Skip to main content
Erschienen in: The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 1/2008

01.07.2008

Home Equity, Household Savings and Consumption

verfasst von: J. D. Benjamin, P. Chinloy

Erschienen in: The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics | Ausgabe 1/2008

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

The home-owning family’s equity is a piggybank that can be broken open by borrowing. Each borrowing increases liabilities and cash equally, initially leaving net wealth unchanged. When those funds are spent and cash balances fall, consumption increases even as net wealth can decline. In a dynamic optimization, the marginal propensity to consume from net wealth is not always positive and can be positively correlated with housing debt.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
In Choi et al. (2006) households respond to capital gains in their pension 401 k accounts by short-term saving, and they reduce consumption. That is attributable to a feedback effect to increase saving to follow positive returns, but may also be attributable to the difficulty of consuming from capital gains in 401 k accounts, or if they are viewed as transitory.
 
2
Borrowing against housing equity includes first and second mortgages, refinancing with cash out of equity, and home equity lines of credit. The housing asset is deemed illiquid for sales, but not for borrowing. For those with a mortgage, each dollar increases liabilities and cash equally, initially leaving net wealth unchanged. This situation occurs for homeowners with a loan. Bucks et al. (2006) report that for the 2004 Survey of Consumer Finances 69.1% of families own a home. Of homeowners, 69.3% reported a home loan, so 30.7% of homeowners had no mortgage debt. In addition, the 30.9% families are renters. Nevertheless, the remaining households represent a large contribution to debt and aggregate wealth. Overall mortgage debt was 44% of gross assets from the Flow of Funds of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2006) in the first quarter of 2006. For those with any mortgage balance, the average loan-to-value ratio is 63% or 0.44/0.693.
 
3
Flavin (1981) and many other researchers note that household consumption changes due to changing expectations about future income. During 1991–1994 from the Panel Survey of Income Dynamics, Hurst and Stafford (2004) find that households with housing equity but limited other assets convert two-thirds of cash-out financing proceeds into consumption. An intertemporal consumption model in Buist and Yang (2000) allows households to make choices between adjustable and fixed-rate mortgages. Agarwal et al. (2005) show that home owners refinance their mortgages when the present value of interest saved is equal to the refinancing cost.
 
4
Laitner (2002) discusses this concentration of wealth, while Deaton (1991) and Bertaut (2002) estimate the low median financial holding at less than $1,000.
 
5
The possible linkage of housing prices to consumption has implications for monetary policy. However, Bernanke and Gertler (2001) argue that the central bank should not pay attention to asset price changes.
 
6
In Carroll et al. (2006), the short-run marginal propensity α S in changes is estimated from consumption and wealth as ΔC t  = α S ΔW t . Then wealth has ΔW t  = γ L ΔW t −1, and the long-run marginal propensity to consume from wealth is \( \frac{{\alpha _{S} }} {{1 - \gamma _{L} }} \). The estimate of the housing first-order coefficient is sluggish, indicating the higher long-run marginal propensity to consume.
 
7
There is a spurious regression if the variables are not cointegrated. A cointegrating relationship between the variables involves a stable relationship such as lnC t  − δlnY t  − (1 − δ)lnW t as the consumption disturbance in consumption C t , income Y t and wealth W t . The geometric weights invested in human and nonhuman capital are, respectively δ and (1 − δ). That is a weighted lagged average of logarithms of income, consumption and interest rates.
 
8
Vesting provisions reward employees for loyalty and longevity, so the retirement accounts are part of incentive compensation. In exchange for tax and incentive benefits, the employee must accept illiquidity on most of its financial assets. Funds in defined-benefit accounts cannot be withdrawn prior to retirement, nor can they serve as loan collateral. Funds in defined-contribution accounts have restrictions and sometimes prohibitions on withdrawal. Hall and Murphy (2003) review the incentive aspects of pension compensation.
 
9
There may be a nonzero covariance between mortgages and financial assets. However, the financial assets are in restricted accounts, and the mortgage is more subject to separate timing issues on refinancing.
 
10
The family could hold other unsecured debt such as credit cards, but this is neglected in the analysis.
 
11
Utility can exhibit non-additive separability in consumption. For one specification as in Sundaresan (1989), consumption is relative to a reference level \( \overline{c} _{t} {\left( {c_{{t - 1}} ,...,c_{0} } \right)} \) depending on the past sequence. At the current date, utility is \( u{\left( {c_{t} - \overline{c} _{t} } \right)} \), a supernumerary level analogous to the Stone–Geary form of demand functions. In equilibrium, consumption is not homothetic in wealth. Consumption remains linear in wealth, the underlying structure required for estimating the wealth effect.
 
12
The unit root test is for ρ = 1 against the alternative of ρ < 1 in \( \Delta x_{t} = \alpha + \varsigma t + {\left( {\rho - 1} \right)}x_{{t - 1}} + {\sum\limits_{j = 1}^r {\varphi _{r} \Delta x_{{t - r}} } } + \varepsilon _{t} \). Here x tested is sequentially from (c, s t , h, q m ) relative to income. All exhibit unit roots in levels. When first-differenced, these time series are stationary. The test statistics on ρ are −7.51 for consumption Δc, −5.13 for income Δy, −5.01 for housing Δh, and −6.90 for mortgage balances Δq m against a critical value of −2.86 at 1%. The data should be first differenced to create stationary time series. The Engle–Granger test statistic for a unit root on the residuals of Δx t is −3.21 (−4.86) with a 5% critical value in parentheses, indicating no cointegrating relationships. Multiple cointegrating relationships are tested using the Johansen rank test. To correct for the autocorrelation of residuals, ARMA terms AR(L) up to lag L are included in the regression models. Serial correlation is tested using the Breusch–Godfrey Lagrange multiplier (LM) test. The null hypothesis of the LM test is that there is no serial correlation up to a lag order k where k is a pre-specified integer. The LM test statistic is asymptotically distributed as \( \chi ^{2}_{k} \), chi-squared with k degrees of freedom. There is no evidence of autocorrelation using orders for k as high as 5.
The test statistics are on insignificance of the trace and largest eigenvalue of a matrix of a Gaussian vector autoregressive representation of the time series. For testing all four time series on consumption, financial assets, housing and mortgage balances, the rank is four and the trace is 18.42 (47.18) while the largest eigenvalue is 18.42 (27.20). Critical values at a 5% significance level are in parentheses. Further, there is no evidence of autocorrelation of residuals.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Agarwal, S., Driscoll, J. C., & Laibson, D. I. (2005). When should borrowers refinance their mortgages? Working Paper, Harvard University, Cambridge. Agarwal, S., Driscoll, J. C., & Laibson, D. I. (2005). When should borrowers refinance their mortgages? Working Paper, Harvard University, Cambridge.
Zurück zum Zitat Benjamin, J. D., Chinloy, P. & Jud, G. D. (2004). Real estate versus financial wealth in consumption. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 29, 341–354.CrossRef Benjamin, J. D., Chinloy, P. & Jud, G. D. (2004). Real estate versus financial wealth in consumption. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 29, 341–354.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bernanke, B., & Gertler, M. (2001). Should central banks respond to movements in asset prices? American Economic Review, 91, 253–257.CrossRef Bernanke, B., & Gertler, M. (2001). Should central banks respond to movements in asset prices? American Economic Review, 91, 253–257.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bertaut, C. (2002). Equity prices, household wealth and consumption growth in foreign industrial countries. International Finance Discussion Paper 724. Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Bertaut, C. (2002). Equity prices, household wealth and consumption growth in foreign industrial countries. International Finance Discussion Paper 724. Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Zurück zum Zitat Bhatia, K. B. (1987). Real estate assets and consumer spending. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 437–444.CrossRef Bhatia, K. B. (1987). Real estate assets and consumer spending. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 437–444.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bostic, R., Gabriel, S., & Painter, G. (2006). Housing wealth, financial wealth and consumption: new evidence from micro data. Working Paper, University of Southern California, CA. Bostic, R., Gabriel, S., & Painter, G. (2006). Housing wealth, financial wealth and consumption: new evidence from micro data. Working Paper, University of Southern California, CA.
Zurück zum Zitat Bucks, B. K., Kennickell, A.B., & Moore, K. B. (2006). Recent changes in U.S. family finance: Evidence from the 2001 and 2004 survey of consumer finances. Federal Reserve Bulletin, March, 1–38. Bucks, B. K., Kennickell, A.B., & Moore, K. B. (2006). Recent changes in U.S. family finance: Evidence from the 2001 and 2004 survey of consumer finances. Federal Reserve Bulletin, March, 1–38.
Zurück zum Zitat Buist, H., & Yang, T. (2000). Mortgage choice in a model of stochastic consumption. Real Estate Economics, 28, 117–139.CrossRef Buist, H., & Yang, T. (2000). Mortgage choice in a model of stochastic consumption. Real Estate Economics, 28, 117–139.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2006). Flow of Funds Accounts. Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2006). Flow of Funds Accounts. Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Zurück zum Zitat Campbell, J. Y., & Cocco, J. F. (2007). How do house prices affect consumption? Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 591–621. Campbell, J. Y., & Cocco, J. F. (2007). How do house prices affect consumption? Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 591–621.
Zurück zum Zitat Carroll, C., Otsuka, M., & Slacalek, J. (2006). How large is the housing wealth effect?: A new approach. Working Paper, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, MD. Carroll, C., Otsuka, M., & Slacalek, J. (2006). How large is the housing wealth effect?: A new approach. Working Paper, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, MD.
Zurück zum Zitat Case, K. E., Quigley, J. M., & Shiller, R. J. (2005). Comparing wealth effects: The stock market versus the housing market. Advances in Macroeconomics, 5, 1–34.CrossRef Case, K. E., Quigley, J. M., & Shiller, R. J. (2005). Comparing wealth effects: The stock market versus the housing market. Advances in Macroeconomics, 5, 1–34.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Choi, J. J., Laibson, D., Madrian, B., & Metrick, A. (2006). Consumption-wealth co-movement of the wrong sign. Working Paper 10454, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, March. Choi, J. J., Laibson, D., Madrian, B., & Metrick, A. (2006). Consumption-wealth co-movement of the wrong sign. Working Paper 10454, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, March.
Zurück zum Zitat Deaton, A. S. (1991). Saving and liquidity constraints. Econometrica, 59, 1221–1248.CrossRef Deaton, A. S. (1991). Saving and liquidity constraints. Econometrica, 59, 1221–1248.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Flavin, M. (1981). The adjustment of consumption to changing expectations about future income. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 975–1009.CrossRef Flavin, M. (1981). The adjustment of consumption to changing expectations about future income. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 975–1009.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hall, B. J., & Murphy, K.J. (2003). The trouble with stock options. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17, 49–70.CrossRef Hall, B. J., & Murphy, K.J. (2003). The trouble with stock options. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17, 49–70.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hurst, E., & Stafford, F. (2004). Home is where the equity is: Mortgage refinancing and household consumption. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 36, 985–1014.CrossRef Hurst, E., & Stafford, F. (2004). Home is where the equity is: Mortgage refinancing and household consumption. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 36, 985–1014.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kishor, N. K. (2005). Does consumption respond more to housing wealth than to financial wealth? If so, why? Working Paper, Washington University, St. Louis, MO. Kishor, N. K. (2005). Does consumption respond more to housing wealth than to financial wealth? If so, why? Working Paper, Washington University, St. Louis, MO.
Zurück zum Zitat Laitner, J. (2002). Wealth inequality and altruistic bequests. American Economic Review, 92, 270–273.CrossRef Laitner, J. (2002). Wealth inequality and altruistic bequests. American Economic Review, 92, 270–273.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Consumption, aggregate wealth and expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56, 815–849.CrossRef Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Consumption, aggregate wealth and expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56, 815–849.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2004). Understanding trend and cycle in asset values: Reevaluating the wealth effect on consumption. American Economic Review, 94, 276–299.CrossRef Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2004). Understanding trend and cycle in asset values: Reevaluating the wealth effect on consumption. American Economic Review, 94, 276–299.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lustig, H. N., & Van Nieuwerburgh, S. G. (2005). Housing collateral, consumption insurance and risk premia: An empirical perspective. Journal of Finance, 60, 1167–1219.CrossRef Lustig, H. N., & Van Nieuwerburgh, S. G. (2005). Housing collateral, consumption insurance and risk premia: An empirical perspective. Journal of Finance, 60, 1167–1219.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Miller, N. & Peng, L. (2006). The economic impact of house price changes: A panel var approach. Working Paper, University of Colorado, Boulder. Miller, N. & Peng, L. (2006). The economic impact of house price changes: A panel var approach. Working Paper, University of Colorado, Boulder.
Zurück zum Zitat Sundaresan, S. M. (1989). Intertemporally dependent preferences and the volatility of consumption and wealth. Review of Financial Studies, 2, 73–89.CrossRef Sundaresan, S. M. (1989). Intertemporally dependent preferences and the volatility of consumption and wealth. Review of Financial Studies, 2, 73–89.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Home Equity, Household Savings and Consumption
verfasst von
J. D. Benjamin
P. Chinloy
Publikationsdatum
01.07.2008
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics / Ausgabe 1/2008
Print ISSN: 0895-5638
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-045X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-007-9059-1

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1/2008

The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 1/2008 Zur Ausgabe