Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Quantitative Marketing and Economics 2/2018

03.10.2017

Television ad-skipping, consumption complementarities and the consumer demand for advertising

verfasst von: Anna E. Tuchman, Harikesh S. Nair, Pedro M. Gardete

Erschienen in: Quantitative Marketing and Economics | Ausgabe 2/2018

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Endogenous consumption of advertising is common. Consumers choose to change channels to avoid TV ads, click away from paid online video ads, or discard direct mail without reading advertised details. As technological advances give firms improved abilities to target individual consumers through various media, it is becoming increasingly important for models to reflect the endogenous nature of ad consumption and to consider the implications that ad choice has for firms’ targeting strategies. With this motivation, we develop an empirical model of consumer demand for advertising in which demand for ads is jointly determined with demand for the advertised products. Building on Becker and Murphy (The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(4), 941–964 1993)’s ideas, the model treats advertising as a good over which consumers have utility and obtains demands as the outcome of a joint utility maximization problem. Leveraging new data that links household-level TV ad-viewing with product purchases, we provide empirical evidence that is consistent with the model: ad-skipping is found to be lower when a household has purchased more of the advertised brand, and purchases are higher when more ads have been watched recently, suggesting that advertising and product consumption are jointly determined. Fitting a structural model of joint demand to the data, we evaluate consumer welfare and advertiser profitability in advertising targeting counterfactuals motivated by an “addressable” future of TV. We find that targeting on the predicted ad-skip probability is an attractive strategy, as it indirectly selects consumers that value the product. Reflecting the positive view of advertising in the model, we also find that net consumer welfare may increase in several targeting scenarios. This occurs because under improved targeting, firms shift advertising to those who are likely to value it. At the same time, consumers that do not value the ads end up skipping them, mitigating possible welfare losses. Both forces are relevant to assessing advertising effects in a world with improved targeting and ad-skipping technology.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
Past frameworks for handling the micro-foundations of advertising include the informative model that posits that advertising affects demand by communicating information about products to consumers (Nelson 1970, 1974; Butters 1977; Grossman-and-Shapiro 1984), and the so-called persuasive model, in which advertising is incorporated into the utility from product consumption and viewed as a means of creating brand loyalty (please see Bagwell 2007 for a comprehensive review of the literature). The informative view is not a good description of ad consumption in our study. The product category we study is a fast moving consumer packaged good that has been on the market for years with no new brand entry during the time period of our data. Like Ackerberg (2001), we find that advertising continues to affect the purchase behavior of experienced consumers in the data even after significant product trial, suggesting its primary role is not to convey information about existence, attributes or match values. In the persuasive stream, advertising is usually treated as a taste shifter in utility, and there is usually no specific theoretical justification for its inclusion in the utility function.
 
2
Evidence in the literature suggests a link between those who respond to advertising and risk in such markets. Using randomized trials on direct-mail advertising, Ausubel (1999) documents that customer pools resulting from credit card offers with inferior terms (e.g., a higher introductory interest rate, a shorter duration for the introductory offer) have worse observable credit-risk characteristics and are more likely to default than those drawn in by solicitations offering superior terms.
 
3
Medical researchers address non-compliance in clinical trials by “double blinding.” When non-complying patients do not know they are in the treated or control groups, there is no reason to believe that non-compliers are more averse to treatment than compliers. Unfortunately, this strategy only works in relatively non-invasive contexts where patients are not able to infer their treatment status from their experienced health outcomes. For similar reasons, the double blinding strategy is not feasible in advertising situations because a consumer always sees an ad before deciding to skip it or to see it fully. Thus, ad consumption per se cannot be randomized.
 
4
For more reading, see Wilbur et al. (2013) who discusses the effect ad-skipping can have on audience composition and how networks might think about incorporating audience externalities into the pricing of ad spots.
 
5
For an example of such data, see http://​www.​finnpanel.​fi/​en/​tv.​php (not necessarily the same as the country in our sample.) Examples of the types of devices used here include the UNITAM meter by Nielsen Media Research (Unitam 2009) and the RapidMeter by Kantar (2012). For a video demonstrating how Nielsen’s system works, see https://​www.​youtube.​com/​watch?​v=​jYrVijea0UM.
 
6
If a consumer finds an advertisement immediately after switching channels, that advertisement is also coded as partially watched. The inclusion of such ‘accidental’ consumption is unlikely to be correlated with the consumer’s purchase patterns, especially taking into account the time controls we include in the analysis.
 
7
TV ads also cannot be targeted to an individual − all individuals watching the same show see the same ad.
 
8
TVision Insights uses a Microsoft Kinect device to identify who is in the room and whose face and eyes are directed towards the TV screen. A handful of other companies have created mobile apps that passively monitor surrounding noise and can recognize shows and ads through audio tags called “watermarks” that are contained in TV content. This technology can be used to determine if an individual is in the same room as the TV, but it does not resolve the question of whether the individual is paying attention.
 
9
“Eye-tracking” data (e.g., Teixeira et al., 2010) like that collected by TVision holds promise in improving measurement of advertising attention, but we have not seen these data collected at scale in field-settings and matched to purchases. To give a sense of scale, TVision devices are currently installed in 2,000 homes in the US as part of an opt-in study, while Nielsen devices are installed in 42,000 homes in the US.
 
10
The distribution of household ad-skip rates we observe is similar to the distribution reported in Wilbur (2016, Figure 8).
 
11
Typically, reported skip-rates of TV ads are lower than skip-rates of online ads. This difference may arise because the effort required to skip an ad online (ignoring a banner ad or clicking to skip a YouTube ad) is generally less than the effort required to skip a TV commercial (changing the channel and monitoring when to return to the program). Some advertising executives we spoke to stated that it could be because TV technology typically requires active avoidance: the passive default option for an online consumer is to ignore the ad, while the action that involves some effort on his part is to click on it. In television advertising, this is reversed: the passive default option for the consumer is to view the ad, while the action that involves some effort on his part is to change the channel.
 
12
Variables considered include the brand of the ad, show genre, network in which the ad airs, product category, location of the commercial break within the show and the slot within the break, day of week and hour of show.
 
13
What could be the psychological underpinnings of such complementarity with product purchases? While we cannot provide data-based support for more micro-explanations, we conjecture one reason consumers may watch more ads of products purchased recently may derive from “licensing,” wherein users watch ads of others consuming the product as a way to justify to themselves their own consumption (Shafir et al., 1993). Behavioral researchers such as Prelec and Lowenstein (1998) have pointed out that such behaviors are likely when consumption of the product evokes a sense of guilt (e.g., expensive luxury items, junk food, indulgent goods). Another explanation is that watching ads of products purchased recently may provide utility to users from re-living the felt-utility from enjoyable past consumption of the product. Past literature (e.g., Lowenstein and Elster 1992) has pointed out that reliving and contemplating past experiences is a source of significant utility for human beings. Mere repeated exposure may also predict a causal relationship between purchase histories and subsequent advertising consumption. The reason is that both purchasing and consuming a product usually imply exposure to that same product. Repeated exposures, including the ones occurring during consumption, may lead to a higher liking of the product as well as of content related to the product, including its advertisements. For example, the results from Bornstein and D’Agostino (1994) suggest that repeated exposure may increase a consumer’s processing fluency towards product-related material, which she may misattribute to the merits of the ad copy or of the product itself. Finally, a body of literature has documented the fact that decision-makers display selective attention (Cherry 1953; Deutsch and Deutsch 1963; Wolford and Morrison 1980; Tacikowski and Nowicka 2010, among others), often directing it towards aspects that are relevant to the self. While we are unaware of work specifically linking purchase histories to subsequent attention selection, it is possible that this mechanism leads consumers to focus more on advertisements about products they have bought in the past. In particular, an advertisement featuring a previously bought product may merit the attention of the viewer, leading her to be less likely to think about immediate alternatives, such as skipping the advertisement by switching the channel.
 
14
We considered cumulative quantity measures ranging from quantity purchased in the preceding day, \(\tilde {Q}_{ijt,1}\), to quantity purchased over the preceding four weeks, \(\tilde {Q}_{ijt,28}\). We found a positive and significant (α = 0.05) relationship between ad consumption and cumulative quantity for [\(\tilde {Q}_{ijt,11},\tilde {Q}_{ijt,15}].\) Outside of this range the relationship between cumulative quantity and ad consumption was consistently positive, but not statistically significant.
 
15
This viewpoint has parallels in the applied econometric literature. For example, Angrist and Krueger (1991) estimate the effect of schooling on earnings using quarter of birth as an instrument for years of education. The typical expectation is that those of higher ability will find schooling easier and will obtain more schooling to signal their ability. Thus, a priori we may expect that OLS estimates of earnings on years of schooling are upward biased because of omitted unobserved ability that is positively correlated with earnings and schooling. Alternatively, it may be possible that there is no signaling, or that some individuals with higher earning potential drop out of school earlier to pursue their own endeavors. On instrumenting for years of schooling, Angrist and Kreuger find the IV coefficient to be positive and slightly larger than the OLS estimate in several specifications, indicating if anything that OLS is slightly biased downward.
 
16
Recall that we will control for seasonality in our regressions using a week fixed effects, so what is relevant is whether there is a systematic relationship between advertising and chain level prices after controlling for such seasonality. We explore this by regressing the weekly price series pooled across all brands and chains on a set of chain, brand, and week FEs. Similarly, we regress weekly ad exposures pooled across brands on a set of brand and week FEs. Finally, we calculate the correlation between the residuals from these two regressions for each chain and brand. For all brands, we fail to reject the null that there is systematic correlation in the level of ad exposures and the prices faced by consumers at the chains in the sample. After controlling for seasonality, there does not seem to be evidence of coordination between retail prices and more intensive advertising on TV.
 
17
In Appendix H, we show that our results are not sensitive to local changes to how we define an ad as “skipped”. Our results remain unaffected if we define an ad as “skipped” if the fraction viewed is < 1, 0.95, 0.9, 0.8 or 0.75. Similarly, the descriptive results from our main specification in Column 1 of Table 4 do not change qualitatively if we instead employ the binary skip or watch indicator as the dependent variable.
 
18
Equation (4) is quasilinear because by dividing through by \(e^{\gamma _{0}+\mu \epsilon _{0t}^{G}}\), a monotone transformation of \(U^{G}\left (.\right )\), we can write \(U\left (\left .x_{0t}...x_{Jt}\right |\boldsymbol {A}_{t-1}\right )=x_{0t}+U\left (\left .x_{1t}...x_{Jt}\right |\boldsymbol {A}_{t-1}\right )\).
 
19
τ is not identified separately from the intercept and is absorbed into α 0.
 
20
These results are meant to illustrate the importance of considering demand-side complementarities and the value of endogenizing the decision to consume advertising in assessing these targeting scenarios. A caveat is we do not accommodate competitive price and advertising response in reaction to the improved price and advertising targeting by the focal advertiser. Thus, the simulations do not speak to equilibrium outcomes in a market with improved addressability and targeting. Doing this would require specifying a supply-side model of price and advertising competition, which is beyond the scope of the current analysis.
 
21
For example, suppose we observe b j t exposures by advertiser j on day t = 1,.., 106 in Fall 2011 in the data. In our counterfactuals, we hold b j t fixed for each t and vary how the b j t exposures are allocated across different sets of consumers. Thus, the ad-side control variable for the firm in all our counterfactuals is a set of indicators \(\left \{ \tilde {b}_{ijt};i=1,..,N\right \} \) such that \(\tilde {b}_{ijt}=1\) if consumer i gets allocated ads on day t, and 0 otherwise, and such that \({\sum }_{i=1}^{N}\tilde {b}_{ijt}=b_{jt}\,\forall t\).
 
22
We also analyzed the case in which firms engage exclusively in targeted pricing. We find that this policy dominates targeting based on ad-viewing behavior for all firms. This does not imply that firms should focus their efforts on targeted pricing, however, because such policies require a great deal of knowledge about each household’s demand curve. In contrast, our focal targeting policy only requires data on households’ ad-viewing behaviors.
 
23
For simplicity, we do not account for the fact that some sophisticated consumers could change their ad viewing behavior in order to influence future prices in the price discrimination scenario.
 
24
For the remainder of the regressions reported here, we restrict our analyses to only include the households who made at least one purchase and were exposed to at least one ad.
 
25
We reject the null hypothesis that the observed purchase quantities for households in the bottom quartile and middle two quartiles of the ad consumption distribution are drawn from the same distribution (p ≈ 0); we also reject the null for the comparison between the middle two quartiles and the upper quartile of the ad consumption distribution (p ≈ 0).
 
26
This field was included in the first version of the dataset released by WCAI, but not in the final version of the data released by WCAI. We use it only to assess informally our timing assumptions.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Ackerberg, D (2001). Empirically distinguishing informative and prestige effects of advertising. The RAND Journal of Economics, 32(2), 316–333.CrossRef Ackerberg, D (2001). Empirically distinguishing informative and prestige effects of advertising. The RAND Journal of Economics, 32(2), 316–333.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Allenby, G.M., & Rossi, P.E. (1999). Marketing models of consumer heterogeneity. Journal of Econometrics, 89, 57–78.CrossRef Allenby, G.M., & Rossi, P.E. (1999). Marketing models of consumer heterogeneity. Journal of Econometrics, 89, 57–78.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Anderson, T., & Rubin, H. (1949). Estimation of the parameters of a single equation in a complete system of stochastic equations. The Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 20-1, 46–63.CrossRef Anderson, T., & Rubin, H. (1949). Estimation of the parameters of a single equation in a complete system of stochastic equations. The Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 20-1, 46–63.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Angrist, J., & Krueger, A. (1991). Does compulsory school attendance affect schooling and earnings? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(4), 979–1014.CrossRef Angrist, J., & Krueger, A. (1991). Does compulsory school attendance affect schooling and earnings? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(4), 979–1014.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Angrist, J., Imbens, G.W., & Krueger, A. (1999). Jackknife instrumental variables estimation. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 14, 57–67.CrossRef Angrist, J., Imbens, G.W., & Krueger, A. (1999). Jackknife instrumental variables estimation. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 14, 57–67.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ashenfelter, O., & Krueger, A.B. (1994). Estimates of the economic returns to schooling from a new sample of twins. American Economic Review, 84(5), 1157–1173. Ashenfelter, O., & Krueger, A.B. (1994). Estimates of the economic returns to schooling from a new sample of twins. American Economic Review, 84(5), 1157–1173.
Zurück zum Zitat Auld, D.A.L. (1974). Advertising and the theory of consumer choice. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 88(3), 480–87.CrossRef Auld, D.A.L. (1974). Advertising and the theory of consumer choice. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 88(3), 480–87.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ausubel, L. (1999). Adverse selection in the credit card market. University of Maryland: mimeo. Ausubel, L. (1999). Adverse selection in the credit card market. University of Maryland: mimeo.
Zurück zum Zitat Bagwell, K. (2007). The economic analysis of advertising. Handbook of industrial organization, 3, 1701–1844.CrossRef Bagwell, K. (2007). The economic analysis of advertising. Handbook of industrial organization, 3, 1701–1844.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Becker, G., & Murphy, K. (1993). A simple theory of advertising as a good or a bad. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(4), 941–964.CrossRef Becker, G., & Murphy, K. (1993). A simple theory of advertising as a good or a bad. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(4), 941–964.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bhat, C. (2005). A multiple Discrete-Continuous extreme value model: Formulation and application to discretionary Time-Use decisions. Transportation Research Part B, 39(8), 679–707.CrossRef Bhat, C. (2005). A multiple Discrete-Continuous extreme value model: Formulation and application to discretionary Time-Use decisions. Transportation Research Part B, 39(8), 679–707.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bornstein, R.F., & D’Agostino, P.R. (1994). The attribution and discounting of perceptual fluency: Preliminary tests of a perceptual fluency/attributional model of the mere exposure effect. Social Cognition, 12.2(1994), 103–128.CrossRef Bornstein, R.F., & D’Agostino, P.R. (1994). The attribution and discounting of perceptual fluency: Preliminary tests of a perceptual fluency/attributional model of the mere exposure effect. Social Cognition, 12.2(1994), 103–128.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bound, J., Jaeger, D., & Baker, R. (1995). Problems with instrumental variable estimation when the correlation between the instruments and the endogenous explanatory variables is weak. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 90, 443–450. Bound, J., Jaeger, D., & Baker, R. (1995). Problems with instrumental variable estimation when the correlation between the instruments and the endogenous explanatory variables is weak. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 90, 443–450.
Zurück zum Zitat Bronnenberg, B., Dubé, J.-P., & Mela, C. (2010). Do DVRs influence consumers’ Brand Purchases? Journal of Marketing Research, 47(6), 998–1010.CrossRef Bronnenberg, B., Dubé, J.-P., & Mela, C. (2010). Do DVRs influence consumers’ Brand Purchases? Journal of Marketing Research, 47(6), 998–1010.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Butters, G. (1977). Equilibrium distributions of sales and advertising prices. Review of Economic Studies, 44(3), 465–91.CrossRef Butters, G. (1977). Equilibrium distributions of sales and advertising prices. Review of Economic Studies, 44(3), 465–91.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cherry, E.C. (1953). Some experiments on the recognition of speech, with one and with two ears. The Journal of the Acoustical Society of America, 25(5), 975–979.CrossRef Cherry, E.C. (1953). Some experiments on the recognition of speech, with one and with two ears. The Journal of the Acoustical Society of America, 25(5), 975–979.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chintagunta, P., Dubé, J.-P., & Goh, K.Y. (2005). Beyond the endogeneity bias: The effect of unmeasured brand characteristics on household level brand choice models. Management Science, 51(5), 832–849.CrossRef Chintagunta, P., Dubé, J.-P., & Goh, K.Y. (2005). Beyond the endogeneity bias: The effect of unmeasured brand characteristics on household level brand choice models. Management Science, 51(5), 832–849.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chintagunta, P., & Nair, H. (2011). Discrete choice models of consumer demand in marketing. Marketing Science, 30(6), 977–996.CrossRef Chintagunta, P., & Nair, H. (2011). Discrete choice models of consumer demand in marketing. Marketing Science, 30(6), 977–996.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat DellaVigna, S., & Gentzkow, M. (2010). Persuasion: Empirical evidence. annual review of economics, 2, 643–669.CrossRef DellaVigna, S., & Gentzkow, M. (2010). Persuasion: Empirical evidence. annual review of economics, 2, 643–669.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Deng, Y., & Mela, C. (2017). TV viewing and advertising targeting. Journal of Marketing Research, forthcoming. Deng, Y., & Mela, C. (2017). TV viewing and advertising targeting. Journal of Marketing Research, forthcoming.
Zurück zum Zitat Deutsch, J.A., & Deutsch, D. (1963). Attention: Some theoretical considerations. Psychological Review, 1(80), 70. Deutsch, J.A., & Deutsch, D. (1963). Attention: Some theoretical considerations. Psychological Review, 1(80), 70.
Zurück zum Zitat Fox, J., & Lazatti, N. (2016). Identification of discrete choice models for bundles and binary games. working paper, Rice Univ., Dept. of Economics. Fox, J., & Lazatti, N. (2016). Identification of discrete choice models for bundles and binary games. working paper, Rice Univ., Dept. of Economics.
Zurück zum Zitat Gentzkow, M. (2007). Valuing new goods in a model with complementarity: Online newspapers. The American Economic Review, 97(3), 713–744.CrossRef Gentzkow, M. (2007). Valuing new goods in a model with complementarity: Online newspapers. The American Economic Review, 97(3), 713–744.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman, G., & Shapiro, C. (1984). Informative advertising with differentiated products. Review of Economic Studies, 51(1), 63–81.CrossRef Grossman, G., & Shapiro, C. (1984). Informative advertising with differentiated products. Review of Economic Studies, 51(1), 63–81.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Isen, A.M. (1992). The influence of positive affect on cognitive organization: Some implications for the influence of advertising on decisions about products and brands. In Mitchell, A.A. (Ed.) Advertising exposure, memory, and choice. Hillsdale: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. Isen, A.M. (1992). The influence of positive affect on cognitive organization: Some implications for the influence of advertising on decisions about products and brands. In Mitchell, A.A. (Ed.) Advertising exposure, memory, and choice. Hillsdale: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.
Zurück zum Zitat Keller, K. (1983). Conceptualizing, measuring and managing Customer-Based brand equity. Journal of Marketing, 57(1), 1–22.CrossRef Keller, K. (1983). Conceptualizing, measuring and managing Customer-Based brand equity. Journal of Marketing, 57(1), 1–22.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kim, K., Allenby, G.M., & Rossi, P.E. (2002). Modeling consumer demand for variety. Marketing Science, 21(3), 229–250.CrossRef Kim, K., Allenby, G.M., & Rossi, P.E. (2002). Modeling consumer demand for variety. Marketing Science, 21(3), 229–250.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lee, S., Kim, J., & Allenby, G.M. (2013). A direct utility model for asymmetric complements. Marketing Science, 32(3), 454–470.CrossRef Lee, S., Kim, J., & Allenby, G.M. (2013). A direct utility model for asymmetric complements. Marketing Science, 32(3), 454–470.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lowenstein, G., & Elster, J. (1992). Utility from memory and anticipation. In Choice over time (pp. 213–34). New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Lowenstein, G., & Elster, J. (1992). Utility from memory and anticipation. In Choice over time (pp. 213–34). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Zurück zum Zitat Naik, P.A., Mantrala, M.K., & Sawyer, A.G. (1998). Planning media schedules in the presence of dynamic advertising quality. Marketing Science, 17(3), 214–235.CrossRef Naik, P.A., Mantrala, M.K., & Sawyer, A.G. (1998). Planning media schedules in the presence of dynamic advertising quality. Marketing Science, 17(3), 214–235.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nelson, P. (1970). Information and consumer behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 78(2), 311–329.CrossRef Nelson, P. (1970). Information and consumer behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 78(2), 311–329.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nelson, P. (1974). Advertising as information. Journal of Political Economy, 82(4), 729–754.CrossRef Nelson, P. (1974). Advertising as information. Journal of Political Economy, 82(4), 729–754.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Prelec, D., & Lowenstein, G. (1998). The red and the black: Mental accounting of savings and debt. Marketing Science, 17, 4–28.CrossRef Prelec, D., & Lowenstein, G. (1998). The red and the black: Mental accounting of savings and debt. Marketing Science, 17, 4–28.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Revelet, D., & Train, K. (2001). Customer-specific taste parameters and mixed Logit: Households’ choice of electricity supplier. Berkeley: Working paper, University of California. Revelet, D., & Train, K. (2001). Customer-specific taste parameters and mixed Logit: Households’ choice of electricity supplier. Berkeley: Working paper, University of California.
Zurück zum Zitat Schweidel, D.A., & Kent, R.J. (2010). Predictors of the gap between program and commercial audiences: An investigation using live tuning data. Journal of Marketing, 74(3), 18–33.CrossRef Schweidel, D.A., & Kent, R.J. (2010). Predictors of the gap between program and commercial audiences: An investigation using live tuning data. Journal of Marketing, 74(3), 18–33.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shafir, E., Simonson, I., & Tversky, A. (1993). Reason-based choice. Cognition, 49(2), 11–36.CrossRef Shafir, E., Simonson, I., & Tversky, A. (1993). Reason-based choice. Cognition, 49(2), 11–36.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Siddarth, S., & Chattopadhyay, A. (1998). To Zap or not to Zap: A study of the determinants of channel switching during commercials. Marketing Science, 17(2), 124–138.CrossRef Siddarth, S., & Chattopadhyay, A. (1998). To Zap or not to Zap: A study of the determinants of channel switching during commercials. Marketing Science, 17(2), 124–138.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stock, J., Wright, J., & Yogo, M. (2002). A survey of weak instruments and weak identification in generalized method of moments. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 20, 518–529.CrossRef Stock, J., Wright, J., & Yogo, M. (2002). A survey of weak instruments and weak identification in generalized method of moments. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 20, 518–529.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tacikowski, P., & Nowicka, A. (2010). Allocation of attention to self-name and self-face: An ERP study. Biological Psychology, 84(2), 318–324.CrossRef Tacikowski, P., & Nowicka, A. (2010). Allocation of attention to self-name and self-face: An ERP study. Biological Psychology, 84(2), 318–324.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Teixeira, T.S., Wedel, M., & Pieters, R. (2010). Moment-to-moment optimal branding in TV commercials: Preventing avoidance by pulsing. Marketing Science, 29 (5), 783–804.CrossRef Teixeira, T.S., Wedel, M., & Pieters, R. (2010). Moment-to-moment optimal branding in TV commercials: Preventing avoidance by pulsing. Marketing Science, 29 (5), 783–804.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Varian, H. (1992). Microeconomic analysis, 3rd edn. New York: W.W.Norton and Co. Varian, H. (1992). Microeconomic analysis, 3rd edn. New York: W.W.Norton and Co.
Zurück zum Zitat Wales, T., & Woodland, A. (1983). Estimation of consumer demand equations with binding Non-Negativity constraints. Journal of Econometrics, 21(3), 263–285.CrossRef Wales, T., & Woodland, A. (1983). Estimation of consumer demand equations with binding Non-Negativity constraints. Journal of Econometrics, 21(3), 263–285.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wilbur, K. (2008). A Two-Sided, empirical model of television advertising and viewing markets. Marketing Science, 27(3), 356–378.CrossRef Wilbur, K. (2008). A Two-Sided, empirical model of television advertising and viewing markets. Marketing Science, 27(3), 356–378.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wilbur, K, Xu, L., & Kempe, D. (2013). Correcting audience externalities in television advertising. Marketing Science, 32(6), 892–912.CrossRef Wilbur, K, Xu, L., & Kempe, D. (2013). Correcting audience externalities in television advertising. Marketing Science, 32(6), 892–912.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wilbur, K. (2016). Advertising content and television advertising avoidance. Journal of Media Economics, 29(2), 51–72.CrossRef Wilbur, K. (2016). Advertising content and television advertising avoidance. Journal of Media Economics, 29(2), 51–72.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wolford, G., & Morrison, F. (1980). Processing of unattended visual information. Memory & Cognition, 8(6), 521–527.CrossRef Wolford, G., & Morrison, F. (1980). Processing of unattended visual information. Memory & Cognition, 8(6), 521–527.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Television ad-skipping, consumption complementarities and the consumer demand for advertising
verfasst von
Anna E. Tuchman
Harikesh S. Nair
Pedro M. Gardete
Publikationsdatum
03.10.2017
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Quantitative Marketing and Economics / Ausgabe 2/2018
Print ISSN: 1570-7156
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-711X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-017-9192-y