Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 3-4/2014

01.12.2014

Explaining variation in the competitiveness of U.S. Senate elections, 1922–2004

verfasst von: Stanley L. Winer, Lawrence W. Kenny, Bernard Grofman

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 3-4/2014

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We develop and test predictions about the factors determining the competitiveness of elections to the U.S. Senate. To do so, we deliberately abstract away from candidate-specific conditions that have often been used to study political competitiveness in order to focus on basic structural features of the electoral landscape. In our framework, party-specific constraints on the ideological positioning of local candidates, linked to the national party organization and its contributors, interact with the heterogeneity of state electorates to determine the number of highly competitive Senate contests. Three hypotheses emerge from this model: (1) the greater the diversity of a party’s national legislative delegation, the more highly competitive Senate elections we will observe; (2) states in which the ideological heterogeneity of the electorate is relatively high will exhibit a greater number of highly competitive elections; and (3) highly competitive Senate contests will be more common in states with closed primaries than in states with open primaries. We provide strong evidence in support of the first two hypotheses and some evidence in support of the third.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
In a mature democratic system, political competition involves party and candidate entry across elections; competition for votes in elections; and competition within legislatures (or among different governments) between elections. Here we limit ourselves to the second of these aspects. Even though we do so, the literature on just this part of the general topic is substantial. There is a large literature starting with Downs (1957) that deals with how electoral competition affects voter turnout (e.g., Filer and Kenny 1980; Cox and Munger 1989; Endersby et al. 2002; Franklin 2004), and there are a smaller number of papers on how variation in competitiveness influences public policy, some addressing this question using data from U.S. states (e.g., Levitt and Poterba 1999 and Besley et al. 2010) or using data from other countries (Remmer and Wibbels 2000; Ferris et al. 2008; Galasso and Nannicini 2011). Also, regression discontinuity studies have focused on the candidates in close elections (e.g., Lee et al. 2004; Ferreira and Gyourko 2007; Pettersson-Lidbom 2008; Caughey and Sekhon 2011). Political competition has also been studied as a dependent variable. One component of this literature, also inspired by Downs, models candidate success by studying platform positioning relative to the median voter (e.g., Ansolabehere et al. 2001; Austen-Smith 1987; Gerber and Lewis 2004; Robertson 1976; Roemer 2001).
 
2
A large literature has sought to understand competitiveness in individual contests by focusing on factors such as candidate experience and funding (e.g., Berry and Canon 1993; Jacobson 2006; Francis and Kenny 2000). In our pursuit of institutional and structural factors that affect competitiveness, rather than individual characteristics of competitors, we follow Taagepera and Shugart (1989) and Taagepera (1999, 2007), among others.
 
3
Our work on the Senate can be thought of as complementary to the body of work inspired by Mayhew (1974), referred to as the 'vanishing marginals' literature, that is concerned with trends in the competitiveness of contests for the US House of Representatives. For example, Abramowitz et al. (2006) support the finding that redistricting is not the primary villain in reducing political competition in the US House, but argue that increasing polarization has led to a larger number of non-competitive seats. Jacobson (2006) reviews work seeking to account for the decline of competition in the House. Merrill et al. (forthcoming) is conceptually related to our explanatory conundrum; they ask, how, with no change in electoral rules, levels of mean party polarization in the U.S. House can dramatically vary over time. See also the discussion of the importance of constraints on candidate locations in Grofman (1987).
 
4
In virtually all models of party formation, when voters differ ideologically, parties form in a way that separates them along ideological lines. See, for example, Aldrich (1983), Gomberg et al. (2004), Moon (2004), Poutvaara (2003), and Snyder and Ting (2002).
 
5
The 17th Amendment to the Constitution providing for direct election of Senators was approved in 1913, and elections were phased in over the next several years. By 1922, all elections to the Senate were direct.
 
6
We note that averaging over time is essential in the present context because a big win in any one election does not establish a systematic pattern of deviation from a regime of close contests. (Buchler (2009) has argued that a big win from time to time may be required to incentivize political parties in a democratic system.) A Methodological Appendix, available on Stanley Winer's website: www.​carleton.​ca/​~winers, contains the rationale for averaging over 12-year periods and the robustness of our results to alternative periodization strategies.
 
7
Later we disaggregate data by region as well as by time period. Inspection of the data on which Table 1 is based shows that variation in competitiveness occurs across states within a given time period as well as over time.
 
8
While changes in the sizes of state populations (Hibbing and Brandes 1983) might be a candidate for such a theory, it cannot account for the types of variation we observe in the Table 1 data. Another explanatory candidate is political realignment. Below and in the on-line Appendix we consider how to take realignment related effects into account; this does not affect our conclusions.
 
9
In contrast with a too simple reading of Downs (1957), in two-party plurality competition convergence of candidates to the median in the constituency should not be expected. Rather, for a plethora of reasons (see e.g., Calvert and Isaac 1981; Palfrey 1984, 1989; Poole and Rosenthal 1984; Wuffle et al. 1989; Grofman et al. 1990; Coughlin 1992; Ansolabehere et al. 2001; Grofman 2004; Adams et al. 2005; Callander 2005; Schofield and Sened 2006; and Hussey and Zaller 2011), we should expect to see candidates located somewhere between their national party median and the constituency median. It is useful to recall that Downs himself (1957, p. 98) saw problems with convergence as an electoral strategy: "Citizens see little point in voting if all choices are identical, so differences between platforms must be created to entice voters to the polls."
 
10
On this point see, for example, Jacobsen (2006) and Masket (2009). On the particular importance of out-of-state campaign financing, the need for which constrains local candidates, see Sorauf (1992) and Marshall (1998). For data concerning out-of-state financing from 2000 to 2010, see www.​opensecrets.​org.
 
11
In recent elections, newspaper articles have associated this sort of constraint on the policy location of Republican candidates with the rise of the “Tea Party,” and the subsequent loss of some moderate Republicans to primary challenges.
 
12
Callander (2005), for example, explores a setting in which national parties compete simultaneously for multiple districts of heterogeneous voters. In his national party model, the party selects the platform that will be espoused by all of its candidates in every district. In this case, he shows that the national parties select different platforms in equilibrium.
 
13
For example, in the 109th Congress, in the US House of Representatives DW-Nominate range is about 2. If we look only at the 235 Republicans, DW-nominate scores ranged from 0.136 to 1.0281, with a mean of 0.518 and a standard deviation of 0.167.
 
14
Conceptual models that predict this stylized fact are, however, hard to find in the existing literature. One exception is recent work by Polborn (2014).
 
15
This prediction has received some empirical support. See for example, Gerber and Morton (1998) and others cited below.
 
16
Empirically we have seen that divergence is established by the DW-Nominate data. Theoretically, one can look at models by Coleman (1971, 1972), Aranson and Ordeshook (1972) and many others since.
 
17
We take the Palfrey model only as illustrative of models predicting divergence and we are, for present purposes, agnostic about the exact causes of candidate divergence. Concerning the Palfrey model, see also Greenberg and Shepsle (1987), Palfrey (1989), and Osborne (1993).
 
18
Complexities caused by competition over multiple dimensions are beyond the scope of this paper.
 
19
Cf. Esiasson (1999). To escape the constraint, the local candidate may substitute personal funds for party funds, or rely on a cult of personality. In the first case, we should expect that candidates facing a relatively hostile national party will tend to self-finance to a greater extent, and in the extreme we may see independent, largely self-financed candidates such as Ross Perot. Testing these predictions is left for future research.
 
20
Cf. Carsey and Harden (2010) and Harden and Carsey (2012).
 
21
We could consider an increase in the dispersion of voters in selected states where the constraint is binding, with analogous qualitative consequences.
 
22
In Callander's National Party-type model, heterogeneity of the electorate is a key determinant of national party platform divergence and of the number of parties in equilibrium. But he is not concerned with explaining variation in the competitiveness of local elections illustrated in Table 1. Froman (1963), Bond (1983) and Koetzle (1998) examine the impact of the heterogeneity on competition empirically, but the evidence in this literature is, on our reading, inconsistent.
 
23
Effects of changes in within-party heterogeneity should be distinguished from effects of a change in between-party caucus polarization, even though the two are empirically correlated. If between-party caucus polarization reflects generally the degree of polarization in, or dispersion of, preferences in local electorates represented by d in the simple model, the result of that development can be predicted using the Mixed Influence Model: a decrease (increase) in between-party caucus polarization will result in fewer (more) highly competitive races, because existing party-specific constraints are then binding in more (fewer) places.
 
24
We assume that in open primaries there is no strategic voting in which Republicans, for example, vote for the Democratic candidate who would be the weakest candidate in the general election.
 
25
Snyder and Ting (2011, p. 783) assert: “[with] primaries, all but the most moderate constituencies are dominated by one party.”
 
27
Our use of 12-year terms is defended in the on-line Appendix. We recall that averaging is also essential because a big win or loss in any one election does not signal systematic variation in competitiveness.
 
28
For example, in the 2004 presidential election, Massachusetts had the smallest share of votes cast for G. W. Bush (0.37) and was coded as 0.02 (=1/50). Utah cast the largest share of votes for Bush (0.73) and was coded as 1(=50/50). Using a rank relative to the number of states included in that election’s returns also allows us to control for omission of observations due to third party success and to control for a gain of observations because of the entry of Alaska and Hawaii into the union in 1959.
 
29
On the empirical importance of homogeneity in the party caucus for party cohesion and strength in Congress and its implications for public expenditure, see Winer et al. (2008).
 
30
In 1954–1955, the wording was “voters receive ballots of [one party] or [both parties].”
 
31
The same caveat applies, of course, to Republican candidates in very liberal states.
 
32
To construct the open seat sample, election races with incumbents are excluded from the raw data, and the 12-year averages are then recomputed.
 
33
The procedure of choosing break points that minimize a mean squared error is similar to that used in maximum likelihood estimation.
 
34
The literature on primaries and platform selection is complex, as one of the reviewers has stressed. For example, Kanthak and Morton (2001) argue that this relationship is non-linear. Furthermore, open primaries may lead more than two candidates to enter the primary, making it difficult to assess the impact on platform selection, and thus on competition. The theoretical ambiguity in the effect of open primaries on political competition certainly may a role in accounting for the relatively weak empirical support for open primaries having some effect on political competition. See also Snyder and Ting (2011).
 
35
The large national media surveys done by Gallop, CBS/NY Times, and so on are less desirable for measuring a state’s variance in voter ideology because they don’t extend back very far and rely on a crude three-category (conservative, moderate, liberal) measure of voter preferences. Robert Erikson, in an October 1, 2009 email, laments that with these data “opinion heterogeneity is very difficult to impossible to measure.” We note also that there are other survey measures of state level ideology used, for example, in Harden and Carsey (2012) in work that also points to the importance of heterogeneity of local electorates, though it is not concerned with explaining competitiveness. But these surveys are available for only a few, more recent years. Here see also Ensley (2012, pp. 43–44).
 
36
And we earlier noted that a further reason for constraints on local candidates is that swing voters, exposed to messages from the national party, may not believe that a Republican candidate, for example, is as liberal as he or she claims to be.
 
37
We note that Gerber and Lewis (2004) have explored the role of heterogeneity in voter preferences. They find that the influence of a district’s median ideology on the voting record of the district’s elected officials is greater in homogeneous (low variance of voter preferences) districts than in heterogeneous ones. This result is difficult to interpret because the regression also contains a variable for party ideology that is appropriate in a divergent platform regression but not in one based on the median voter model.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Abramowitz, A. I., Alexander, B., & Gunning, M. (2006). Incumbency, redistricting, and the decline of competition in US house elections. Journal of Politics, 68(1), 75–88.CrossRef Abramowitz, A. I., Alexander, B., & Gunning, M. (2006). Incumbency, redistricting, and the decline of competition in US house elections. Journal of Politics, 68(1), 75–88.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Adams, J., Merrill, S., & Grofman, B. (2005). A unified theory of party competition: A cross-national analysis integrating spatial and behavioral Factors. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Adams, J., Merrill, S., & Grofman, B. (2005). A unified theory of party competition: A cross-national analysis integrating spatial and behavioral Factors. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Aldrich, J. H. (1983). A Downsian spatial model with party activism. American Political Science Review, 77(4), 974–990.CrossRef Aldrich, J. H. (1983). A Downsian spatial model with party activism. American Political Science Review, 77(4), 974–990.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Aldrich, J. H., & Battista, J. S. (2002). Conditional party government in the states. American Journal of Political Science, 46(1), 164–172.CrossRef Aldrich, J. H., & Battista, J. S. (2002). Conditional party government in the states. American Journal of Political Science, 46(1), 164–172.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Aldrich, J. H., & Rohde, D. W. (1998). Measuring conditional party government. Presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association. Aldrich, J. H., & Rohde, D. W. (1998). Measuring conditional party government. Presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association.
Zurück zum Zitat Aldrich, J. H., & Rohde, D. W. (2000). The Republican revolution and the house appropriations committee. Journal of Politics, 62, 1–33. Aldrich, J. H., & Rohde, D. W. (2000). The Republican revolution and the house appropriations committee. Journal of Politics, 62, 1–33.
Zurück zum Zitat Aldrich, J. H., Rohde, D. W., & Tofias, M. (2007). One D is not enough: Measuring conditional party government, 1887–2002. In D. Brady & M. McCubbins (Eds.), Party, process, and political change in congress (Vol. 2, pp. 102–112). Stanford: Stanford University Press. Aldrich, J. H., Rohde, D. W., & Tofias, M. (2007). One D is not enough: Measuring conditional party government, 1887–2002. In D. Brady & M. McCubbins (Eds.), Party, process, and political change in congress (Vol. 2, pp. 102–112). Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Ansolabehere, S., Snyder, J. M., Jr., & Stewart, C., III (2001). Candidate positioning in US house elections. American Journal of Political Science, 45(1), 136–159.CrossRef Ansolabehere, S., Snyder, J. M., Jr., & Stewart, C., III (2001). Candidate positioning in US house elections. American Journal of Political Science, 45(1), 136–159.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Aranson, P. H., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1972). Spatial strategies for sequential elections. In G. Niemi & H. F. Weisberg (Eds.), Probability models of collective decision making (pp. 298–331). Columbus, OH: Charles Merrill. Aranson, P. H., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1972). Spatial strategies for sequential elections. In G. Niemi & H. F. Weisberg (Eds.), Probability models of collective decision making (pp. 298–331). Columbus, OH: Charles Merrill.
Zurück zum Zitat Austen-Smith, D. (1984). Two-party competition with many constituencies. Mathematical Social Sciences, 7(2), 177–198.CrossRef Austen-Smith, D. (1984). Two-party competition with many constituencies. Mathematical Social Sciences, 7(2), 177–198.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Austen-Smith, D. (1987). Parties, districts and the spatial theory of elections. Social Choice and Welfare, 4(1), 9–23.CrossRef Austen-Smith, D. (1987). Parties, districts and the spatial theory of elections. Social Choice and Welfare, 4(1), 9–23.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berry, W. D., & Canon, B. C. (1993). Explaining the competitiveness of gubernatorial primaries. Journal of Politics, 55(2), 454–471.CrossRef Berry, W. D., & Canon, B. C. (1993). Explaining the competitiveness of gubernatorial primaries. Journal of Politics, 55(2), 454–471.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Besley, T., Persson, T., & Sturm, D. M. (2010). Political competition, policy and growth: Theory and evidence from the United States. Review of Economic Studies, 77, 1329–1352.CrossRef Besley, T., Persson, T., & Sturm, D. M. (2010). Political competition, policy and growth: Theory and evidence from the United States. Review of Economic Studies, 77, 1329–1352.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bibby, J. F. (1992). Politics, parties, and elections in America (2nd ed.). Chicago: Nelson-Hall Publishers. Bibby, J. F. (1992). Politics, parties, and elections in America (2nd ed.). Chicago: Nelson-Hall Publishers.
Zurück zum Zitat Bibby, J. F. (1996). Politics, parties, and elections in America (3rd ed.). Chicago: Nelson-Hall Publishers. Bibby, J. F. (1996). Politics, parties, and elections in America (3rd ed.). Chicago: Nelson-Hall Publishers.
Zurück zum Zitat Bibby, J. F. (2000). Politics, parties, and elections in America (4th ed.). Belmont, CA: Wadsworth Publishers. Bibby, J. F. (2000). Politics, parties, and elections in America (4th ed.). Belmont, CA: Wadsworth Publishers.
Zurück zum Zitat Bibby, J. F., & Schaffner, B. F. (2008). Politics, parties, and elections in America (4th ed.). Boston, MA: Thomson Wadsworth Publishers. Bibby, J. F., & Schaffner, B. F. (2008). Politics, parties, and elections in America (4th ed.). Boston, MA: Thomson Wadsworth Publishers.
Zurück zum Zitat Bond, J. R. (1983). The influence of constituency diversity on electoral competition in voting for congress, 1974–1978. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 7, 201–217.CrossRef Bond, J. R. (1983). The influence of constituency diversity on electoral competition in voting for congress, 1974–1978. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 7, 201–217.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bott, A. J. (1990). Handbook of US election laws and practices. New York: Greenwood Press. Bott, A. J. (1990). Handbook of US election laws and practices. New York: Greenwood Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Buchler, J. (2009). Rejoinder to ‘the sub-optimality of competitive elections: Comment. Public Choice, 138, 1–2.CrossRef Buchler, J. (2009). Rejoinder to ‘the sub-optimality of competitive elections: Comment. Public Choice, 138, 1–2.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Callander, S. (2005). Electoral competition in heterogeneous districts. Journal of Political Economy, 13, 1116–1145.CrossRef Callander, S. (2005). Electoral competition in heterogeneous districts. Journal of Political Economy, 13, 1116–1145.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Calvert, R. L., & Isaac, R. M. (1981). The inherent disadvantage of the presidential party in midterm congressional elections. Public Choice, 36, 141–146.CrossRef Calvert, R. L., & Isaac, R. M. (1981). The inherent disadvantage of the presidential party in midterm congressional elections. Public Choice, 36, 141–146.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carsey, T. M., & Harden, J. J. (2010). New measures of partisanship, ideology, and policy mood in the American states. State Politics & Policy Quarterly, 10(2), 138–158.CrossRef Carsey, T. M., & Harden, J. J. (2010). New measures of partisanship, ideology, and policy mood in the American states. State Politics & Policy Quarterly, 10(2), 138–158.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Caughey, D., & Sekhon, J. S. (2011). Elections and the regression discontinuity design: Lessons from close US houses, 1942–2008. Political Analysis, 19, 385–408.CrossRef Caughey, D., & Sekhon, J. S. (2011). Elections and the regression discontinuity design: Lessons from close US houses, 1942–2008. Political Analysis, 19, 385–408.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Coleman, J. S. (1971). Internal processes governing party positions in elections. Public Choice, 11, 35–60.CrossRef Coleman, J. S. (1971). Internal processes governing party positions in elections. Public Choice, 11, 35–60.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Coleman, J. S. (1972). The positions of political parties in elections. In R. G. Niemi & H. F. Weisberg (Eds.), Probability models of collective decision making (pp. 332–357). Columbus, OH: Charles E. Merrill. Coleman, J. S. (1972). The positions of political parties in elections. In R. G. Niemi & H. F. Weisberg (Eds.), Probability models of collective decision making (pp. 332–357). Columbus, OH: Charles E. Merrill.
Zurück zum Zitat Coughlin, P. (1992). Probabilistic voting theory. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Coughlin, P. (1992). Probabilistic voting theory. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Council of State Governments. (various years). The book of the states. Lexington, KY. Council of State Governments. (various years). The book of the states. Lexington, KY.
Zurück zum Zitat Cox, G., & Munger, M. C. (1989). Contributions, expenditure, turnout: The 1982 US house elections. American Political Science Review, 83, 217–231.CrossRef Cox, G., & Munger, M. C. (1989). Contributions, expenditure, turnout: The 1982 US house elections. American Political Science Review, 83, 217–231.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row. Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.
Zurück zum Zitat Endersby, J., Galatas, S., & Rackaway, C. (2002). Closeness counts in Canada: Voter participation in the 1993 and 1997 Federal Elections. Journal of Politics, 64(2), 610–631.CrossRef Endersby, J., Galatas, S., & Rackaway, C. (2002). Closeness counts in Canada: Voter participation in the 1993 and 1997 Federal Elections. Journal of Politics, 64(2), 610–631.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ensley, M. J. (2012). Incumbent positioning, ideological heterogeneity and mobilization in US house elections. Public Choice, 151, 43–61.CrossRef Ensley, M. J. (2012). Incumbent positioning, ideological heterogeneity and mobilization in US house elections. Public Choice, 151, 43–61.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Esiasson, P. (1999). Not all politics is local: The geographic dimension of policy representation. In W. E. Miller, R. Pierce, J. Thomassen, R. Herrera, S. Holmberg, P. Esiasson, & B. Wessels (Eds.), Policy representation in Western Democracies (pp. 110–136). Oxford: Oxford University Press. Esiasson, P. (1999). Not all politics is local: The geographic dimension of policy representation. In W. E. Miller, R. Pierce, J. Thomassen, R. Herrera, S. Holmberg, P. Esiasson, & B. Wessels (Eds.), Policy representation in Western Democracies (pp. 110–136). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Ferreira, F., & Gyourko, J. (2007). Do political parties matter? Evidence from US Cities. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(1), 349–397. Ferreira, F., & Gyourko, J. (2007). Do political parties matter? Evidence from US Cities. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(1), 349–397.
Zurück zum Zitat Ferris, J. S., Park, S. B., & Winer, S. L. (2008). Studying the role of political competition in the evolution of government size over long horizons. Public Choice, 137, 369–401.CrossRef Ferris, J. S., Park, S. B., & Winer, S. L. (2008). Studying the role of political competition in the evolution of government size over long horizons. Public Choice, 137, 369–401.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Filer, J. E., & Kenny, L. W. (1980). Voter turnout and the benefits of voting. Public Choice, 35(5), 575–585.CrossRef Filer, J. E., & Kenny, L. W. (1980). Voter turnout and the benefits of voting. Public Choice, 35(5), 575–585.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Francis, W. L., & Kenny, L. W. (2000). Up the political ladder: Career paths in US politics. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Francis, W. L., & Kenny, L. W. (2000). Up the political ladder: Career paths in US politics. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Zurück zum Zitat Franklin, M. (2004). Voter turnout and the dynamics of electoral competition in established democracies since 1945. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Franklin, M. (2004). Voter turnout and the dynamics of electoral competition in established democracies since 1945. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Froman, L. A. (1963). Congressmen and their constituencies. Chicago: Rand McNally & Co. Froman, L. A. (1963). Congressmen and their constituencies. Chicago: Rand McNally & Co.
Zurück zum Zitat Galasso, V., & Nannicini, T. (2011). Competing on good politicians. American Political Science Review, 105(1), 79–99.CrossRef Galasso, V., & Nannicini, T. (2011). Competing on good politicians. American Political Science Review, 105(1), 79–99.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gerber, E., & Lewis, J. B. (2004). Beyond the median: Voter preferences, district heterogeneity, and political representation. Journal of Political Economy, 112, 1364–1383.CrossRef Gerber, E., & Lewis, J. B. (2004). Beyond the median: Voter preferences, district heterogeneity, and political representation. Journal of Political Economy, 112, 1364–1383.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gerber, E., & Morton, R. B. (1998). Primary election systems and representation. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 11, 304–324.CrossRef Gerber, E., & Morton, R. B. (1998). Primary election systems and representation. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 11, 304–324.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goff, B. L., & Grier, K. B. (1993). On the (mis)measurement of legislator ideology and shirking. Public Choice, 76, 5–20.CrossRef Goff, B. L., & Grier, K. B. (1993). On the (mis)measurement of legislator ideology and shirking. Public Choice, 76, 5–20.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gomberg, A. M., Marhuenda, F., & Ortuno-Ortin, I. (2004). A model of endogenous political party platforms. Economic Theory, 24, 373–394.CrossRef Gomberg, A. M., Marhuenda, F., & Ortuno-Ortin, I. (2004). A model of endogenous political party platforms. Economic Theory, 24, 373–394.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Greenberg, J., & Shepsle, K. (1987). The effect of electoral rewards in multiparty competition with entry. American Political Science Review, 81, 525–538.CrossRef Greenberg, J., & Shepsle, K. (1987). The effect of electoral rewards in multiparty competition with entry. American Political Science Review, 81, 525–538.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grofman, B. (1987). Models of voting. In Samuel Long (Ed.), Micropolitics annual (pp. 31–61). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. Grofman, B. (1987). Models of voting. In Samuel Long (Ed.), Micropolitics annual (pp. 31–61). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Grofman, B. (2004). Downs and two-party convergence. Annual Review of Political Science, 7, 25–46.CrossRef Grofman, B. (2004). Downs and two-party convergence. Annual Review of Political Science, 7, 25–46.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grofman, B., & Brunell, T. (2001). Explaining the ideological differences between the two US Senators elected from the same state: An institutional effects model. In Galderisi (Ed.), Congressional primaries in the politics of representation (pp. 132–142). New York: Rowman & Littlefield. Grofman, B., & Brunell, T. (2001). Explaining the ideological differences between the two US Senators elected from the same state: An institutional effects model. In Galderisi (Ed.), Congressional primaries in the politics of representation (pp. 132–142). New York: Rowman & Littlefield.
Zurück zum Zitat Grofman, B., Griffin, R., & Glazer, Amihai. (1990). Identical geography, different party: A natural experiment on the magnitude of party differences in the US Senate. In R. J. Johnston, F. M. Shelley, & P. J. Taylor (Eds.), Developments in electoral geography (pp. 1960–1984). London: Routledge. Grofman, B., Griffin, R., & Glazer, Amihai. (1990). Identical geography, different party: A natural experiment on the magnitude of party differences in the US Senate. In R. J. Johnston, F. M. Shelley, & P. J. Taylor (Eds.), Developments in electoral geography (pp. 1960–1984). London: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Harden, J., & Carsey, T. M. (2012). Balancing constituency representation and party responsiveness in the US senate: The conditioning effect of state ideological heterogeneity. Public Choice, 150, 137–154.CrossRef Harden, J., & Carsey, T. M. (2012). Balancing constituency representation and party responsiveness in the US senate: The conditioning effect of state ideological heterogeneity. Public Choice, 150, 137–154.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Heckelman, J. C. (2004). A spatial model of US senate elections. Public Choice, 118, 87–103.CrossRef Heckelman, J. C. (2004). A spatial model of US senate elections. Public Choice, 118, 87–103.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hibbing, J., & Brandes, S. (1983). State population and the electoral success of senators. American Journal of Political Science, 27, 808–819.CrossRef Hibbing, J., & Brandes, S. (1983). State population and the electoral success of senators. American Journal of Political Science, 27, 808–819.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hussey, W., & Zaller, J. (2011). Who do parties represent? In P. K. Enns & C. Wlezien (Eds.), Who gets represented? (p. 82). New York: Russell Sage. Hussey, W., & Zaller, J. (2011). Who do parties represent? In P. K. Enns & C. Wlezien (Eds.), Who gets represented? (p. 82). New York: Russell Sage.
Zurück zum Zitat Jacobson, G. (2006). The politics of Congressional elections (7th ed.). New York: Longman. Jacobson, G. (2006). The politics of Congressional elections (7th ed.). New York: Longman.
Zurück zum Zitat Kanthak, K., & Morton, R. B. (2001). The effects of primary systems on congressional elections. In P. Galderisi & M. Lyons (Eds.), Congressional primaries and the politics of representation. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield. Kanthak, K., & Morton, R. B. (2001). The effects of primary systems on congressional elections. In P. Galderisi & M. Lyons (Eds.), Congressional primaries and the politics of representation. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield.
Zurück zum Zitat Koetzle, W. (1998). The impact of constituency diversity upon the competitiveness of U.S. House elections, 1962–96. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 23(4), 561–573.CrossRef Koetzle, W. (1998). The impact of constituency diversity upon the competitiveness of U.S. House elections, 1962–96. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 23(4), 561–573.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lee, D. S., Moretti, E., & Butler, M. J. (2004). Do voters affect or elect policies? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 807–859.CrossRef Lee, D. S., Moretti, E., & Butler, M. J. (2004). Do voters affect or elect policies? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 807–859.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Levitt, S. D., & Poterba, J. M. (1999). Congressional distributive politics and state economic performance. Public Choice, 99, 185–215.CrossRef Levitt, S. D., & Poterba, J. M. (1999). Congressional distributive politics and state economic performance. Public Choice, 99, 185–215.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Marshall, W. (1998). American political culture and the failures of process federalism. Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy, 22, 139. Marshall, W. (1998). American political culture and the failures of process federalism. Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy, 22, 139.
Zurück zum Zitat Masket, G. (2009). No middle ground: How informal party organizations control nominations and polarize legislatures. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press. Masket, G. (2009). No middle ground: How informal party organizations control nominations and polarize legislatures. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Mayhew, D. R. (1974). Congressional elections: The case of the vanishing marginals. Polity, 6(3), 295–317.CrossRef Mayhew, D. R. (1974). Congressional elections: The case of the vanishing marginals. Polity, 6(3), 295–317.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Merrill, S., III, Grofman, B., & Brunell, T. L. (forthcoming). Modeling the electoral dynamics of party polarization in two-party legislatures. Journal of Theoretical Politics. Merrill, S., III, Grofman, B., & Brunell, T. L. (forthcoming). Modeling the electoral dynamics of party polarization in two-party legislatures. Journal of Theoretical Politics.
Zurück zum Zitat Moon, W. (2004). Party activists, campaign resources and candidate position taking: Theory, tests and applications. British Journal Political Science, 34, 611–633.CrossRef Moon, W. (2004). Party activists, campaign resources and candidate position taking: Theory, tests and applications. British Journal Political Science, 34, 611–633.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Moore, J. L., Preimesberger, J. P., & Tarr, D. R. (Eds.). (2001). Congressional quarterly’s guide to US elections (4th ed.). Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly Press. Moore, J. L., Preimesberger, J. P., & Tarr, D. R. (Eds.). (2001). Congressional quarterly’s guide to US elections (4th ed.). Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Osborne, M. J. (1993). Candidate positioning and entry in political competition. Games and Economic Behavior, 5(1), 133–151.CrossRef Osborne, M. J. (1993). Candidate positioning and entry in political competition. Games and Economic Behavior, 5(1), 133–151.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Palfrey, T. R. (1984). Spatial equilibrium with entry. Review of Economic Studies, 51, 139–157.CrossRef Palfrey, T. R. (1984). Spatial equilibrium with entry. Review of Economic Studies, 51, 139–157.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Palfrey, T. R. (1989). A mathematical proof of Duverger’s law. In P. C. Ordeshook (Ed.), Models of strategic choice in politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Palfrey, T. R. (1989). A mathematical proof of Duverger’s law. In P. C. Ordeshook (Ed.), Models of strategic choice in politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Pettersson-Lidbom, P. (2008). Do parties matter for economic outcomes? A regression-discontinuity approach. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6, 1037–1056.CrossRef Pettersson-Lidbom, P. (2008). Do parties matter for economic outcomes? A regression-discontinuity approach. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6, 1037–1056.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Polborn, M. (2014). Political competition in legislative elections. Presented at the Economics Seminar, University of California, Irvine, January 13. Polborn, M. (2014). Political competition in legislative elections. Presented at the Economics Seminar, University of California, Irvine, January 13.
Zurück zum Zitat Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1984). The polarization of American politics. Journal of Politics, XLVI, 102–131. Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1984). The polarization of American politics. Journal of Politics, XLVI, 102–131.
Zurück zum Zitat Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1997). Congress: A political economic history of roll call voting. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1997). Congress: A political economic history of roll call voting. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Poutvaara, P. (2003). Party platforms with endogenous party membership. Public Choice, 117, 79–98.CrossRef Poutvaara, P. (2003). Party platforms with endogenous party membership. Public Choice, 117, 79–98.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Remmer, K. L., & Wibbels, E. (2000). The subnational politics of economic adjustment. Comparative Political Studies, 33(4), 419–451.CrossRef Remmer, K. L., & Wibbels, E. (2000). The subnational politics of economic adjustment. Comparative Political Studies, 33(4), 419–451.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Robertson, D. (1976). A theory of party competition. London: Wiley. Robertson, D. (1976). A theory of party competition. London: Wiley.
Zurück zum Zitat Roemer, J. E. (2001). Political competition: Theory and applications. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Roemer, J. E. (2001). Political competition: Theory and applications. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Scammon, R. M., McGillivray, A. V., & Cook, R. (Various years). America votes: Election returns by state. Washington, DC: CQ Press. Scammon, R. M., McGillivray, A. V., & Cook, R. (Various years). America votes: Election returns by state. Washington, DC: CQ Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Schofield, N., & Sened, I. (2006). Multiparty democracy: Elections and legislative behavior. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Schofield, N., & Sened, I. (2006). Multiparty democracy: Elections and legislative behavior. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Snyder, J. M., Jr., & Ting, M. M. (2002). An informational rationale for political parties. American Journal of Political Science, 46(1), 90–110.CrossRef Snyder, J. M., Jr., & Ting, M. M. (2002). An informational rationale for political parties. American Journal of Political Science, 46(1), 90–110.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Snyder, J. M., Jr., & Ting, M. M. (2011). Electoral selection with parties and primaries. American Journal of Political Science, 55(4), 782–796.CrossRef Snyder, J. M., Jr., & Ting, M. M. (2011). Electoral selection with parties and primaries. American Journal of Political Science, 55(4), 782–796.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sorauf, F. J. (1992). Inside campaign finance: Myths and realities. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Sorauf, F. J. (1992). Inside campaign finance: Myths and realities. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Taagepera, R. (1999). Ignorance-based quantitative models and their practical implications. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 11(3), 421–431.CrossRef Taagepera, R. (1999). Ignorance-based quantitative models and their practical implications. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 11(3), 421–431.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Taagepera, R. (2007). Predicting party sizes: The logic of simple electoral systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef Taagepera, R. (2007). Predicting party sizes: The logic of simple electoral systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Taagepera, R., & Shugart, M. (1989). Seats and votes: The effects and determinants of electoral systems. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Taagepera, R., & Shugart, M. (1989). Seats and votes: The effects and determinants of electoral systems. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Winer, S. L., Tofias, M., Grofman, B., & Aldrich, J. (2008). Is it economics or politics? Trending economic factors and the structure of Congress in the growth of government, 1930–2002. Public Choice, 113, 389–402. Winer, S. L., Tofias, M., Grofman, B., & Aldrich, J. (2008). Is it economics or politics? Trending economic factors and the structure of Congress in the growth of government, 1930–2002. Public Choice, 113, 389–402.
Zurück zum Zitat Wuffle, A., Owen, G., Feld, S. L., & Grofman, B. (1989). Finagle’s law and the finagle point: A new solution concept for two-candidate competition in spatial voting games. American Journal of Political Science, 33(2), 348–375.CrossRef Wuffle, A., Owen, G., Feld, S. L., & Grofman, B. (1989). Finagle’s law and the finagle point: A new solution concept for two-candidate competition in spatial voting games. American Journal of Political Science, 33(2), 348–375.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Explaining variation in the competitiveness of U.S. Senate elections, 1922–2004
verfasst von
Stanley L. Winer
Lawrence W. Kenny
Bernard Grofman
Publikationsdatum
01.12.2014
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 3-4/2014
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-014-0176-0

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3-4/2014

Public Choice 3-4/2014 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner