Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Constitutional Political Economy 2/2019

09.05.2019 | Original Paper

Bootleggers, Baptists, and the risks of rent seeking

verfasst von: Patrick A. McLaughlin, Adam C. Smith, Russell S. Sobel

Erschienen in: Constitutional Political Economy | Ausgabe 2/2019

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Interest groups ‘caught’ influencing public policy solely for private gain risk public backlash. These risks can be diminished, and rent seeking efforts made more successful, when moral or social arguments are employed in pushing for changes to public policy. Following Yandle’s Bootlegger and Baptist model, we postulate this risk differential should manifest itself in regulatory output with social regulations being more responsive to political influence than economic regulations. We test, and confirm, our theory using data on economic and social regulations from the new RegData project matched with data on campaign contributions and lobbying activity at the industry level.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
See Smith et al. (2011) for a more detailed account of this episode.
 
2
This is not to say that Occupy Wall Street was universally supported, only that enough lingering animosity remained to generate a notable political movement almost a full 2 years after the initial event.
 
3
Langer (2010). Citizens United Poll: 80 Percent Of Americans Oppose Supreme Court Decision. The Huffington Post (Apr 19) http://​www.​huffingtonpost.​com/​2010/​02/​17/​citizens-united-poll-80-p_​n_​465396.​html. Accessed April 5, 2019.
 
4
Seitz-Wald (2012). "Everyone Hates Citizens United." Salon. http://​www.​salon.​com/​2012/​10/​25/​people_​really_​hate_​citizens_​united/​. Accessed April 5, 2019.
 
5
Long and Vousden (1987) explain how this risk may be overcome through sharing rents.
 
6
The estimated total for campaign spending when Tullock wrote the article in 1972 was around $200 million, while simultaneously hundreds of billions of dollars were available through public expenditures and anti-regulatory efforts (see Ansolabehere et al. 2003, p. 110).
 
7
The idea that government may pressure firms to spend money fighting regulatory influence is discussed below. If true, this would only deepen the conundrum as firms should be even more willing to spend money towards political influence in order to avoid public backlash.
 
8
In a common example of adopting inefficient technologies at the local level, the NC Board of Governors “discussed a ‘buy local’ resolution that would require UNC colleges to favor North Carolina venders and products for capital projects, like new building construction and renovating existing ones” (see Hennan 2018).
 
9
Hillman and Ursprung (2016, p. 130) expand upon this point in the context of manipulating voters, noting that “because of requisites of political accountability, governments engage in purposefully inefficient income redistribution to take advantage of voter ignorance.” The resulting deadweight losses incurred represent the costs associated with keeping voters docile and ignorant of rent seeking. This is consistent with our claim below that there is an implicit moral (or ‘Baptist’) dimension to rent seeking that must be addressed if legislative efforts are to be successful. .
 
10
For example, Godwin et al. (2006, p. 40) model this element by having policymakers face a cost N of providing the rent, itself informed by the policy environment. They argue, “Public perception may help to determine N if it involves a policy that would attract substantial negative media attention to the policymakers.” Their model indicates that firms will seek out policymakers with a low enough N in order to entice an otherwise reluctant policymaker into the fold. However, greater pressure from other would-be competitors can reduce the marginal investment in political influence.
 
11
Long and Vousden (1987) arrive at a similar conclusion when rents are shared across groups. Mitigation of risk in particular can increase overall lobbying efforts.
 
12
As Hopenhayn and Lohmann (1996, p. 208) explain “A political principal who suffers an informational disadvantage vis-a-vis a regulatory agency can nevertheless use information supplied by the media, interest groups, and constituents to monitor whether the agency is acting in her best interests.”
 
13
Mixon et al. (1994, p. 172) further expand upon this fear of public backlash, noting “overt bribes attract attention and invited regulation, although rent seeking investments will take place even where cash bribes are costly.”.
 
14
He further adds, “Political ideologies normally include a notion of the good society towards which the actual, naturally imperfect, society should move.”.
 
15
Aidt (2016, p. 150) notes that “the degree of rent dissipation is much larger with private than with public-good rents.”.
 
16
Smith and Yandle (2014) discuss at length both types of rent seeking, focusing on social regulation in areas such as alcohol, tobacco, environmental, and health care. They find abundant evidence of rent seeking through social regulation where firms utilize Bootlegger/Baptist coalitions to avoid public outcry.
 
17
For example, “In a Pew Research Center survey conducted last year, about three-quarters of U.S. adults (74%) said ‘the country should do whatever it takes to protect the environment,’ compared with 23% who said “the country has gone too far in its efforts to protect the environment.” (see Anderson 2017). .
 
18
Hillman and Ursprung (2016, p. 127) distinguish Tullock’s contributions from Becker (1983, 1985) in modeling the costs of rent seeking noting “Becker’s conclusion was more favorable to an ideology that sees merit in extensive income redistribution.” As a further example MacKenzie (2017, p. 145) explains “In the mainstream environmental economics literature, the objective of regulation has been specified as the maximization of social welfare.”.
 
19
More recent regulatory activity originating with the efforts of Senator Elizabeth Warren (see Bar-gill and Warren 2008) and culminating in the founding of the Consumer Protection Financial Bureau would seem to belie this assumption. It’s certainly true that Senator Warren has brought greater public scrutiny to an otherwise obscure section of the regulatory landscape. See Smith and Zywicki (2015) for an analysis of the somewhat unique regulatory structure of the CFPB.
 
20
And as Tullock (1983, p. 165) explains within the context of farm special privileges “An asset that is held at risk is one in which one must put considerable resources into defending.”.
 
21
For example, it may be that activity meant to influence social regulation is less expensive to produce as it relies more heavily on voluntary efforts. This would only increase the relevant returns to the Bootlegger rent-seeking organization and accordingly make social regulations more worth securing (see Lipford and Yandle 2009).
 
22
Eventually, of course, gains from social regulation would diminish too as more firms utilize this type of rent seeking. Indeed, in theory, at the margin, the returns should equalize across economic and social regulatory capture, at least as a long-term equilibrium state. This assumes though that the total level of regulation is itself fixed. While we do not test this hypothesis, our reading of the background literature suggests that the size and scope of government is itself a potential variable of influence by special interest groups (see Olson 1982).
 
23
Congleton (2018, p. 10) notes “The direct sale of public policies is often illegal, because it tends to harm or violate social norms important to voters or other critical supporters.” Hillman and Long (2018, p. 7) reinforce this argument explaining “The resources used in a contest are not generally observable. Moreover, successful rent seekers will in general attribute their rents to their effort and competence, rather than to their success in rent seeking.”.
 
24
For example, Mixon et al. (1994) attempt to locate rent seeking by comparing the number of sit-down restaurants and public golf courses located in state capitals to other cities with similar income characteristics. Sobel and Garrett (2002) follow this thread by comparing a number of industries that would be necessary to generate rent-seeking activity such as printing services, billboard advertising, radio and television broadcasting, and policy institutes. The trouble in is that “other reasonable factors such as the administrative costs of government and its agencies” would also account for the presence of these industries (p. 130).
 
25
Aidt (2016, p. 143) describes this as ‘the invertibility hypothesis’ in that by “applying contest theory and assumptions about the behavior of rent seekers, the size of the social cost can be inferred from the value of the contestability rent.”.
 
26
Our framework also implies that production costs are equal across the two regulatory fronts. If social regulation is less expensive to pursue as we suggested in the above footnote, then its empirical presence would only serve to further validate our overarching hypothesis.
 
27
The Center for Responsive Politics. (2017). Opensecrets RSS. Combined Federal Campaign of the National Capital Area. http://​www.​opensecrets.​org/​industries/​slist.​php. Visited August 5, 2017.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Aidt, T. S. (2003). Redistribution and deadweight cost: the role of political competition. European Journal of Political Economy, 19(2), 205–226.CrossRef Aidt, T. S. (2003). Redistribution and deadweight cost: the role of political competition. European Journal of Political Economy, 19(2), 205–226.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Aidt, T. S. (2016). Rent seeking and the economics of corruption. Constitutional Political Economy, 27(2), 142–157.CrossRef Aidt, T. S. (2016). Rent seeking and the economics of corruption. Constitutional Political Economy, 27(2), 142–157.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Al-Ubaydli, O., & McLaughlin, P. A. (2017). RegData: A numerical database on industry-specific regulations for all United States industries and federal regulations, 1997–2012. Regulation & Governance, 11(1), 109–123.CrossRef Al-Ubaydli, O., & McLaughlin, P. A. (2017). RegData: A numerical database on industry-specific regulations for all United States industries and federal regulations, 1997–2012. Regulation & Governance, 11(1), 109–123.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ansolabehere, S., de Figueiredo, J. M., & Snyder, J. M. (2003). Why is there so little money in US politics? The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17, 105–130.CrossRef Ansolabehere, S., de Figueiredo, J. M., & Snyder, J. M. (2003). Why is there so little money in US politics? The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17, 105–130.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bar-Gill, O., & Warren, E. (2008). Making credit safer. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 157, 1–101. Bar-Gill, O., & Warren, E. (2008). Making credit safer. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 157, 1–101.
Zurück zum Zitat Baum, C. F., Schaffer, M. E., & Stillman, S. (2007). Enhanced routines for instrumental variables/generalized method of moments estimation and testing. The Stata Journal, 7(4), 465–506.CrossRef Baum, C. F., Schaffer, M. E., & Stillman, S. (2007). Enhanced routines for instrumental variables/generalized method of moments estimation and testing. The Stata Journal, 7(4), 465–506.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98, 371–400.CrossRef Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98, 371–400.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Becker, G. S. (1985). Public policies, pressure groups, and dead weight costs. Journal of public economics, 28, 329–347.CrossRef Becker, G. S. (1985). Public policies, pressure groups, and dead weight costs. Journal of public economics, 28, 329–347.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brito, J., & Dudley, S. E. (2012). Regulation: A primer. Arlington: Mercatus Center at George Mason University. Brito, J., & Dudley, S. E. (2012). Regulation: A primer. Arlington: Mercatus Center at George Mason University.
Zurück zum Zitat Congleton, R. D. (1991). Ideological conviction and persuasion in the rent-seeking society. Journal of Public Economics, 44(1), 65–86.CrossRef Congleton, R. D. (1991). Ideological conviction and persuasion in the rent-seeking society. Journal of Public Economics, 44(1), 65–86.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Congleton, R. D. (2018). The Political Economy of Rent Creation and Rent Extraction. In R. D. Congleton, B. N. Grofman, & S. Voigt (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of public choice. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Congleton, R. D. (2018). The Political Economy of Rent Creation and Rent Extraction. In R. D. Congleton, B. N. Grofman, & S. Voigt (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of public choice. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Congleton, R. D., & Hillman, A. L. (2015). Companion to the political economy of rent seeking. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.CrossRef Congleton, R. D., & Hillman, A. L. (2015). Companion to the political economy of rent seeking. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Congleton, R. D., Hillman, A. L., & Konrad, K. A. (2008). Forty years of research on rent seeking: fan overview. The Theory of Rent Seeking: Forty Years of Research, 1, 1–42. Congleton, R. D., Hillman, A. L., & Konrad, K. A. (2008). Forty years of research on rent seeking: fan overview. The Theory of Rent Seeking: Forty Years of Research, 1, 1–42.
Zurück zum Zitat Del Rosal, I. (2011). The empirical measurement of rent? Seeking costs. Journal of Economic Surveys, 25(2), 298–325.CrossRef Del Rosal, I. (2011). The empirical measurement of rent? Seeking costs. Journal of Economic Surveys, 25(2), 298–325.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Denzau, A. T., & Munger, M. C. (1986). Legislators and interest groups: How unorganized interests get represented. The American Political Science Review, 80, 89–106.CrossRef Denzau, A. T., & Munger, M. C. (1986). Legislators and interest groups: How unorganized interests get represented. The American Political Science Review, 80, 89–106.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dudley, S., & Warren, M. (2011). Fiscal statement reflected in regulators’ budget: An analysis of the U.S. budget for fiscal years 2011 and 2012. Wiedenbaum Center on the Economy, Government, and Public Policy. St. Louis: Washington University. Dudley, S., & Warren, M. (2011). Fiscal statement reflected in regulators’ budget: An analysis of the U.S. budget for fiscal years 2011 and 2012. Wiedenbaum Center on the Economy, Government, and Public Policy. St. Louis: Washington University.
Zurück zum Zitat Godwin, R. K., López, E. J., & Seldon, B. J. (2006). Incorporating policymaker costs and political competition into rent-seeking games. Southern Economic Journal, 73, 37–54.CrossRef Godwin, R. K., López, E. J., & Seldon, B. J. (2006). Incorporating policymaker costs and political competition into rent-seeking games. Southern Economic Journal, 73, 37–54.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hillman, A. L. (2019). Public finance and public policy: responsibilities and limitations of government (3rd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Hillman, A. L. (2019). Public finance and public policy: responsibilities and limitations of government (3rd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hillman, A. L., & Katz, E. (1984). Risk-averse rent seekers and the social cost of monopoly power. The Economic Journal, 94(373), 104–110.CrossRef Hillman, A. L., & Katz, E. (1984). Risk-averse rent seekers and the social cost of monopoly power. The Economic Journal, 94(373), 104–110.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hillman, A. L., & Long, N. V. (2018). Rent seeking: the social cost of contestable benefits. In R. D. Congleton, B. N. Grofman, & S. Voigt (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of public choice. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hillman, A. L., & Long, N. V. (2018). Rent seeking: the social cost of contestable benefits. In R. D. Congleton, B. N. Grofman, & S. Voigt (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of public choice. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Hillman, A. L., & Riley, J. G. (1989). Politically contestable rents and transfers. Economics and Politics, 1(1), 17–39.CrossRef Hillman, A. L., & Riley, J. G. (1989). Politically contestable rents and transfers. Economics and Politics, 1(1), 17–39.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hillman, A.L. & Ursprung, H.W. (1992). The influence of environmental concerns on the political determination of trade policy. The greening of world trade issues, p. 195–220. Hillman, A.L. & Ursprung, H.W. (1992). The influence of environmental concerns on the political determination of trade policy. The greening of world trade issues, p. 195–220.
Zurück zum Zitat Hillman, A. L., & Ursprung, H. W. (1994). Greens, supergreens, and international trade policy: Environmental concerns and protectionism. In C. Carraro (Ed.), Trade, innovation, environment (pp. 75–108). Dordrecht: Springer.CrossRef Hillman, A. L., & Ursprung, H. W. (1994). Greens, supergreens, and international trade policy: Environmental concerns and protectionism. In C. Carraro (Ed.), Trade, innovation, environment (pp. 75–108). Dordrecht: Springer.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hillman, A. L., & Ursprung, H. W. (2016). Where are the rent seekers? Constitutional Political Economy, 27(2), 124–141.CrossRef Hillman, A. L., & Ursprung, H. W. (2016). Where are the rent seekers? Constitutional Political Economy, 27(2), 124–141.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hopenhayn, H., & Lohmann, S. (1996). Fire-alarm signals and the political oversight of regulatory agencies. The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 12(1), 196–213.CrossRef Hopenhayn, H., & Lohmann, S. (1996). Fire-alarm signals and the political oversight of regulatory agencies. The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 12(1), 196–213.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Issacharoff, S., & Peterman, J. (2013). Special interests after citizens united: Access, replacement, and interest group response to legal change. Annual Review of Law and Social Science, 9, 185–205.CrossRef Issacharoff, S., & Peterman, J. (2013). Special interests after citizens united: Access, replacement, and interest group response to legal change. Annual Review of Law and Social Science, 9, 185–205.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lilly, W., & Miller, J. C. (1977). The new social regulation. The Public Interest, 47, 28–36. Lilly, W., & Miller, J. C. (1977). The new social regulation. The Public Interest, 47, 28–36.
Zurück zum Zitat Lipford, J. W., & Slice, J. (2007). Adam Smith’s roles for government and contemporary US government roles. The Independent Review, 11(4), 485–501. Lipford, J. W., & Slice, J. (2007). Adam Smith’s roles for government and contemporary US government roles. The Independent Review, 11(4), 485–501.
Zurück zum Zitat Lipford, J. W., & Yandle, B. (2009). The determinants of purposeful voluntarism. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 38(1), 72–79.CrossRef Lipford, J. W., & Yandle, B. (2009). The determinants of purposeful voluntarism. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 38(1), 72–79.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Long, N. V., & Vousden, N. (1987). Risk-averse rent seeking with shared rents. The Economic Journal, 97, 971–985.CrossRef Long, N. V., & Vousden, N. (1987). Risk-averse rent seeking with shared rents. The Economic Journal, 97, 971–985.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lopez, R. A., & Pagoulatos, E. (1994). Rent seeking and the welfare cost of trade barriers. Public Choice, 79(1), 149–160.CrossRef Lopez, R. A., & Pagoulatos, E. (1994). Rent seeking and the welfare cost of trade barriers. Public Choice, 79(1), 149–160.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat MacKenzie, I. A. (2017). Rent creation and rent seeking in environmental policy. Public Choice, 171(1–2), 145–166.CrossRef MacKenzie, I. A. (2017). Rent creation and rent seeking in environmental policy. Public Choice, 171(1–2), 145–166.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Miller, J. C., & Yandle, B. (Eds.). (1979). Benefit-cost analyses of social regulation: Case studies from the council on wage and price stability (Vol. 231). Washington: American Enterprise Institute Press. Miller, J. C., & Yandle, B. (Eds.). (1979). Benefit-cost analyses of social regulation: Case studies from the council on wage and price stability (Vol. 231). Washington: American Enterprise Institute Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Mixon, F. G., Laband, D. N., & Ekelund, R. B. (1994). Rent seeking and hidden in-kind resource distortion: some empirical evidence. Public Choice, 78(2), 171–185.CrossRef Mixon, F. G., Laband, D. N., & Ekelund, R. B. (1994). Rent seeking and hidden in-kind resource distortion: some empirical evidence. Public Choice, 78(2), 171–185.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1993). Why is rent-seeking so costly to growth? The American Economic Review, 83(2), 409–414. Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1993). Why is rent-seeking so costly to growth? The American Economic Review, 83(2), 409–414.
Zurück zum Zitat Newey, W. K., & West, K. D. (1987). A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica, 55, 703–708.CrossRef Newey, W. K., & West, K. D. (1987). A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica, 55, 703–708.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Newey, W. K., & West, K. D. (1994). Automatic lag selection in covariance matrix estimation. Review of Economic Studies, 61, 631–653.CrossRef Newey, W. K., & West, K. D. (1994). Automatic lag selection in covariance matrix estimation. Review of Economic Studies, 61, 631–653.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations: Economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Press. Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations: Economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 19, 211–240.CrossRef Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 19, 211–240.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shogren, J. F. (1990). The optimal subsidization of Baptists by Bootleggers. Public Choice, 67(2), 181–189.CrossRef Shogren, J. F. (1990). The optimal subsidization of Baptists by Bootleggers. Public Choice, 67(2), 181–189.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Smith, A. C., Wagner, R. E., & Yandle, B. (2011). A theory of entangled political economy, with application to TARP and NRA. Public Choice, 148, 45–66.CrossRef Smith, A. C., Wagner, R. E., & Yandle, B. (2011). A theory of entangled political economy, with application to TARP and NRA. Public Choice, 148, 45–66.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Smith, A. C., & Yandle, B. (2014). Bootleggers and Baptists: How economic forces and moral persuasion interact to shape regulatory politics. Washington: Cato Institute Press. Smith, A. C., & Yandle, B. (2014). Bootleggers and Baptists: How economic forces and moral persuasion interact to shape regulatory politics. Washington: Cato Institute Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Smith, A. C., & Zywicki, T. (2015). Behavior, paternalism, and policy: evaluating consumer financial protection. NYUJL & Liberty, 9, 201. Smith, A. C., & Zywicki, T. (2015). Behavior, paternalism, and policy: evaluating consumer financial protection. NYUJL & Liberty, 9, 201.
Zurück zum Zitat Sobel, R. S., & Garrett, T. A. (2002). On the measurement of rent seeking and its social opportunity cost. Public Choice, 112(1), 115–136.CrossRef Sobel, R. S., & Garrett, T. A. (2002). On the measurement of rent seeking and its social opportunity cost. Public Choice, 112(1), 115–136.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stratmann, T. 2005. Some talk: Money in politics. A (partial) review of the literature. In Policy challenges and political responses (pp. 135–156). Springer, New York. Stratmann, T. 2005. Some talk: Money in politics. A (partial) review of the literature. In Policy challenges and political responses (pp. 135–156). Springer, New York.
Zurück zum Zitat Tollison, R. D. (1982). Rent seeking: A survey. Kyklos, 35(4), 575–602.CrossRef Tollison, R. D. (1982). Rent seeking: A survey. Kyklos, 35(4), 575–602.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Economic Inquiry, 5(3), 224–232.CrossRef Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Economic Inquiry, 5(3), 224–232.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1972). The purchase of politicians. Western Economic Journal [Economic Inquiry], 10, 354–355. Tullock, G. (1972). The purchase of politicians. Western Economic Journal [Economic Inquiry], 10, 354–355.
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1983). Economics of income redistribution. Berlin: Springer.CrossRef Tullock, G. (1983). Economics of income redistribution. Berlin: Springer.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1989). The economics of special privilege and rent seeking. Alphen aan den Rijn: Kluwer Academic Publishers.CrossRef Tullock, G. (1989). The economics of special privilege and rent seeking. Alphen aan den Rijn: Kluwer Academic Publishers.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ursprung, H. W. (1990). Public goods, rent dissipation, and candidate competition. Economics and Politics, 2(2), 115–132.CrossRef Ursprung, H. W. (1990). Public goods, rent dissipation, and candidate competition. Economics and Politics, 2(2), 115–132.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ursprung, H. W. (2012). The evolution of sharing rules in rent seeking contests: incentives crowd out cooperation. Public Choice, 153(1–2), 149–161.CrossRef Ursprung, H. W. (2012). The evolution of sharing rules in rent seeking contests: incentives crowd out cooperation. Public Choice, 153(1–2), 149–161.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Vogel, D. (1988). The ‘new’ social regulation in historical and comparative perspective (p. 431). American Law and the Constitutional Order: Historical Perspectives. Vogel, D. (1988). The ‘new’ social regulation in historical and comparative perspective (p. 431). American Law and the Constitutional Order: Historical Perspectives.
Zurück zum Zitat Wagner, R. E. (2007). Fiscal sociology and the theory of public finance: An exploratory essay. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.CrossRef Wagner, R. E. (2007). Fiscal sociology and the theory of public finance: An exploratory essay. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wagner, R. E. (2016). Politics as a peculiar business: Insights from a theory of entangled political economy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.CrossRef Wagner, R. E. (2016). Politics as a peculiar business: Insights from a theory of entangled political economy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Weidenbaum, M. L. (1977). Business, government and the public. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall. Weidenbaum, M. L. (1977). Business, government and the public. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.
Zurück zum Zitat Williams, B. A., & Matheny, A. R. (1984). Testing theories of social regulation: Hazardous waste regulation in the American states. The Journal of Politics, 46(2), 428–458.CrossRef Williams, B. A., & Matheny, A. R. (1984). Testing theories of social regulation: Hazardous waste regulation in the American states. The Journal of Politics, 46(2), 428–458.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Yandle, B. (1983). Bootleggers and Baptists—The education of a regulatory economist. Regulation, 7, 12. Yandle, B. (1983). Bootleggers and Baptists—The education of a regulatory economist. Regulation, 7, 12.
Zurück zum Zitat Yandle, B. (1999). Bootleggers and Baptists in retrospect. Regulation, 22, 5. Yandle, B. (1999). Bootleggers and Baptists in retrospect. Regulation, 22, 5.
Metadaten
Titel
Bootleggers, Baptists, and the risks of rent seeking
verfasst von
Patrick A. McLaughlin
Adam C. Smith
Russell S. Sobel
Publikationsdatum
09.05.2019
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Constitutional Political Economy / Ausgabe 2/2019
Print ISSN: 1043-4062
Elektronische ISSN: 1572-9966
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-019-09278-2

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 2/2019

Constitutional Political Economy 2/2019 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner