Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Empirical Economics 4/2016

04.01.2016

Labor supply heterogeneity and demand for child care of mothers with young children

verfasst von: Patricia Apps, Jan Kabátek, Ray Rees, Arthur van Soest

Erschienen in: Empirical Economics | Ausgabe 4/2016

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper presents a structural model of the labor supply and child care choices of partnered mothers with pre-school aged children. The father’s time-use decisions are taken as given. The main goal is to analyze the sensitivity of maternal time use to the price of child care, taxes, benefits and child care subsidies. To account for non-convexities in the budget sets, we specify a discrete choice model. We estimate the model on data on couples with young children from the HILDA survey representative of the Australian population, which contains detailed information on time use and bought-in child care. Simulations based on the estimated parameters show that the time decisions of mothers with pre-school children are highly sensitive to changes in wages and the cost of child care. Our results also suggest that lowering effective tax rates faced by partnered mothers as second earners, by switching from family payments that are targeted on joint incomes to payments that are universal and funded by a more progressive individual-based income tax, would lead to a substantial increase in their labor force participation and hours of work.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
Applications using this approach include Ribar (1995), Doiron and Kalb (2005) and Kabátek et al. (2014).
 
2
Several studies of female labor supply allow for more flexible treatment of the unobserved heterogeneity (Bernal 2008; Blau and Hagy 1998 and Tekin 2007), building on seminal works of Heckman and Singer (1984) and Mroz (1999). The latent-class approach can be considered a generalization of these models, allowing for additional flexibility.
 
3
Every variable or function with subscript h can vary across households. Each of these is therefore in principle a contributor to across-household heterogeneity in choices.
 
4
The fact that we restrict ourselves to the unitary framework and do not develop a collective model is essentially due to data limitations that constrain what we can estimate. Furthermore, non-convexity of budget constraints is a central aspect of the motivation of the modeling in this paper, and this non-convexity poses a problem for the possibility of the existence of a decentralized sharing rule, which is a central aspect of the collective approach.
 
5
In principle, the distributional factors could also include the wage rates, but this will not be allowed for in the empirical model.
 
6
For a detailed exposition of the economics of this type of household model, see Apps and Rees (2009), Ch 3.
 
7
For example there may be tax offsets for expenditure on market child care.
 
8
For detailed discussion and applications of the discrete approach adopted here see, for example, Van Soest (1995), Van Soest et al. (2002) and Pacifico (2012).
 
9
In other empirical studies, additional household-specific restrictions are often needed to account for infeasibility of certain choices. Kornstad and Thoresen (2007), for example, constrain choice sets of selected households to account for high degree of rationing in Norwegian day care centers.
 
10
A limitation of the HILDA time-use data is that only one activity is reported for each episode. In contrast, the Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) Time Use Surveys report a second activity when relevant. Child care is almost always a second activity during housework and related activities.
 
11
Similar income-based exclusion restrictions are used by, e.g., Blundell et al. (2007b) and Sorensen (1993).
 
12
The imputation of child care prices should be approached with caution because the observed prices can reflect variation in quality of the service. The quality of child care can be endogenous to the regressors used in the Heckman selection model and hence can distort reliability of the imputed prices. To address these concerns, we estimate an alternative specification of the model which uses imputed prices of child care for all families in the sample. Relative differences in the predictions made by the original model and the alternative specification can be used to assess whether the endogeneity is likely to play a role here.
 
13
This helps to reduce the computational complexity of the problem. Given that the utility function is identified up to a monotonic transformation only, it does not seem overly restrictive.
 
14
The penalized choices are identical to the standard choices in all respects other than household income, which is lower for penalized choices. Negative marginal utility would imply that penalized choices in the interior would be favored by the decision makers, but the observed choices are always on the budget frontier. Maximum Likelihood estimates maximize the probability of the observed outcomes and will therefore give parameters that make internal choices unlikely, that is, parameters that imply a positive marginal utility of income.
 
15
“Full-time” employment is defined by the ABS as 35 hours or more per week.
 
16
The time-use data are collected by questionnaire and reported as weekly time uses. Unlike diary data, questionnaire data are typically subject to larger reporting errors, and as a result the sum of individual time allocations to the various activities sometimes fails to satisfy the time constraint.
 
17
As a robustness check, we also estimated the structural model excluding these 85 women. This gave virtually identical estimates of elasticities and policy effects.
 
18
Leisure is computed as the remainder of the daily time endowment after subtracting market work and household production hours, which may be adjusted to satisfy the total time constraint. The 42-h per week threshold follows from assuming at least 6 h per day for sleep and personal care.
 
19
An economic rationale for this would be that informal child care is quantity-rationed and has a lower cost than formal child care, the price of which determines demand for child care at the margin.
 
20
The details of the tax rates, family payments and income thresholds on which the figure is based are set out in “Appendix 2”.
 
21
For a graphical analysis of cases in which the second earner has lower income than the primary earner, see Apps and Rees (2009), Ch 6.
 
22
This “tax penalty” on the second earner’s income under joint taxation explains why switching from a joint to a purely individual-based system stimulates the participation of the second earner (see, for example, Steiner and Wrohlich 2004).
 
23
The latter is obtained by taking weighted means over all classes, where the weights are the class probabilities given the observed choice.
 
24
Standard errors on the elasticities were computed through 199 Monte Carlo simulations, recomputing the percentage changes with simulated sets of parameters determining \(\mathbf {A}\) and \(\mathbf {b}\). These parameters were drawn from the estimated (multivariate normal) distribution of the ML estimates. See Ruud (1991).
 
25
In absolute terms, the wage increase induces the average mother to spend about 0.55 h per week more on market work, 0.40 h less on household production, and 0.15 h less on leisure.
 
26
This elasticity is well in line with that of Gong and Breunig (2011) but smaller than that in Breunig et al. (2012).
 
27
On average mothers spend about 0.10 h per week longer on household production and reduce their market work by 0.10 h and bought-in child care by 0.05 h.
 
28
It should be noted that these results are specific to the population of partnered mothers with preschool children. The revenue neutrality is also achieved by raising income taxes only for this group.
 
29
The percentage changes presented in Table 8 use quartile-specific sample means of time-use allocations as a point of reference. If we would use unconditional means, the percentage change for female labor supply in the fourth quartile would be 1.26 %.
 
30
In our sample, 65 % of mothers are predicted to increase their hours of formal child care (typically the mothers who increase their hours of market work). Once again, a key role is played by mothers with higher wages who reduce their market work hours and also their utilization of formal care. The relatively large fall in their claimed benefits is sufficient to offset most of the rise in benefit claims by other households.
 
31
This allows us to examine direct substitution effects between maternal and formal child care.
 
32
There is no clear consensus with respect to which form the working indicator should take on. Blundell et al. (2007a) put the employment dummy into the budget constraint, so that it represents fixed monetary costs of working. Donald and Hamermesh (2009) interact the dummy with time-use variables entering the utility function, referring to the corresponding parameters as shifters of time-use efficiency. We choose to add the employment dummy into the individual utility function in a non-interacted form, which allows us to model fixed disutility from work without substantially increasing the computational burden.
 
33
Restricting the age range to women aged 48 and under hardly affects the results—the correlation coefficient between the two sets of wage predictions is 0.99.
 
34
Despite its title, the ML is a tax on income and is not tied to funding any aspect of the health system.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Aaberge R, Colombino U, Strom S (1999) Labour supply in Italy: an empirical analysis of joint household decisions, with taxes and quantity constraints. J Appl Econ 14:403–422CrossRef Aaberge R, Colombino U, Strom S (1999) Labour supply in Italy: an empirical analysis of joint household decisions, with taxes and quantity constraints. J Appl Econ 14:403–422CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alesina A, Ichino A, Karabarbounis L (2011) Gender-based taxation and the division of family chores. Am Econ J Econ Policy 3:1–40CrossRef Alesina A, Ichino A, Karabarbounis L (2011) Gender-based taxation and the division of family chores. Am Econ J Econ Policy 3:1–40CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Apps P, Rees R (2009) Public economics and the household. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef Apps P, Rees R (2009) Public economics and the household. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Baker M, Gruber J, Milligan K (2008) Universal child care, maternal labor supply, and family well-being. J Polit Econ 116:709–745CrossRef Baker M, Gruber J, Milligan K (2008) Universal child care, maternal labor supply, and family well-being. J Polit Econ 116:709–745CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bernal R (2008) The effect of maternal employment and child care on children’s cognitive development. Int Econ Rev 49:1173–1209CrossRef Bernal R (2008) The effect of maternal employment and child care on children’s cognitive development. Int Econ Rev 49:1173–1209CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blau DM (2003) Child care subsidy programs, in Means-tested transfer programs in the United States. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, NBER Chapters, pp 443–516 Blau DM (2003) Child care subsidy programs, in Means-tested transfer programs in the United States. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, NBER Chapters, pp 443–516
Zurück zum Zitat Blau DM, Hagy AP (1998) The demand for quality in child care. J Polit Econ 106:104–146CrossRef Blau DM, Hagy AP (1998) The demand for quality in child care. J Polit Econ 106:104–146CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blundell R, Gosling A, Ichimura H, Meghir C (2007a) Changes in the distribution of male and female wages accounting for employment composition using bounds. Econometrica 75:323–363CrossRef Blundell R, Gosling A, Ichimura H, Meghir C (2007a) Changes in the distribution of male and female wages accounting for employment composition using bounds. Econometrica 75:323–363CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blundell R, MaCurdy T, Meghir C (2007b) Labor supply models: Unobserved heterogeneity, nonparticipation and dynamics. In: Heckman J, Leamer E (eds) Handbook of econometrics, chap. 69, vol. 6. Elsevier, Amsterdam Blundell R, MaCurdy T, Meghir C (2007b) Labor supply models: Unobserved heterogeneity, nonparticipation and dynamics. In: Heckman J, Leamer E (eds) Handbook of econometrics, chap. 69, vol. 6. Elsevier, Amsterdam
Zurück zum Zitat Blundell R, Shephard A (2012) Employment, hours of work and the optimal taxation of low-income families. Rev Econ Stud 79:481–510CrossRef Blundell R, Shephard A (2012) Employment, hours of work and the optimal taxation of low-income families. Rev Econ Stud 79:481–510CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Breunig R, Gong X, King A (2012) Partnered women’s labour supply and child-care costs in Australia: measurement error and the child-care price. Econ Rec 88:51–69CrossRef Breunig R, Gong X, King A (2012) Partnered women’s labour supply and child-care costs in Australia: measurement error and the child-care price. Econ Rec 88:51–69CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Burda M, Harding M, Hausman J (2008) A Bayesian mixed logit & probit model for multinomial choice. J Econom 147:232–246CrossRef Burda M, Harding M, Hausman J (2008) A Bayesian mixed logit & probit model for multinomial choice. J Econom 147:232–246CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Connelly R (1992) The effect of child care costs on married women’s labor force participation. Rev Econ Stat 74:83–90CrossRef Connelly R (1992) The effect of child care costs on married women’s labor force participation. Rev Econ Stat 74:83–90CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Connelly R, Kimmel J (2003) Marital status and full-time/part-time work status in child care choices. Appl Econ 35:761–777CrossRef Connelly R, Kimmel J (2003) Marital status and full-time/part-time work status in child care choices. Appl Econ 35:761–777CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Doiron D, Kalb G (2005) Demands for child care and household labour supply in Australia. Econ Rec 81:215–236CrossRef Doiron D, Kalb G (2005) Demands for child care and household labour supply in Australia. Econ Rec 81:215–236CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Donald SG, Hamermesh DS (2009) A structural model of the fixed time costs of market work. Econ Lett 104:125–128CrossRef Donald SG, Hamermesh DS (2009) A structural model of the fixed time costs of market work. Econ Lett 104:125–128CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gong X, Breunig R (2011) Estimating net child care price elasticities of partnered women with pre-school children using a discrete structural labour supply-child care model. CEPR Discussion Papers 653, Centre for Economic Policy Research, Research School of Economics, Australian National University Gong X, Breunig R (2011) Estimating net child care price elasticities of partnered women with pre-school children using a discrete structural labour supply-child care model. CEPR Discussion Papers 653, Centre for Economic Policy Research, Research School of Economics, Australian National University
Zurück zum Zitat Heckman J (1979) Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 129:153–161CrossRef Heckman J (1979) Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 129:153–161CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Heckman J, Singer B (1984) A method for minimizing the impact of distributional assumptions in econometric models for duration data. Econometrica 52:271–320CrossRef Heckman J, Singer B (1984) A method for minimizing the impact of distributional assumptions in econometric models for duration data. Econometrica 52:271–320CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kabátek J, van Soest A, Stancanelli E (2014) Income taxation, labour supply and housework: a discrete choice model for French couples. Lab Econ 27:30–43CrossRef Kabátek J, van Soest A, Stancanelli E (2014) Income taxation, labour supply and housework: a discrete choice model for French couples. Lab Econ 27:30–43CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kalenkoski CM, Ribar DC, Stratton LS (2005) Parental child care in single-parent, cohabiting, and married-couple families: time-diary evidence from the United Kingdom. Am Econ Rev 95:194–198CrossRef Kalenkoski CM, Ribar DC, Stratton LS (2005) Parental child care in single-parent, cohabiting, and married-couple families: time-diary evidence from the United Kingdom. Am Econ Rev 95:194–198CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Keane M, Moffitt R (1998) A structural model of multiple welfare program participation and labor supply. Int Econ Rev 39:553–589CrossRef Keane M, Moffitt R (1998) A structural model of multiple welfare program participation and labor supply. Int Econ Rev 39:553–589CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kornstad T, Thoresen T (2007) A discrete choice model for labor supply and childcare. J Popul Econ 20:781–803CrossRef Kornstad T, Thoresen T (2007) A discrete choice model for labor supply and childcare. J Popul Econ 20:781–803CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mroz TA (1999) Discrete factor approximations in simultaneous equation models: estimating the impact of a dummy endogenous variable on a continuous outcome. J Econom 92:233–274CrossRef Mroz TA (1999) Discrete factor approximations in simultaneous equation models: estimating the impact of a dummy endogenous variable on a continuous outcome. J Econom 92:233–274CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pacifico D (2012) On the role of unobserved preference heterogeneity in discrete choice models of labour supply. Empir Econ 45(2):929–963 Pacifico D (2012) On the role of unobserved preference heterogeneity in discrete choice models of labour supply. Empir Econ 45(2):929–963
Zurück zum Zitat Ribar DC (1995) A structural model of child care and the labor supply of married women. J Labor Econ 13:558–97CrossRef Ribar DC (1995) A structural model of child care and the labor supply of married women. J Labor Econ 13:558–97CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ruud P (1991) Extensions of estimation methods using the EM algorithm. J Econom 49:305–341CrossRef Ruud P (1991) Extensions of estimation methods using the EM algorithm. J Econom 49:305–341CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sorensen E (1993) Continuous female workers: how different are they from other women? East Econ J 19:15–32 Sorensen E (1993) Continuous female workers: how different are they from other women? East Econ J 19:15–32
Zurück zum Zitat Steiner V, Wrohlich K (2004) Household taxation, income splitting and labor supply incentives: a microsimulation study for Germany. Tech. rep Steiner V, Wrohlich K (2004) Household taxation, income splitting and labor supply incentives: a microsimulation study for Germany. Tech. rep
Zurück zum Zitat Tekin E (2007) Childcare subsidies, wages, and employment of single mothers. J Hum Resour 42(2):453–487CrossRef Tekin E (2007) Childcare subsidies, wages, and employment of single mothers. J Hum Resour 42(2):453–487CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Train K (2008) EM algorithms for nonparametric estimation of mixing distributions. Journal of Choice Modelling 1:40–69CrossRef Train K (2008) EM algorithms for nonparametric estimation of mixing distributions. Journal of Choice Modelling 1:40–69CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Van Soest A (1995) Structural models of family labor supply: a discrete choice approach. J Hum Resour 30:63–88CrossRef Van Soest A (1995) Structural models of family labor supply: a discrete choice approach. J Hum Resour 30:63–88CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Van Soest A, Das M, Gong X (2002) A structural labour supply model with flexible preferences. J Econom 107:345–374CrossRef Van Soest A, Das M, Gong X (2002) A structural labour supply model with flexible preferences. J Econom 107:345–374CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Labor supply heterogeneity and demand for child care of mothers with young children
verfasst von
Patricia Apps
Jan Kabátek
Ray Rees
Arthur van Soest
Publikationsdatum
04.01.2016
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Empirical Economics / Ausgabe 4/2016
Print ISSN: 0377-7332
Elektronische ISSN: 1435-8921
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-015-1046-4

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 4/2016

Empirical Economics 4/2016 Zur Ausgabe