Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Electronic Commerce Research 1/2021

29.03.2021

Crowdfunding as a screener for collective investment

verfasst von: Sha Zhou, Tao Ma, Zhengchi Liu

Erschienen in: Electronic Commerce Research | Ausgabe 1/2021

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Crowdfunding uses a small amount of money from many people to fund a new venture. It is essentially a collective investment characterized by diversified investors, crowd-based decision-making, and consensus threshold. The sustainability of these markets heavily depends on the screening performance of the crowd. Although empirical studies suggest crowd-based funding decisions can be wise, little is known about the underlying rationale. This paper fills this void. We employ a computational experiment to investigate the impacts of investors’ attributes, i.e. ability and heterogeneity, and the threshold mechanisms on screening performance. We firstly identify the filtering effect of the consensus threshold. The high threshold screens out most of the unattractive projects and leads to less waste of capital, which makes All-Or-Nothing always outperform Keep-It-All. Further, we find a substitution effect of heterogeneity. When the group size is big enough, heterogeneous unsophisticated groups trump same-sized well-chosen ones. Lastly, the substitution effect of heterogeneity is moderated by the effectiveness of signals. In a crowdfunding environment of low predictability, investors’ heterogeneity contributes little to the collective accuracy, while investors’ expertise remains critical. In contrast to popular perceptions of crowdfunding markets as a new financing tool or marketing tool for entrepreneurs, our research indicates that crowdfunding is also an effective screener for collective investment.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 390 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe




 

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
Note that in AON the entrepreneur keeps nothing unless the goal is achieved, while in KIA the entrepreneur keeps the entire amount raised regardless of whether or not they meet their goal [20].
 
2
The signal effectiveness refers to the extent to which a signal maintains validity in communicating underlying quality and reducing information asymmetry across a breadth of investors or domains in a variety of exchange contexts [51].
 
3
The measurements of signal effectiveness are inconsistent in prior literature and most of them are qualitative. For example, Bjornsdottir and Rule [10] argue that the predictability of signals is associated with its visibility and representativeness. In Scheaf et al.’s [51] research, the degree to which a signal is effective is a function of the characteristics of the source and receivers of the signal. Based on the theory of statistics, we quantitively measure signal effectiveness by calculating the assessment model’s explanatory power.
 
4
Two signal-based judgmental processes are studied in this paper: perceive the values of proximal signals and weigh the validity of signals. The former is related to the individual’s perception ability while the latter relies on the individual’s reasoning ability, and they are generally independent of each other.
 
5
The investor makes a biased estimation for a project largely because he can not perfectly perceive signals and combine the perceived signals in the wrong way, which means the smaller the differences between the real and perceived signal values or the correct and adopted weights, the less biased the investor’s estimation. To precisely portray the two kinds of differences above, we chose root mean squared error (RMSE) as the operationalization of the investors’ ability owing to its useful property of penalizing strong deviations.
 
6
We prefer the pairwise coorelations in that the variance can’t fully depict the heterogeneity among individual cognitions and fails to interpret the deeper evaluating process of investors in the crowdfunding context, while the pairwise correlations precisely characterize the extent of cognitive divergences among investors.
 
7
It might seem that our ceiling of \(N = 20\) is not perfectly consistent with the practice that most crowdfunding projects usually are funded by hundreds of backers [43]. Considering the constraints of computing power, we specifically chose this modest range to distinguish from the decision-making literature that focuses on small groups (the range of group size includes 5 and 12), e.g. board of directors and jury [28,26]. Generalizing the experiment by scaling up the group size is a task left to future research.
 
8
Most researches on human cognition shows that owing to individuals’ cognitive limitations and cue intercorrelations or information redundancy, judgments based on a finite set of cues can be predicted with a high degree of accuracy from a simple linear combination of three or fewer cues [52].
 
9
See [28].
 
10
Here we follows Karelaia and Hogarth [31] and Hastie and Kameda [26] in adopting a compensatory weight dispersion. Our later sensitivity analysis shows that changing the dispersion form of weight won’t affect our main results.
 
11
To focus on the effects of investors’ characteristics and consensus threshold on screening performance, we first control the signal effectiveness of a median level. Subsequently, we reran our experiment with various environmental predictability to investigate the moderating effect of signal effectiveness.
 
12
Most of the crowdfunding projects raises funds with moderate threshold. The projects with extremely low or unrealistic high threshold are still a minority (see [43]. Consistent with that, we set here the expected value of T as the mid-value of group size.
 
13
According to the 3σ principle of the normal distribution, the probability that normally distributed stochastic variable x falls in the interval of \(\left[ {\mu - 3\sigma ,\mu + 3\sigma } \right]\) is 99.74%. That is, our setting of standard deviation of T almost guarantees the value of T falls in the interval of \(\left( {0,N} \right)\).
 
14
Note that the crowd has no loss when the project they supported fails to reach the consensus threshold, in that their contributions will be returned in full under the threshold scheme. Those failed projects do not receive any pieces of collective funds, so they have no impact on the efficiency of collective investment.
 
15
Panel (b) in Fig. 8 presents a benchmark case of \(R^{2} = 0.80\) (medium signal effectiveness) and facilitates the discussion of the moderating effect of signal effectiveness.
 
Literatur
1.
Zurück zum Zitat Abdel-Khalik, A. R., & El-Sheshai, K. M. (1980). Information choice and utilization in an experiment on default prediction. Journal of Accounting Research, 18(2), 325–342.CrossRef Abdel-Khalik, A. R., & El-Sheshai, K. M. (1980). Information choice and utilization in an experiment on default prediction. Journal of Accounting Research, 18(2), 325–342.CrossRef
2.
Zurück zum Zitat Agrawal, A., Catalini, C., & Goldfarb, A. (2015). Crowdfunding: Geography, social networks, and the timing of investment decisions. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 24(2), 253–274. Agrawal, A., Catalini, C., & Goldfarb, A. (2015). Crowdfunding: Geography, social networks, and the timing of investment decisions. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 24(2), 253–274.
3.
Zurück zum Zitat Agrawal, A., Catalini, C., & Goldfarb, A. (2016). Are syndicates the killer app of equity-based crowdfunding? California Management Review, 58(2), 111–124.CrossRef Agrawal, A., Catalini, C., & Goldfarb, A. (2016). Are syndicates the killer app of equity-based crowdfunding? California Management Review, 58(2), 111–124.CrossRef
4.
Zurück zum Zitat Ahlers, G. K., Cumming, D., Günther, C., & Schweizer, D. (2015). Signaling in equity-based crowdfunding. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 39(4), 955–980. Ahlers, G. K., Cumming, D., Günther, C., & Schweizer, D. (2015). Signaling in equity-based crowdfunding. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 39(4), 955–980.
5.
Zurück zum Zitat Belleflamme, P., Omrani, N., & Peitz, M. (2015). The economics of crowdfunding platforms. Information Economics and Policy, 33, 11–28.CrossRef Belleflamme, P., Omrani, N., & Peitz, M. (2015). The economics of crowdfunding platforms. Information Economics and Policy, 33, 11–28.CrossRef
6.
Zurück zum Zitat Belleflamme, P., Lambert, T., & Schwienbacher, A. (2014). Crowdfunding: Tapping the right crowd. Journal of Business Venturing., 29(5), 585–609.CrossRef Belleflamme, P., Lambert, T., & Schwienbacher, A. (2014). Crowdfunding: Tapping the right crowd. Journal of Business Venturing., 29(5), 585–609.CrossRef
7.
Zurück zum Zitat Bester, H. (1985). Screening vs. rationing in credit markets with imperfect information. American Economic Review, 75(4), 850–855. Bester, H. (1985). Screening vs. rationing in credit markets with imperfect information. American Economic Review, 75(4), 850–855.
8.
Zurück zum Zitat Bi, G., Geng, B., & Liu, L. (2019). On the fixed and flexible funding mechanisms in reward-based crowdfunding. European Journal of Operational Research, 279(1), 168–183.CrossRef Bi, G., Geng, B., & Liu, L. (2019). On the fixed and flexible funding mechanisms in reward-based crowdfunding. European Journal of Operational Research, 279(1), 168–183.CrossRef
9.
Zurück zum Zitat Biemann, T., & Kearney, E. (2010). Size does matter: How varying group sizes in a sample affect the most common measures of group heterogeneity. Organizational Research Methods, 13(3), 582–599.CrossRef Biemann, T., & Kearney, E. (2010). Size does matter: How varying group sizes in a sample affect the most common measures of group heterogeneity. Organizational Research Methods, 13(3), 582–599.CrossRef
10.
Zurück zum Zitat Bjornsdottir, R. T., & Rule, N. O. (2017). The visibility of the social class from facial cues. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 113(4), 530–546.CrossRef Bjornsdottir, R. T., & Rule, N. O. (2017). The visibility of the social class from facial cues. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 113(4), 530–546.CrossRef
11.
Zurück zum Zitat Burtch, G., Hong, Y., & Liu, D. (2018). The role of provision points in online crowdfunding. Journal of Management Information Systems, 35(1), 117–144.CrossRef Burtch, G., Hong, Y., & Liu, D. (2018). The role of provision points in online crowdfunding. Journal of Management Information Systems, 35(1), 117–144.CrossRef
12.
Zurück zum Zitat Brunswik, E. (1956). Perception and the representative design of psychological experiments. California: Univ of California Press.CrossRef Brunswik, E. (1956). Perception and the representative design of psychological experiments. California: Univ of California Press.CrossRef
13.
Zurück zum Zitat Casamatta, C., & Haritchabalet, C. (2007). Experience, screening and syndication in venture capital investments. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 16(3), 368–398.CrossRef Casamatta, C., & Haritchabalet, C. (2007). Experience, screening and syndication in venture capital investments. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 16(3), 368–398.CrossRef
14.
Zurück zum Zitat Chemla, G., & Tinn, K. (2020). Learning through crowdfunding. Management Science, 66(5), 1783–1801.CrossRef Chemla, G., & Tinn, K. (2020). Learning through crowdfunding. Management Science, 66(5), 1783–1801.CrossRef
15.
Zurück zum Zitat Chemmanur, T. J., & Fulghieri, P. (2013). Entrepreneurial finance, and innovation: An introduction and agenda for future research. The Review of Financial Studies, 27(1), 1–19.CrossRef Chemmanur, T. J., & Fulghieri, P. (2013). Entrepreneurial finance, and innovation: An introduction and agenda for future research. The Review of Financial Studies, 27(1), 1–19.CrossRef
17.
Zurück zum Zitat Chen, W., Lin, M., & Zhang, B. Z. (2018). Lower taxes, smarter crowd? The impact of tax incentives on equity-based crowdfunding. Georgia Tech Scheller College of Business Research Paper, 18–27. Chen, W., Lin, M., & Zhang, B. Z. (2018). Lower taxes, smarter crowd? The impact of tax incentives on equity-based crowdfunding. Georgia Tech Scheller College of Business Research Paper, 18–27.
19.
Zurück zum Zitat Connelly, B. L., Certo, S. T., Ireland, R. D., & Reutzel, C. R. (2011). Signaling theory: A review and assessment. Journal of Management, 37(1), 39–67.CrossRef Connelly, B. L., Certo, S. T., Ireland, R. D., & Reutzel, C. R. (2011). Signaling theory: A review and assessment. Journal of Management, 37(1), 39–67.CrossRef
20.
Zurück zum Zitat Cumming, D. J., Leboeuf, G., & Schwienbacher, A. (2020). Crowdfunding models: Keep-it-all vs. all-or-nothing. Financial Management, 49(2), 331–360.CrossRef Cumming, D. J., Leboeuf, G., & Schwienbacher, A. (2020). Crowdfunding models: Keep-it-all vs. all-or-nothing. Financial Management, 49(2), 331–360.CrossRef
21.
Zurück zum Zitat Csaszar, F. A., & Eggers, J. P. (2013). Organizational decision making: An information aggregation view. Management Science, 59(10), 2257–2277.CrossRef Csaszar, F. A., & Eggers, J. P. (2013). Organizational decision making: An information aggregation view. Management Science, 59(10), 2257–2277.CrossRef
22.
Zurück zum Zitat Ellman, M., & Hurkens, S. (2019). Optimal crowdfunding design. Journal of Economic Theory, 184, 104939.CrossRef Ellman, M., & Hurkens, S. (2019). Optimal crowdfunding design. Journal of Economic Theory, 184, 104939.CrossRef
23.
Zurück zum Zitat Du, Q. (2016). Birds of a feather or celebrating differences? The formation and impacts of venture capital syndication. Journal of Empirical Finance, 39, 1–14.CrossRef Du, Q. (2016). Birds of a feather or celebrating differences? The formation and impacts of venture capital syndication. Journal of Empirical Finance, 39, 1–14.CrossRef
24.
Zurück zum Zitat Falconieri, S., Filatotchev, I., & Tastan, M. (2019). Size and diversity in VC syndicates and their impact on IPO performance. The European Journal of Finance, 25(11), 1032–1053.CrossRef Falconieri, S., Filatotchev, I., & Tastan, M. (2019). Size and diversity in VC syndicates and their impact on IPO performance. The European Journal of Finance, 25(11), 1032–1053.CrossRef
25.
Zurück zum Zitat Grüner, H. P., & Siemroth, C. (2019). Crowdfunding, efficiency, and inequality. Journal of the European Economic Association, 17(5), 1393–1427.CrossRef Grüner, H. P., & Siemroth, C. (2019). Crowdfunding, efficiency, and inequality. Journal of the European Economic Association, 17(5), 1393–1427.CrossRef
26.
Zurück zum Zitat Hastie, R., & Kameda, T. (2005). The robust beauty of majority mechanisms in group decisions. Psychological Review, 112(2), 494–508.CrossRef Hastie, R., & Kameda, T. (2005). The robust beauty of majority mechanisms in group decisions. Psychological Review, 112(2), 494–508.CrossRef
27.
Zurück zum Zitat Hildebrand, T., Puri, M., & Rocholl, J. (2016). Adverse incentives in crowdfunding. Management Science, 63(3), 587–608.CrossRef Hildebrand, T., Puri, M., & Rocholl, J. (2016). Adverse incentives in crowdfunding. Management Science, 63(3), 587–608.CrossRef
28.
Zurück zum Zitat Hong, L., & Page, S. E. (2004). Groups of diverse problem solvers can outperform groups of high-ability problem solvers. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 101(46), 16385–16389.CrossRef Hong, L., & Page, S. E. (2004). Groups of diverse problem solvers can outperform groups of high-ability problem solvers. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 101(46), 16385–16389.CrossRef
29.
Zurück zum Zitat Hopp, C., & Rieder, F. (2011). What drives venture capital syndication? Applied Economics, 43(23), 3089–3102.CrossRef Hopp, C., & Rieder, F. (2011). What drives venture capital syndication? Applied Economics, 43(23), 3089–3102.CrossRef
30.
Zurück zum Zitat Iyer, R., Khwaja, A. I., Luttmer, E. F. P., et al. (2016). Screening peers softly: Inferring the quality of small borrowers. Management Science, 62(6), 1554–1577.CrossRef Iyer, R., Khwaja, A. I., Luttmer, E. F. P., et al. (2016). Screening peers softly: Inferring the quality of small borrowers. Management Science, 62(6), 1554–1577.CrossRef
31.
Zurück zum Zitat Karelia, N., & Hogarth, R. M. (2008). Determinants of linear judgment: A meta-analysis of lens model studies. Psychological Bulletin, 134(3), 404.CrossRef Karelia, N., & Hogarth, R. M. (2008). Determinants of linear judgment: A meta-analysis of lens model studies. Psychological Bulletin, 134(3), 404.CrossRef
32.
Zurück zum Zitat Keuschnigg, M., & Ganser, C. (2016). Crowd wisdom relies on agents’ ability in small groups with a voting aggregation mechanism. Management Science, 63(3), 818–828.CrossRef Keuschnigg, M., & Ganser, C. (2016). Crowd wisdom relies on agents’ ability in small groups with a voting aggregation mechanism. Management Science, 63(3), 818–828.CrossRef
33.
Zurück zum Zitat Kunz, M. M., Ulrich, B., Max, E., & Jan, M. L. (2017). An empirical investigation of signaling in reward-based crowdfunding. Electronic Commerce Research, 17(3), 425–461.CrossRef Kunz, M. M., Ulrich, B., Max, E., & Jan, M. L. (2017). An empirical investigation of signaling in reward-based crowdfunding. Electronic Commerce Research, 17(3), 425–461.CrossRef
34.
Zurück zum Zitat Lerner, J. (1994). The syndication of venture capital investments. Financial Management, 23(3), 16–27.CrossRef Lerner, J. (1994). The syndication of venture capital investments. Financial Management, 23(3), 16–27.CrossRef
35.
Zurück zum Zitat Lin, M., Prabhala, N. R., & Viswanathan, S. (2013). Judging borrowers by the company they keep: Friendship networks and information asymmetry in online peer-to-peer lending. Management Science, 59(1), 17–35.CrossRef Lin, M., Prabhala, N. R., & Viswanathan, S. (2013). Judging borrowers by the company they keep: Friendship networks and information asymmetry in online peer-to-peer lending. Management Science, 59(1), 17–35.CrossRef
36.
Zurück zum Zitat Lin, M., & Viswanathan, S. (2015). Home bias in online investments: An empirical study of an online crowdfunding market. Management Science, 62(5), 1393–1414.CrossRef Lin, M., & Viswanathan, S. (2015). Home bias in online investments: An empirical study of an online crowdfunding market. Management Science, 62(5), 1393–1414.CrossRef
37.
Zurück zum Zitat List, C., & Goodin, R. E. (2001). Epistemic democracy: Generalizing the condorcet jury theorem. Journal of Political Philosophy, 9(3), 277–306.CrossRef List, C., & Goodin, R. E. (2001). Epistemic democracy: Generalizing the condorcet jury theorem. Journal of Political Philosophy, 9(3), 277–306.CrossRef
38.
Zurück zum Zitat Liu, Z., Shang, J., Wu, S., et al. (2020). Social collateral, soft information and online peer-to-peer lending: A theoretical model. European Journal of Operational Research, 281(2), 428–438.CrossRef Liu, Z., Shang, J., Wu, S., et al. (2020). Social collateral, soft information and online peer-to-peer lending: A theoretical model. European Journal of Operational Research, 281(2), 428–438.CrossRef
39.
Zurück zum Zitat Lockett, A., & Wright, M. (2001). The syndication of venture capital investments. Omega, 29(5), 375–390.CrossRef Lockett, A., & Wright, M. (2001). The syndication of venture capital investments. Omega, 29(5), 375–390.CrossRef
41.
Zurück zum Zitat Lorenz, J., Rauhut, H., Schweitzer, F., & Helbing, D. (2011). How social influence can undermine the wisdom of crowd effect. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108(22), 9020–9025.CrossRef Lorenz, J., Rauhut, H., Schweitzer, F., & Helbing, D. (2011). How social influence can undermine the wisdom of crowd effect. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108(22), 9020–9025.CrossRef
42.
Zurück zum Zitat Mahmood, A., Luffarelli, J., & Mukesh, M. (2019). What’s in a logo? The impact of complex visual cues in equity crowdfunding. Journal of Business Venturing, 34(1), 41–62.CrossRef Mahmood, A., Luffarelli, J., & Mukesh, M. (2019). What’s in a logo? The impact of complex visual cues in equity crowdfunding. Journal of Business Venturing, 34(1), 41–62.CrossRef
43.
Zurück zum Zitat Mollick, E. (2014). The dynamics of crowdfunding: An exploratory study. Journal of Business Venturing, 29(1), 1–16.CrossRef Mollick, E. (2014). The dynamics of crowdfunding: An exploratory study. Journal of Business Venturing, 29(1), 1–16.CrossRef
44.
Zurück zum Zitat Mollick, E., & Nanda, R. (2015). Wisdom or madness? Comparing crowds with expert evaluation in funding the arts. Management Science, 62(6), 1533–1553.CrossRef Mollick, E., & Nanda, R. (2015). Wisdom or madness? Comparing crowds with expert evaluation in funding the arts. Management Science, 62(6), 1533–1553.CrossRef
45.
Zurück zum Zitat Oliver, P. E., & Marwell, G. (1988). The paradox of group size in collective action: A theory of the critical mass II. American Sociological Review, 53(1), 1–8.CrossRef Oliver, P. E., & Marwell, G. (1988). The paradox of group size in collective action: A theory of the critical mass II. American Sociological Review, 53(1), 1–8.CrossRef
46.
Zurück zum Zitat Pahnke, E. C., Katila, R., & Eisenhardt, K. M. (2015). Who takes you to the dance? How partners’ institutional logics influence innovation in young firms. Administrative Science Quarterly, 60(4), 596–633.CrossRef Pahnke, E. C., Katila, R., & Eisenhardt, K. M. (2015). Who takes you to the dance? How partners’ institutional logics influence innovation in young firms. Administrative Science Quarterly, 60(4), 596–633.CrossRef
47.
Zurück zum Zitat Paravisini, D., Rappoport, V., & Ravina, E. (2016). Risk aversion and wealth: Evidence from person-to-person lending portfolios. Management Science, 63(2), 279–297.CrossRef Paravisini, D., Rappoport, V., & Ravina, E. (2016). Risk aversion and wealth: Evidence from person-to-person lending portfolios. Management Science, 63(2), 279–297.CrossRef
48.
Zurück zum Zitat Parker, S. C. (2014). Crowdfunding, cascades, and informed investors. Economics Letters, 125(3), 432–435.CrossRef Parker, S. C. (2014). Crowdfunding, cascades, and informed investors. Economics Letters, 125(3), 432–435.CrossRef
49.
Zurück zum Zitat Price, P. C., & Stone, E. R. (2004). Intuitive evaluation of likelihood judgment producers: Evidence for a confidence heuristic. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 17(1), 39–57.CrossRef Price, P. C., & Stone, E. R. (2004). Intuitive evaluation of likelihood judgment producers: Evidence for a confidence heuristic. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 17(1), 39–57.CrossRef
50.
Zurück zum Zitat Sauermann, H., Franzoni, C., & Shafi, K. (2019). Crowdfunding scientific research: Descriptive insights and correlates of funding success. PLoS ONE, 14(1), e0208384.CrossRef Sauermann, H., Franzoni, C., & Shafi, K. (2019). Crowdfunding scientific research: Descriptive insights and correlates of funding success. PLoS ONE, 14(1), e0208384.CrossRef
51.
Zurück zum Zitat Scheaf, D. J., Davis, B. C., Webb, J. W., Coombs, J. E., Borns, J., & Holloway, G. (2018). Signals’ flexibility and interaction with visual cues: Insights from crowdfunding. Journal of Business Venturing, 33(6), 720–741.CrossRef Scheaf, D. J., Davis, B. C., Webb, J. W., Coombs, J. E., Borns, J., & Holloway, G. (2018). Signals’ flexibility and interaction with visual cues: Insights from crowdfunding. Journal of Business Venturing, 33(6), 720–741.CrossRef
52.
Zurück zum Zitat Slovic, P., & Lichtenstein, S. (1971). Comparison of Bayesian and regression approaches to the study of information processing in judgment. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 6(6), 649–744.CrossRef Slovic, P., & Lichtenstein, S. (1971). Comparison of Bayesian and regression approaches to the study of information processing in judgment. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 6(6), 649–744.CrossRef
53.
Zurück zum Zitat Stevenson, R. M., Ciuchta, M. P., Letwin, C., Dinger, J. M., & Vancouver, J. B. (2019). Out of control or right on the money? Funder self-efficacy and crowd bias in equity crowdfunding. Journal of Business Venturing, 34(2), 348–367.CrossRef Stevenson, R. M., Ciuchta, M. P., Letwin, C., Dinger, J. M., & Vancouver, J. B. (2019). Out of control or right on the money? Funder self-efficacy and crowd bias in equity crowdfunding. Journal of Business Venturing, 34(2), 348–367.CrossRef
54.
Zurück zum Zitat Stiglitz, J. E. (1975). The theory of “screening.” Education, and the distribution of income. American Economic Review, 65(3), 283–300. Stiglitz, J. E. (1975). The theory of “screening.” Education, and the distribution of income. American Economic Review, 65(3), 283–300.
55.
Zurück zum Zitat Strausz, R. (2017). A theory of crowdfunding: A mechanism design approach with demand uncertainty and moral hazard. American Economic Review, 107(6), 1430–1476.CrossRef Strausz, R. (2017). A theory of crowdfunding: A mechanism design approach with demand uncertainty and moral hazard. American Economic Review, 107(6), 1430–1476.CrossRef
56.
Zurück zum Zitat Welch, I. (1992). Sequential sales, learning, and cascades. Journal of Finance, 47(2), 695–732.CrossRef Welch, I. (1992). Sequential sales, learning, and cascades. Journal of Finance, 47(2), 695–732.CrossRef
57.
Zurück zum Zitat Woolley, A. W., Chabris, C. F., Pentland, A., Hashmi, N., & Malone, T. W. (2010). Evidence for a collective intelligence factor in the performance of human groups. Science, 330(6004), 686–688.CrossRef Woolley, A. W., Chabris, C. F., Pentland, A., Hashmi, N., & Malone, T. W. (2010). Evidence for a collective intelligence factor in the performance of human groups. Science, 330(6004), 686–688.CrossRef
58.
Zurück zum Zitat Wright, M., & Lockett, A. (2003). The structure and management of alliances: Syndication in the venture capital industry. Journal of Management Studies, 40(8), 2073–2102.CrossRef Wright, M., & Lockett, A. (2003). The structure and management of alliances: Syndication in the venture capital industry. Journal of Management Studies, 40(8), 2073–2102.CrossRef
59.
Zurück zum Zitat Zacharakis, A. L., & Meyer, G. D. (1998). A lack of insight: Do venture capitalists really understand their own decision process? Journal of Business Venturing, 13(1), 57–76.CrossRef Zacharakis, A. L., & Meyer, G. D. (1998). A lack of insight: Do venture capitalists really understand their own decision process? Journal of Business Venturing, 13(1), 57–76.CrossRef
60.
Zurück zum Zitat Zacharakis, A. L., & Meyer, G. D. (2000). The potential of actuarial decision models: Can they improve the venture capital investment decision? Journal of Business Venturing, 15(4), 323–346.CrossRef Zacharakis, A. L., & Meyer, G. D. (2000). The potential of actuarial decision models: Can they improve the venture capital investment decision? Journal of Business Venturing, 15(4), 323–346.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Crowdfunding as a screener for collective investment
verfasst von
Sha Zhou
Tao Ma
Zhengchi Liu
Publikationsdatum
29.03.2021
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Electronic Commerce Research / Ausgabe 1/2021
Print ISSN: 1389-5753
Elektronische ISSN: 1572-9362
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-021-09461-4

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1/2021

Electronic Commerce Research 1/2021 Zur Ausgabe