistication and economic growth. Though our scope does not include economic growth, the base philosophy that “what a country exports matters (Hausmann et al. 2007)” is the same. In contrast to the majority of this literature, we refine manufacturing down to hundreds of subsectors to analyze the interaction of enterprises.
The remainder of this paper will be organized as follows. Section 2 provides background with a theoretic framework. In Sect. 3, we present the empirical analysis. Concluding remarks may be found in Sect. 4.

2 Background

In this section, we will briefly see the characteristics of processing trade in China and will introduce a theoretic framework for examining the overall effect of processing trade on overall productivity.

2.1 Stylized facts about processing trade

2.1.1 Processing trade and foreign enterprises in China

First, we define “processing trade” by regime of trade. China Customs classifies each type of trade into 19 regimes (or modes) by its nature. There are two important regimes of processing trade: processing and assembling trade with customer-supplied materials and processing trade with imported materials. In the first case, most processing firms in China hardly manage their profit levels because their only added value, processing fees, is determined by ordering organizations outside of China. As for a firm in the second case, a processing firm can handle their profits by choosing trading partners. Ordinary trade is the opposite concept to processing trade. Table 1 shows a distribution of trade of China by trade regimes and type of enterprises. As shown in Table 1, the three regimes account for about 87% of total trade in 2014. Other regimes will be omitted as we cannot access detailed information about the processing. China Customs also compiles the trade statistics by 8 types of enterprise. In this paper, “foreign enterprise” is defined as all types of enterprise with foreign capital.1
Table 1
Composition of China’s trade by trade mode and type of enterprise (2014).
Source: China Customs
 
State owned enterprises
Foreign enterprises
Privately owned enterprises
Other
Total
China–foreign joint ventures
Wholly owned foreign enterprises
Ordinary trade
12.5
6.2
9.2
23.1
2.8
53.8
Processing and assembling trade with customer-supplied materials
1.0
0.7
2.0
0.5
0.2
4.4
Processing trade with imported materials
1.1
5.8
17.4
3.2
0.8
28.4
Inbound/outbound goods in bonded warehouses
1.3
0.7
0.3
1.3
0.1
3.6
Storage of transit goods in bonded warehouses
0.9
0.6
2.7
2.7
0.0
6.9
Others
0.6
0.2
0.2
1.9
0.0
3.0
Total
17.4
14.3
31.9
32.6
3.9
100.0
Unit: percent
Not surprisingly, foreign enterprises conducted about 80% of processing trade in 2014. Wholly owned foreign enterprises are more likely to concentrate on processing trade with imported materials. Privately owned enterprises contribute only 11.1% of processing trade, while their contribution to ordinary trade is 43%. Also, the three regimes mentioned before account for 86.5% of total trade.
Inward foreign direct investment in China is believed to promote manufacturing export performance (Zhang and Felmingham 2001; Long 2005; Zhang 2015). Figure 1 shows a positive relationship between FDI stock and processing export performance.

2.1.2 Role in trade balance, structural characteristics

The share of processing trade in total trade is gradually decreasing due to the emergence of ordinary trade. However, its importance in the balance of trade has been maintained. Figure 2 shows that trade surplus from processing trade overtook the total trade surplus in most of the time. The demand-driven nature of processing trade allows processing firms to take less risk than other firms.
Structurally, processing trade is concentrated on a few products and is different from ordinary trade as depicted in Fig. 3. Over 65% of processing trade falls into the category of “Machinery and transport equipment (SITC 7),” which requires more technology than the others. Also, 19 out of 5200 Harmonized System 6-digit products account for half of total trade, while 171 products take the same share in ordinary trade.
To summarize, most processing trade is related to foreign enterprises and their home countries. The role of processing trade in the balance of trade is substantial, though its composition is highly concentrated on specific sectors and commodities.

2.2 A simple model: Hausmann et al. (2007) revisited

In this section, we bring a simple model modified from Hausmann et al. (2007) in order to see the effects of processing trade on the productivity of the Chinese economy. Following the original model, all production activities can be divided into two sectors: the traditional and the modern sector. In the traditional sector, there is no uncertainty to entrepreneurs, while the entrepreneurs in the modern sector face cost uncertainty. In other words, in the traditional sector, outcomes are homogeneous and individual productivity does not affect to the output. But, in the modern sector, individual productivity matters since there should be some discovery procedure to produce a new good. The traditional sector only work for clearing wage level. Thus, we concentrate on the modern sector.
Let \(N = \left\{ {1,2,3, \ldots } \right\}\) be a (finite or infinite) universe of all potential varieties that a country can produce in the modern sector. Unit price of all goods is same, and each good only can be distinguished by its required productivity of production. A function \(\theta\) maps each good in \(N\) into the closed nonnegative interval \(\left[ {0,h} \right]\) which called “the production space” in Hausmann et al. (2007). \(h\) means the upper bound of productivity. The required productivity level for \(i\), denoted by \(\theta_{i}\), can identify good inversely. Thus, \(\theta\) is injective but not surjective.
Let assume marginal cost for production of good \(i\) is given as follows:
$$c_{i} = \frac{b}{{\theta_{i} }}w$$
(1)
where \(\frac{b}{{\theta_{i} }}\) is the number of labor force and \(w\) is the wage. Even if there exist two goods, let us say good 1 and good 2, identical to every consumer, they are heterogeneously identified in our model as \(\theta_{1} \ne \theta_{2}\). A good only can be produced by entrepreneurs with appropriate productivity. Each entrepreneur (investor) has intrinsic level of productivity but never know before it discovered. Let \(M = \left\{ {1,2, \ldots ,m} \right\}\) be the finite set of entrepreneurs in a country. They are potential exporters who can be characterized by their productivity. Different from the map \(\theta\) given as a state-of-nature, a productivity of investor is given by probability distribution. Suppose investor \(j\) decided to enter the market. His own (potential) productivity \(\theta_{j}\) is revealed soon after his fixed cost sunk. For convenience, we assume the distribution of productivity is uniform in \(\left[ {0,h} \right]\).
Let assume \(m_{t}\) numbers of entrepreneurs invest to the modern sector at time \(t\). At the time \(t\), their fixed cost sunk and they do not know their available outcomes because they do not know their productivity. At the beginning of time \(t + 1\), individual \(j\) knows his productivity \(\theta_{j}\). Naturally he will stick with the best project (product) that he can afford. Thus, his output is also identified with his productivity. Without loss of generality, exit cases of investors are ruled out in our model.
We will distinguish \(\hat{\theta }_{j}\), productivity of “realized” outcome of \(j\), and \(\theta_{j}\) since we allow imitation. In the early version of the model (Hausman and Rodrik 2003) assumes that it is possible to imitate all products perfectly. Hausmann et al. (2007) adopt imperfect imitation which depends on the maximum level of revealed productivity in an economy. Both allow that any follower can imitate former product regardless of his original productivity. However, intrinsic productivity matters even for simple imitation in the real world. We assume each investor who engaged at time \(t\) will face two choices at the beginning of time \(t + 1\). And his outcome depends on his own productivity. Then, the revealed productivity of \(j\) can be expressed as follows.
$$\hat{\theta }_{j} = { \hbox{max} }\left\{ {\alpha \theta_{j} + \beta , \theta_{j} } \right\}$$
(2)
In (2), we assume a discount parameter of imitation \(\alpha\) lays in \(\left[ {0,1} \right)\) and every imitation gives a constant level of outcome represented by \(\beta\). Naturally, \(\beta \in \left( {0,h} \right)\). Figure 4 shows how production frontier changes by imitation. One can think \(\alpha\) and \(\beta\) are positively associated with maximum level of revealed productivity, \(\widehat{\theta _{\hbox{max} }}\) of the economy. Hausmann et al. (2007) assume \(\alpha = 0\) and \(\beta\) is strictly increasing in \(\widehat{\theta _{\hbox{max} }}\). We simply assume \(\beta\) is non-decreasing in \(\widehat{\theta _{\hbox{max} }}\).
Overall revealed productivity level of an economy is as follows:
$$E\left( {\hat{\theta }} \right) = {\text{Prob}}\left( {\theta_{j} \ge \tilde{\theta }_{1} } \right)E\left( {\hat{\theta } |\theta_{j} \ge \tilde{\theta }_{1} } \right) + {\text{Prob}}\left( {\theta_{j} < \tilde{\theta }_{1} } \right)E\left( {\hat{\theta } |\theta_{j} < \tilde{\theta }_{1} } \right)$$
(3)
$$\begin{aligned} E\left( {\hat{\theta }} \right) = \frac{{\tilde{\theta }_{1} }}{h}\frac{{\beta + \tilde{\theta }_{1} }}{2} + \frac{{h - \tilde{\theta }_{1} }}{h}\frac{{\tilde{\theta }_{1} + h}}{2} = \frac{h}{2} + \underbrace {{\frac{{\beta^{2} }}{{2h\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)}}}}_{{}} \hfill \\ \quad \quad \quad {\text{additional productivity acquired by imitation}} \hfill \\ \end{aligned}$$
(4)
where \(\tilde{\theta }_{1} = \frac{\beta }{1 - \alpha }\).
Note that additional productivity from imitation does not affect the maximum productivity \(\widehat{\theta _{\hbox{max} }}\) directly. Now we introduce another imitation “processing trade.” Every processing trade has a relationship with foreign affiliates. It is risky business compared with local imitations. Similar to the case for local imitation, we assume investor \(j\) who engaged in processing trade will get his outcome \(\alpha^{\prime}\theta_{j} + \beta^{\prime}\) and the fixed outcome \(\beta^{\prime}\) is smaller than \(\beta\). We can expect that \(\alpha^{\prime}\) and \(\beta^{\prime}\) are much related to outside of the country, so those are set exogenously in the model. In Fig. 5, the production frontier changed compared to Fig. 4.
Hypothesis 1
The productivity level of processing firms reflected in the export basket will be higher than the local imitators but lower than local frontiers. In formula, \(\beta^{\prime} < \beta\) and \(\alpha^{\prime} < 1\).
Set \(\tilde{\theta }_{2} = \frac{{\beta^{\prime}}}{{1 - \alpha^{\prime}}}\) and \(\tilde{\theta }_{3} = \frac{{\beta^{\prime} - \beta }}{{\alpha - \alpha^{\prime}}}\); then, we can get expected productivity of an economy as follows:
$$E\left( {\hat{\theta }} \right) = {\text{Prob}}\left( {\theta_{j} \ge \tilde{\theta }_{2} } \right)E\left( {\hat{\theta } |\theta_{j} \ge \tilde{\theta }_{2} } \right) + {\text{Prob}}\left( {\theta_{j} \in \left[ {\tilde{\theta }_{3} ,\tilde{\theta }_{2} } \right)} \right)E\left( {\hat{\theta } |\theta_{j} \in \left[ {\tilde{\theta }_{3} ,\tilde{\theta }_{2} } \right)} \right) + Prob\left( {\theta_{j} < \tilde{\theta }_{3} } \right)E\left( {\hat{\theta } |\theta_{j} < \tilde{\theta }_{3} } \right)$$
(5)
$$E\left( {\hat{\theta }} \right) = \frac{{\tilde{\theta }_{3} }}{h}\frac{{\beta + \left( {\beta + \alpha \tilde{\theta }_{3} } \right)}}{2} + \frac{{\tilde{\theta }_{2} - \tilde{\theta }_{3} }}{h}\frac{{\alpha^{\prime}\left( {\tilde{\theta }_{3} + \tilde{\theta }_{2} } \right) + 2\beta '}}{2} + \frac{{h - \tilde{\theta }_{2} }}{h}\frac{{\tilde{\theta }_{2} + h}}{2}.$$
(6)
Subtracting (4) from (6) gives the additional productivity from processing trade as follows:
$$\frac{1}{2}\underbrace {{\left( {\left( {1 - \alpha^{\prime}} \right)\tilde{\theta }_{3} - \beta^{\prime}} \right)}}_{\text{I}}\underbrace {{\left( {\tilde{\theta }_{1} - \tilde{\theta }_{2} } \right)}}_{\text{II}}$$
(7)
Notice term \({\text{I}}\) and \({\text{II}}\) are always negative by definitions. Thus, the model states that the additional (average) productivity gain from conducting processing trade depends on its size of leverage (\({\text{I}}\)) and coverage (\({\text{II}}\)).
Hypothesis 2
The share of processing trade decided leverage and coverage of processing trade. In other words, share of processing trade will be large if the level of productivity achievable by processing trade is relatively high or the productivity coverage of processing trade is wide.
Does processing trade not affect to the productivity of local firms? No, it is also possible by shifting \(\beta\). Let \(F\left( {\hat{\theta }} \right)\) and \(F^{\prime}\left( {\hat{\theta }} \right)\) be the cumulative distribution of \(\hat{\theta }\) without/with processing trade, respectively. Then \(F^{\prime}\left( {\hat{\theta }} \right)\) first-order stochastically dominates \(F\left( {\hat{\theta }} \right)\) as the additional term (7) is nonzero. Thanks to the theorem of maximum of independent and identically distributed random variables, the cumulative distribution function of \(\widehat{\theta_{\hbox{max} } }\) is a permutation of individual cumulative distributions. It suffices to state that expected maximum productivity \(\widehat{\theta_{\hbox{max} } }\) with processing trade always dominates the opposite case. Thus, productivity of local firms will be affected by processing trade especially in terms of catch-up.
Hypothesis 3
Experience of processing exports will facilitate the productivity catch-up of ordinary exports.

3 Empirics

3.1 Definitions, data, and methods

3.1.1 Definition of PRODY and EXPY

We adopt an index called EXPY (Hausmann et al. 2007) as a proxy variable for measuring average \(\hat{\theta }\), a revealed productivity of a country. The underlying idea and construction of the index are as follows. We assume that rich countries export more sophisticated (productive) products than others. Each product can be ranked by average wealth of exporting countries. First, we construct a product-wise index by calculating average per capita GDP of exporting countries. For a given commodity, a value share of a country divided by the sum of value share of all countries can represent a revealed comparative advantage2 of the country in the commodity market. Weighted according to comparative advantage, we can calculate the average per capita GDP by product, called PRODY. In a formula, it can be expressed as:
$${\text{PRODY}}_{i} = \mathop \sum \limits_{\text{c}} \left( {\frac{{x_{{i{\text{c}}}} /X_{\text{c}} }}{{\mathop \sum \nolimits_{\text{c}} \left( {\frac{{x_{{i{\text{c}}}} }}{{X_{c} }}} \right)}}{\text{GDP}}_{\text{c}} } \right)$$
(8)
where \(x_{{i{\text{c}}}}\): export of good \(i\) of country \({\text{c}}\), \(X_{\text{c}}\): total export of country \({\text{c}}\).
Now we define productivity level associated with the export variety of a country as:
$${\text{EXPY}}_{\text{c}} = \mathop \sum \limits_{i} \left( {\frac{{x_{{i{\text{c}}}} }}{{X_{i} }}{\text{PRODY}}_{i} } \right).$$
(9)
Typically, firms with high productivity export. In Hausmann et al. (2007), EXPY is used as a proxy of \(\widehat{\theta _{\hbox{max} }}\). We use as the proxy of \(\hat{\theta }\), because in our setting, every investor is exporter. Also productivity varies over firms and sectors.
We apply EXPY by trade regimes and subsectors. Since there is no discrimination of consumers’ preference for the trade regime, we assume that each commodity has unique PRODY at the same time. By confining the range of EXPY, we can calculate an average productivity of processing or non-processing firms in a given sector.

3.1.2 Data and methods

In this study, all trade data are based on the Harmonized System 6-digit level and a time span of 9 years between 2007 and 2015. The Harmonized System has been revised every 4 or 5 years by the World Customs Organization, and each revision follows different nomenclature systems. We combined data under the 3rd revision (2007–2011) and the 4th revision (2012–2015). Data with invalid nomenclature are eliminated to maintain the consistency of product codes across countries. The trade data for this study come from various sources. The first is UN COMTRADE. Trade data from China with trade regimes and types of enterprise are from China Customs. Since UN COMTRADE data are missing for Taiwan and Korea, we fill the gaps with data from Trade Map and Korea Customs. And data from Macau are deleted in the full set since it distorts PRODY and EXPY.
In using trade statistics, any trade flow is measured by the import and the export country. Choosing import statistics is more common for analyses because of the relation with tariffs. However, we will use some export statistics together with import statistics to utilize the China trade statistics with extra information about trade regime and type of enterprise. To calculate PRODY and EXPY, along with trade data, real GDP per capita data from Penn World Table 9.0 database was used. All values of trade data were measured in current US dollars and GDP is PPP-adjusted at 2011 US dollars (Table 1).
Classifications of trade statistics divide broadly into two categories: product- and industry-based. They have different origins and most trade statistics are product-based. Industry-based classifications are advantageous in analyzing interactions within industries. However, industry classifications such as the International Standard Industry Classification do not have a direct concordance to the Harmonized System. The Central Product Classification can bridge these two, but with many \(n:n\) correlations. Therefore, we divide the modern sector into subsectors by using a product-based classification. Specifically, the first three digit codes of the Standard International Trade Classification revision 3 are considered as a subsector since they have roots in the Harmonized System, but are time-consistent over our time span. There are 262 subsectors in total, and each subsector comprises 20 Harmonized System 6-digit products on average.

3.2 Static analysis

Table 2 shows some descriptive statistics of EXPY. China’s productivity level has been gradually increased, similar to the world mean.3 When it comes to the relative position, the famous argument of Rodrik (2006), “China is special,” still looks valid. Figure 6 shows China’s high EXPY conditional on the income level. However, as in Xu and Lu (2009), the consideration of trade regimes alleviates deviation of China’s EXPY from the conditional mean. We observe persistent gaps between processing and ordinary exports. China exports more sophisticated products by processing exports. Also, between processing and ordinary exports, there is not a significant difference of shares in total exports.
Table 2
Descriptive statistics of EXPY.
Source: Author’s calculation
World
China
 
Year
Mean EXPY
Min EXPY
Max EXPY
Obs
EXPY: total export
EXPY: ordinary export (A)
EXPY: processing export (B)
Gap (B − A)
Share of processing export (%)
2007
25,360
6530
44,858
78
27,671
25,485
29,505
4020
53.4
2008
20,355
4924
42,196
111
25,187
23,415
27,097
3682
50.5
2009
18,860
4180
38,299
133
23,121
20,987
25,052
4065
52.6
2010
17,899
2150
39,345
139
23,815
21,727
25,808
4081
50.7
2011
19,856
2331
65,192
139
24,844
22,807
27,017
4210
47.7
2012
25,239
11,431
46,066
96
27,696
26,020
29,226
3206
46.6
2013
25,662
8827
67,212
112
27,092
25,250
28,634
3384
44.1
2014
24,203
6674
72,871
122
27,276
25,869
28,631
2762
42.4
2015
25,684
7068
84,839
97
28,519
26,708
30,770
4062
39.5
Simple mathematics can prove the equivalence of Mean EXPY and MEAN GDP
Strikingly, share of processing trade in Fig. 7 varies over industries and its distribution over EXPY is inversed U-shaped. In other words, share of processing trade is low in the top- and the bottom-level goods. This supports our first hypothesis and Fig. 5 which guesses processing trade will work for entrepreneurs with intermediate level of productivity.
The competitiveness of a sector relates to productivity and capabilities. If non-processing firms in a sector are competitive, processing firms are likely to attain high productivity since they might access production factors more easily: skilled workers, quality intermediate goods, infrastructure, institutional supports, etc. But our second hypothesis claims a slightly different side.
The model predicts a low productivity of ordinary exports, far from the processing exports, will generate a leverage (or an incentive) of processing trade. Leverage and coverage are divided mathematically in the formula (7). But there is a positive correlation between two if we consider \(\alpha '\) as a constant. Since a coverage is hard to measure, only EXPY ratio (\({\text{EXPY}}^{\text{processing}} /{\text{EXPY}}^{\text{ordinary}}\)) is accounted to verify the second hypothesis. To control the overall productivity and related environments, sectoral EXPY and RCA of ordinary exports were included in regressions.
Table 3 shows regressions in which the share of and processing exports is regressed on the ratio and other regressors. We show both OLS and FE results since Hausman tests point out a systematic difference in coefficients in all the regressions. Ratio enters with a positive coefficient that is statistically significant in all FE specifications. The estimated coefficient is distributed between 0.034 and 0.054. This result implies that there is a positive relationship between relative productivity of processing export and share of processing exports.
Table 3
Share of processing exports in total exports—OLS and FE estimates
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
Dependent variable: share of processing exports in total exports
OLS
OLS
OLS
FE
FE
FE
Ratio
−0.021
−0.080
−0.025
0.034
0.052
0.045
(0.66)
(2.59)**
(0.81)
(2.11)*
(3.52)**
(2.91)**
EXPY
0.152
 
0.140
−0.015
 
−0.018
(8.60)**
 
(7.92)**
(1.19)
 
(1.48)
RCA
 
−0.012
−0.010
 
−0.062
−0.062
 
(7.30)**
(6.49)**
 
(11.18)**
(11.21)**
Constant
−1.214
0.400
−1.065
0.413
0.344
0.529
(6.45)**
(12.31)**
(5.67)**
(3.16)**
(19.88)**
(4.18)**
R 2
0.04
0.03
0.06
0.00
0.07
0.08
N
1868
1868
1868
1868
1868
1868
p < 0.05; ** p < 0.01
Productivity of ordinary export is a significant factor only in OLS classifications. A high RCA of ordinary export was a negative factor in all specifications. Those observations imply that when China has a large export market for their ordinary exports, share of processing export will be relatively low.
It is interesting to see that \({\text{EXPY}}\) turned out not to be that significant. Intuitively, a frontier ordinary exporter may shift the overall level of productivity. But in case of China, regional difference may hamper dispersion of cost discoveries.

3.3 What has China learned from processing trade?

By proving Hypotheses 1 and 2, we show that the productivity of processing exports is systematically higher than that of ordinary exports. The gap is large when the productivity of ordinary exports is lower than the world average.
Hypothesis 3 addresses the learning effect from processing exports on ordinary exports. To test the hypothesis, we set \({\text{EXPY}}_{t}^{\text{ordinary}}\) as our dependent variable. All regressions in Table 4 include the lagged difference \({\text{EXPY}}_{t}^{\text{processing}} - {\text{EXPY}}_{t}^{\text{ordinary}}\) as a covariate. This difference can be interpreted a quality gap. If this quality gap positively affects the productivity of ordinary exports in dynamics, the higher productivity of processing firms transfers to other firms in the sector. Regressions selectively include lagged value of processing or ordinary exports, or both. These variables can be understood as measures of quantitative experience. We expect positive signs for all regressors. As our variables have an intrinsic autoregressive data generating process, we use GMM (Arellano Bond estimator) for panel regression. For a robustness check, we also conducted OLS and FE.
Table 4
China’s productivity of ordinary export—OLS, FE, and GMM estimates
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
Dependent variable: China’s EXPY of ordinary export
OLS
OLS
FE
FE
GMM
GMM
L(agged). dependent var.
0.890
0.887
0.087
0.085
0.257
0.252
(72.31)**
(71.49)**
(3.28)**
(3.19)**
(2.22)*
(2.14)*
L. productivity gap
0.095
0.099
0.015
0.015
0.307
0.305
(4.72)**
(4.88)**
(0.53)
(0.56)
(3.08)**
(3.06)**
L. processing export
66.793
126.091
233.496
226.898
309.905
305.111
(2.15)*
(2.97)**
(2.16)*
(2.10)*
(0.89)
(0.88)
L. ordinary export
 
−119.104
 
−198.345
 
22.301
 
(2.05)*
 
(1.17)
 
(0.05)
Constant
1516.113
2460.343
22,579.408
25,556.789
  
(3.03)**
(3.62)**
(14.55)**
(8.56)**
  
R 2
0.79
0.79
0.46
0.46
0.38
0.25
N
1663
1663
1663
1663
1435
1435
p < 0.05; ** p < 0.01
As expected, the productivity gap becomes significant in all regressions. Especially in the GMM setting, the size of coefficients is bigger than in the other regressions, suggesting that the higher productivity of processing exports is pulling the productivity of ordinary exports with a time lag. The quantitative variables of export experience are not consistently significant. The lagged value of processing exports is significant in OLS and fixed-effect setting, but not in GMM.

4 Concluding remarks

Our model reconciles contrary arguments about processing trade. Firms engaged in processing trade are not a pioneer. Since we cannot consider allocation of profit, their “real” productivity measured by value added may be lower. However, their productivity measured by sophistication level of their exporting product is systemically higher than the others. If doing a processing trade is better to the entrepreneurs in terms of productivity, processing trade can enhance overall productivity of the economy simultaneously. Also, processing trade entails a learning effect by changing the maximum productivity of a sector.
Although many papers point out the profitability of processing trade, processing firms indeed contribute productivity enhancement in the industry by knowledge spillover. Despite the rapid growth of labor costs, processing trade in China has maintained its volume. More than its volume, “what exports by which regime” is now important for making appropriate trade policies.

Acknowledgements

Not applicable.

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Availability of data and materials

Trade data from UN COMTRADE are publicly available at https://​comtrade.​un.​org/​or http://​wits.​worldbank.​org. Chinese trade data are not open to the public. You may purchase the data from authorized dealers from China Customs. For further information, contact directly to the author.

Funding

Not applicable.

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Open AccessThis article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.
Fußnoten
1
China–foreign contractual joint ventures, China–foreign equity joint ventures, and foreign wholly owned enterprises.
 
2
This is a bit different from the Revealed Comparative Advantage index proposed by Balassa (1965).
 
3
The years between 2007 and 2012 have fewer observations due to data availability. In those years, a revision of the Harmonized System was newly enforced in the relevant countries. Adopting a new system entails a lack of time occasionally since each country should change its own tariff lines conforming to the new Harmonized System. Thus, there is a systematic bias caused by omission of low-income countries for those years. Since there is a correlation between ranges of reporting countries and observed one, level-based interpretation should be excluded.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Balassa B (1965) Trade liberalisation and “revealed” comparative advantage. Manchester Sch 33(2):99–123CrossRef Balassa B (1965) Trade liberalisation and “revealed” comparative advantage. Manchester Sch 33(2):99–123CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dai M, Maitra M, Yu M (2016) Unexceptional exporter performance in China? The role of processing trade. J Dev Econ 121:177–189CrossRef Dai M, Maitra M, Yu M (2016) Unexceptional exporter performance in China? The role of processing trade. J Dev Econ 121:177–189CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dixit A, Norman V (1980) Theory of international trade: a dual, general equilibrium approach. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef Dixit A, Norman V (1980) Theory of international trade: a dual, general equilibrium approach. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fernandes AP, Tang H (2015) Scale, scope, and trade dynamics of export processing plants. Econom Lett 133:68–72CrossRef Fernandes AP, Tang H (2015) Scale, scope, and trade dynamics of export processing plants. Econom Lett 133:68–72CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hausman R, Rodrik D (2003) Economic development as self-discovery. J Dev Econ 72(2):603–633CrossRef Hausman R, Rodrik D (2003) Economic development as self-discovery. J Dev Econ 72(2):603–633CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hausmann R, Hwang J, Rodrik D (2007) What you export matters. J Econ Growth 12(1):1–25CrossRef Hausmann R, Hwang J, Rodrik D (2007) What you export matters. J Econ Growth 12(1):1–25CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Koopman R, Wang Z, Wei SJ (2008) How much of Chinese exports is really made in China? NBER Working Paper 14109:67 Koopman R, Wang Z, Wei SJ (2008) How much of Chinese exports is really made in China? NBER Working Paper 14109:67
Zurück zum Zitat Lardy NR (1994) China in the world economy. Peterson Institute Press, Washington Lardy NR (1994) China in the world economy. Peterson Institute Press, Washington
Zurück zum Zitat Long G (2005) China’s policies on FDI: review and evaluation. In: Moran TH, Graham EM, Blomstrom M (eds) Does foreign direct investment promote development?. Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington Long G (2005) China’s policies on FDI: review and evaluation. In: Moran TH, Graham EM, Blomstrom M (eds) Does foreign direct investment promote development?. Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington
Zurück zum Zitat Manova K, Yu ZH (2016) How firms export: processing vs. ordinary trade with financial frictions. J Int Econ 100:120–137CrossRef Manova K, Yu ZH (2016) How firms export: processing vs. ordinary trade with financial frictions. J Int Econ 100:120–137CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Melitz MJ (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6):1695–1725CrossRef Melitz MJ (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6):1695–1725CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rodrik D (2006) What’s so special about China’s exports? China World Econ 14(5):1–19CrossRef Rodrik D (2006) What’s so special about China’s exports? China World Econ 14(5):1–19CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schott PK (2008) The relative sophistication of Chinese exports. Economic policy 23(53):6–49 Schott PK (2008) The relative sophistication of Chinese exports. Economic policy 23(53):6–49
Zurück zum Zitat Xu B, Lu JY (2009) Foreign direct investment, processing trade, and the sophistication of China’s exports. China Econ Rev 20(3):425–439CrossRef Xu B, Lu JY (2009) Foreign direct investment, processing trade, and the sophistication of China’s exports. China Econ Rev 20(3):425–439CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Zhang KH (2015) What drives export competitiveness? The role of FDI in Chinese manufacturing. Contemp Econ Policy 33(3):499–512CrossRef Zhang KH (2015) What drives export competitiveness? The role of FDI in Chinese manufacturing. Contemp Econ Policy 33(3):499–512CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Zhang Q, Felmingham B (2001) The relationship between inward direct foreign investment and China’s provincial export trade. China Econ Rev 12(1):82–99CrossRef Zhang Q, Felmingham B (2001) The relationship between inward direct foreign investment and China’s provincial export trade. China Econ Rev 12(1):82–99CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
What has China learned from processing trade?
verfasst von
Bawoo Kim
Publikationsdatum
01.12.2017
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Journal of Economic Structures / Ausgabe 1/2017
Elektronische ISSN: 2193-2409
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1186/s40008-017-0088-5

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1/2017

Journal of Economic Structures 1/2017 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner