Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 3-4/2015

01.06.2015

On the relationship between corruption and migration: empirical evidence from a gravity model of migration

verfasst von: Marie Poprawe

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 3-4/2015

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper shows the relationship between corruption and migration. In particular, countries with much corruption are shown to encourage emigration and discourage immigration because they provide worse and unpredictable economic conditions, more insecurity, and a lower quality of life. This hypothesis is confirmed empirically with a cross-sectional dataset with bilateral migration data covering 230 countries. Well-known implications of the gravity model are confirmed here: larger populations, a common language and a common border increase migration, while distance between two countries decreases migration. Furthermore, education, GDP per capita, inflation in the destination country, as well as corruption and education in the origin country can robustly explain migration. Corruption thus appears to be a push factor of migration.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
See Tiebout (1956) and Tullock (1971) for early discussions. See also Cebula and Zafoglis (1986), Cebula et al. (2014), and Goodspeed (1998) for applications of the Tiebout–Tullock hypothesis.
 
2
Alternatively one could use a utility function containing consumption in \(t\) and \(t+1\). The conclusion drawn from this would be the same, i.e., that indirect utility is an increasing function of income.
 
3
The maximum value reached is 3,789,377, a lot further from the mean than two standard deviations. The observation responsible for this (the country-pair USA—Mexico) is clearly an outlier and is therefore removed from now on.
 
4
This type of migration occurs between wealthy countries; for example, between EU countries and the US, or within the EU.
 
5
The latter two being sub-indices of the overall economic freedom index.
 
6
It is beyond the scope of this paper to study the spatial patterns of migration and corruption and thus the paper abstracts from possible spillover effects as described by Becker et al. (2009). However, if one were to take into account the spatial aspect of migration decisions, the estimated coefficient of Corruption (i) is likely a lower bound.
 
7
For some control variables for the origin country the estimated coefficient sometimes contradicts the hypothesized sign (for example, GDP(i))—this effect can be attributed to large volumes of North-North migration in comparison to total migrant flows. In regressions excluding North–North country-pairs, the coefficients are negative.
 
8
The effect of education in the origin country is positive and statistically significant in this specification, but negative in column (4). Its overall effect is ambiguous.
 
9
Zero divides the area under the density in two. CDF(0) from now on refers to the larger of the two areas under the density function, either above or below zero.
 
10
The varying number of observations in the regressions in consequence of missing observations in some of the variables implies that using weights proportional to the integrated likelihood as a goodness-of-fit measure may not be a good indicator of the probability that a model is the true model, as explained in Sturm and de Haan (2005). The reason for using the criterion that CDF(0)\(>0.95\) is that CDF(0) will always be between 0.5 and 1; and using CDF(0)\(>0.95\) as Sala-i-Martin (1997) therefore seems too low.
 
11
With the exception of % tertiary education (i) - the sign of the coefficient can again be attributed to large North-North migration.
 
12
Its coverage in terms of countries is slightly larger as it relies heavily on the data published by Transparency International but fills any gaps with additional data.
 
13
It relies on 31 individual data sources and measures corruption in the public as well as private sector.
 
14
To facilitate comparability the indicators have been rescaled so that they range from 0 to 10, with higher scores signifying lower corruption.
 
15
Although especially for receiving countries what matters to immigrants is the perceived level of corruption, about which immigrants are likely to hear.
 
16
These data are converted to a scale between 0 and 10 and reversed so that high values imply low levels of experienced corruption. Because a worldwide index of actual corruption has become available only recently, Column (5) shows a regression for the year 2010. The World Bank bilateral migration database provides data at 10-year intervals, the next available year being 2010. All control variables were collected for the year 2010 also, and all other data sources are the same as for the year 2000.
 
17
The 38 countries are: Austria, Australia, Belgium, Bulgaria, Canada, Croatia, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Latvia, Lithuania, Luxembourg, Malta, Mexico, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Korea, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, The Netherlands, Turkey, United Kingdom and the United States. Years range from 1993 to 2008.
 
18
The datacode in Eurostat is tsdde230.
 
19
These differences may be because of an extension of the time period covered, and because of a different sample.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Aidt, T. S. (2003). Economic analysis of corruption: A survey. Economic Journal, 113(491), 632–652.CrossRef Aidt, T. S. (2003). Economic analysis of corruption: A survey. Economic Journal, 113(491), 632–652.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Aidt, T. S., Dutta, J., & Sena, V. (2008). Governance regimes, corruption and growth: Theory and evidence. Journal of Comparative Economics, 36, 195–220.CrossRef Aidt, T. S., Dutta, J., & Sena, V. (2008). Governance regimes, corruption and growth: Theory and evidence. Journal of Comparative Economics, 36, 195–220.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Anderson, J. E., & van Wincoop, E. (2003). Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the border puzzle. American Economic Review, 93(1), 170–192.CrossRef Anderson, J. E., & van Wincoop, E. (2003). Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the border puzzle. American Economic Review, 93(1), 170–192.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barro, R. J., & Lee, J. W. (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950—2010. Journal of Development Economics, 104, 184–198.CrossRef Barro, R. J., & Lee, J. W. (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950—2010. Journal of Development Economics, 104, 184–198.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Becker, S. O., Egger, P. H., & Seidel, T. (2009). Common political culture: Evidence on regional corruption contagion. European Journal of Political Economy, 25, 300–310.CrossRef Becker, S. O., Egger, P. H., & Seidel, T. (2009). Common political culture: Evidence on regional corruption contagion. European Journal of Political Economy, 25, 300–310.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bertocchi, G., & Strozzi, C. (2008). International migration and the role of institutions. Public Choice, 137, 81–102.CrossRef Bertocchi, G., & Strozzi, C. (2008). International migration and the role of institutions. Public Choice, 137, 81–102.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Borjas, G. (1989). Economic theory and international migration. International Migration Review, 23(3), 457–485.CrossRef Borjas, G. (1989). Economic theory and international migration. International Migration Review, 23(3), 457–485.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Borjas, G. J. (1987). Self-selection and the earnings of immigrants. American Economic Review, 77(4), 531–553. Borjas, G. J. (1987). Self-selection and the earnings of immigrants. American Economic Review, 77(4), 531–553.
Zurück zum Zitat Bosquet, C. & Boulhol, H. (2010). Scale-dependence of the negative binomial pseudo-maximum likelihood estimator, Documents de travail du Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne 10092, Université Panthéon-Sorbonne (Paris 1), Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne. Bosquet, C. & Boulhol, H. (2010). Scale-dependence of the negative binomial pseudo-maximum likelihood estimator, Documents de travail du Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne 10092, Université Panthéon-Sorbonne (Paris 1), Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne.
Zurück zum Zitat Cebula, R. J. (2002). Migration and the Tiebout–Tullock hypothesis revisited. The Review of Regional Studies, 32(1), 87–96. Cebula, R. J. (2002). Migration and the Tiebout–Tullock hypothesis revisited. The Review of Regional Studies, 32(1), 87–96.
Zurück zum Zitat Cebula, R. J., & Zafoglis, M. Z. (1986). A note on the Tiebout–Tullock hypthesis: The period 1975–1980. Public Choice, 48, 65–69.CrossRef Cebula, R. J., & Zafoglis, M. Z. (1986). A note on the Tiebout–Tullock hypthesis: The period 1975–1980. Public Choice, 48, 65–69.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cebula, R. J., Nair-Reichert, U., & Coombs, C. K. (2014). Total state in-migration rates and public policy in the United States: A comparative analysis of the Great Recession and the pre- and post-Great Recession years. Regional Studies, Regional Science, 1(1), 102–115.CrossRef Cebula, R. J., Nair-Reichert, U., & Coombs, C. K. (2014). Total state in-migration rates and public policy in the United States: A comparative analysis of the Great Recession and the pre- and post-Great Recession years. Regional Studies, Regional Science, 1(1), 102–115.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cooray, A. V., & Schneider, F. (2014). Does corruption promote emigration? An empirical examination, Discussion Paper 8094, IZA. Cooray, A. V., & Schneider, F. (2014). Does corruption promote emigration? An empirical examination, Discussion Paper 8094, IZA.
Zurück zum Zitat Dimant, E., Krieger, T., & Meierrieks, D. (2013). The effect of corruption on migration, 1985–2000. Applied Economics Letters, 20, 1270–1274.CrossRef Dimant, E., Krieger, T., & Meierrieks, D. (2013). The effect of corruption on migration, 1985–2000. Applied Economics Letters, 20, 1270–1274.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Djankov, S., McLiesh, C., & Ramalho, R. M. (2006). Regulation and growth. Economics Letters, 92(3), 395–401.CrossRef Djankov, S., McLiesh, C., & Ramalho, R. M. (2006). Regulation and growth. Economics Letters, 92(3), 395–401.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Donchev, D., & Ujhelyi, G. (2014). What do corruption indices measure? Economics & Politics, 26(2), 309–331.CrossRef Donchev, D., & Ujhelyi, G. (2014). What do corruption indices measure? Economics & Politics, 26(2), 309–331.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dreher, A., & Gassebner, M. (2013). Greasing the wheels? The impact of regulations and corruption on firm entry. Public Choice, 155, 413–432.CrossRef Dreher, A., & Gassebner, M. (2013). Greasing the wheels? The impact of regulations and corruption on firm entry. Public Choice, 155, 413–432.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dreher, A., Krieger, T., & Meierrieks, D. (2011). Hit and (they will) run: The impact of terrorism on migration. Economics Letters, 113(1), 42–46.CrossRef Dreher, A., Krieger, T., & Meierrieks, D. (2011). Hit and (they will) run: The impact of terrorism on migration. Economics Letters, 113(1), 42–46.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ehrlich, I., & Lui, F. (1999). Bureaucratic corruption and endogenous economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 107(6), 270–293.CrossRef Ehrlich, I., & Lui, F. (1999). Bureaucratic corruption and endogenous economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 107(6), 270–293.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gallin, J. (2004). Net migration and state labour market dynamics. Journal of Labour Economics, 1, 1–21.CrossRef Gallin, J. (2004). Net migration and state labour market dynamics. Journal of Labour Economics, 1, 1–21.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gassebner, M., Lamla, M., & Vreeland, J. R. (2013). Extreme bounds of democracy. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 57(2), 171–197.CrossRef Gassebner, M., Lamla, M., & Vreeland, J. R. (2013). Extreme bounds of democracy. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 57(2), 171–197.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goodspeed, T. J. (1998). On the importance of public choice in migration models. Economics Letters, 59, 373–379.CrossRef Goodspeed, T. J. (1998). On the importance of public choice in migration models. Economics Letters, 59, 373–379.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Greene, W. H. (2008). Econometric analysis. Boston: Pearson. Greene, W. H. (2008). Econometric analysis. Boston: Pearson.
Zurück zum Zitat Heston, A., Summers, R., & Aten, B. (2011). Penn world table version 7.0, dataset. Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania. Heston, A., Summers, R., & Aten, B. (2011). Penn world table version 7.0, dataset. Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania.
Zurück zum Zitat Jahedi, S., & Méndez, F. (2014). On the advantages and disadvantages of subjective measures. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 98, 97–114.CrossRef Jahedi, S., & Méndez, F. (2014). On the advantages and disadvantages of subjective measures. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 98, 97–114.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Karemera, D., Oguledo, V. I., & Davis, B. (2000). A gravity model analysis of international migration to North America. Applied Economics, 32(13), 1745–1755.CrossRef Karemera, D., Oguledo, V. I., & Davis, B. (2000). A gravity model analysis of international migration to North America. Applied Economics, 32(13), 1745–1755.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kleven, H. J., Landais, C., & Saez, E. (2013). Taxation and international migration of superstars: Evidence from the European football market. American Economic Review, 103(5), 1892–1924.CrossRef Kleven, H. J., Landais, C., & Saez, E. (2013). Taxation and international migration of superstars: Evidence from the European football market. American Economic Review, 103(5), 1892–1924.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leamer, E. (1983). Let’s take the con out of econometrics. American Economic Review, 73, 31–43. Leamer, E. (1983). Let’s take the con out of econometrics. American Economic Review, 73, 31–43.
Zurück zum Zitat Lederman, D., Loayza, N. V., & Soares, R. R. (2005). Accountability and corruption: Political institutions matter. Economics & Politics, 17(1), 1–35.CrossRef Lederman, D., Loayza, N. V., & Soares, R. R. (2005). Accountability and corruption: Political institutions matter. Economics & Politics, 17(1), 1–35.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Letouzé, E., Purser, M., Rodriguez, F., & Cummins, M. (2009). Revisiting the migration-development nexus: A gravity model approach, Discussion Paper 19227, MPRA. Letouzé, E., Purser, M., Rodriguez, F., & Cummins, M. (2009). Revisiting the migration-development nexus: A gravity model approach, Discussion Paper 19227, MPRA.
Zurück zum Zitat Levine, R., & Renelt, D. (1992). A senstivity analysis of cross-country growth regressions. American Economic Review, 82(4), 942–963. Levine, R., & Renelt, D. (1992). A senstivity analysis of cross-country growth regressions. American Economic Review, 82(4), 942–963.
Zurück zum Zitat Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), 681–712.CrossRef Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), 681–712.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Méndez, F., & Sepúlveda, F. (2006). Corruption, growth and political regimes: Cross country evidence. European Journal of Political Economy, 22(1), 82–98.CrossRef Méndez, F., & Sepúlveda, F. (2006). Corruption, growth and political regimes: Cross country evidence. European Journal of Political Economy, 22(1), 82–98.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Méon, P.-G., & Sekkat, K. (2005). Does corruption grease or sand the wheels of growth? Public Choice, 122, 69–97.CrossRef Méon, P.-G., & Sekkat, K. (2005). Does corruption grease or sand the wheels of growth? Public Choice, 122, 69–97.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Méon, P.-G., & Weill, L. (2010). Is corruption an efficient grease? World Development, 38, 244–259.CrossRef Méon, P.-G., & Weill, L. (2010). Is corruption an efficient grease? World Development, 38, 244–259.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Moore, W., & Shellman, S. (2004). Fear of prosecution: Forced migration, 1952–1995. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 48(5), 723–745.CrossRef Moore, W., & Shellman, S. (2004). Fear of prosecution: Forced migration, 1952–1995. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 48(5), 723–745.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Özden, C., Parsons, C. R., Schiff, M., & Walmsley, T. L. (2011). Where on earth is everybody? The evolution of global bilateral migration 1960–2000. World Bank Economic Review, 25(1), 12–56.CrossRef Özden, C., Parsons, C. R., Schiff, M., & Walmsley, T. L. (2011). Where on earth is everybody? The evolution of global bilateral migration 1960–2000. World Bank Economic Review, 25(1), 12–56.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Radnitz, S. (2006). Weighing the political and economic motivations for migration in post-Soviet space: The case of Uzbekistan. Europe-Asia Studies, 58(5), 653–677.CrossRef Radnitz, S. (2006). Weighing the political and economic motivations for migration in post-Soviet space: The case of Uzbekistan. Europe-Asia Studies, 58(5), 653–677.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sala-i-Martin, X. (1997). I just ran two million regressions. American Economic Review, 87(2), 178–183. Sala-i-Martin, X. (1997). I just ran two million regressions. American Economic Review, 87(2), 178–183.
Zurück zum Zitat Santos Silva, J. M. C., & Tenreyro, S. (2006). The log of gravity. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88, 641–658.CrossRef Santos Silva, J. M. C., & Tenreyro, S. (2006). The log of gravity. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88, 641–658.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Serra, D. (2006). Empirical determinants of corruption: A sensitivity analysis. Public Choice, 126, 225–256.CrossRef Serra, D. (2006). Empirical determinants of corruption: A sensitivity analysis. Public Choice, 126, 225–256.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stanton Russell, S. (1995). International migration: implications for the World Bank, Working Papers 54, HRO. Stanton Russell, S. (1995). International migration: implications for the World Bank, Working Papers 54, HRO.
Zurück zum Zitat Sturm, J., & de Haan, J. (2005). Determinants of long-term growth: New results applying robust estimation and extreme bounds analysis. Empirical Economics, 30, 597–617.CrossRef Sturm, J., & de Haan, J. (2005). Determinants of long-term growth: New results applying robust estimation and extreme bounds analysis. Empirical Economics, 30, 597–617.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sturm, J.-E., Berger, H., & de Haan, J. (2005). Which variables explain decisions on IMF credit? An extreme bounds analysis. Economics & Politics, 17(2), 177–213.CrossRef Sturm, J.-E., Berger, H., & de Haan, J. (2005). Which variables explain decisions on IMF credit? An extreme bounds analysis. Economics & Politics, 17(2), 177–213.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Svendsen, G. T. (2003). Social capital, corruption and economic growth: Eastern and Western Europe, Working Papers 03–21, University of Aarhus, Aarhus School of Business, Department of Economics. Svendsen, G. T. (2003). Social capital, corruption and economic growth: Eastern and Western Europe, Working Papers 03–21, University of Aarhus, Aarhus School of Business, Department of Economics.
Zurück zum Zitat Tiebout, C. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64(1), 416–424.CrossRef Tiebout, C. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64(1), 416–424.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Treisman, D. (2007). What have we learned about the causes of corruption from ten years of cross-national empirical research? Annual Review of Political Science, 10, 211–244.CrossRef Treisman, D. (2007). What have we learned about the causes of corruption from ten years of cross-national empirical research? Annual Review of Political Science, 10, 211–244.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1971). Public decisions as public goods. Journal of Political Economy, 79(4), 913–918.CrossRef Tullock, G. (1971). Public decisions as public goods. Journal of Political Economy, 79(4), 913–918.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tunali, I. (2000). Rationality of migration. International Economic Review, 41(4), 893–920.CrossRef Tunali, I. (2000). Rationality of migration. International Economic Review, 41(4), 893–920.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
On the relationship between corruption and migration: empirical evidence from a gravity model of migration
verfasst von
Marie Poprawe
Publikationsdatum
01.06.2015
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 3-4/2015
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-015-0255-x

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3-4/2015

Public Choice 3-4/2015 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner