Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Journal of International Entrepreneurship 3/2023

Open Access 17.03.2022

Institutional change and entrepreneurship as occupational choice—The case of South Korea

verfasst von: Diana Schüler

Erschienen in: Journal of International Entrepreneurship | Ausgabe 3/2023

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Even though research on the influence of institutions on entrepreneurial activities has recently gained scholarly attention, most studies are quantitative cross-country analyses that assume response homogeneity. Qualitative single-country studies that provide deeper insights into institutional peculiarities are still rare, especially in the East Asian context. Based on qualitative data generated from semi-structured interviews, this study examines the institutional environment for entrepreneurship in South Korea and its latest changes to explain the recent wave of newly established corporations. Building on Scott’s distinction of institutional dimensions, this article demonstrates how significant changes in regulative institutions pushed forward by the Korean central government have decreased individual financial risks and have created a surge in business foundations. At the same time, normative institutions have remained almost unchanged, while changes of the cognitive institutional dimension in the form of entrepreneurship education are underway. The findings suggest that regulative institutions play a bigger role for entrepreneurial activities than cognitive or normative institutions, as people start a business despite unfavorable informal institutions. Theory should therefore reevaluate the importance and effective power of each institutional dimension on entrepreneurial activities. Policymakers who put high emphasis on regulative institutions should pay attention to potential moral hazards arising from generous support programs.
Hinweise

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Summary highlights
Contributions of the Paper: The paper provides deeper insights into the three-dimensional institutional environment for entrepreneurship in Korea. It allows a better understanding of institutional elements, their origin, and recent changes.
Research questions/purpose: The purpose of this study is to examine Korea’s perceived institutional environment for entrepreneurship as an occupational choice among young Koreans with the goal of finding evidence for the rise in entrepreneurial activities.
Methodology: Qualitative study.
Database/Information : Semi-structured interviews with experts and entrepreneurs.
Results/Findings: Regulative institutions have improved noticeably and possess the most power over the occupational choice for entrepreneurship. Cognitive and normative institutions are still unfavorable and are not the main driver of entrepreneurial activities.
Limitations (If There Are Any): Low generalizability and impossibility of statistical inference.
Recommendations for further research: Further research should examine the role of cognitive and normative institutions to verify the hypothesis that they are not as crucial for the decision to start a business as regulative institutions. Qualitative studies should be conducted in other countries as well.
Managerial/Theoretical Implications: Formal institutions overrule informal institutions in encouraging entrepreneurship and they change quicker.Formal institutions overrule informal institutions in encouraging entrepreneurship and they change quicker.
Practical Implications and Recommendations as well as Public Policy Recommendations: Stronger awareness by the government of moral hazard issues is recommended.

Introduction

Entrepreneurship has been found to positively influence economic growth (Wennekers and Thurik 1999; Acs et al. 2012; Braunerhjelm et al. 2010; Audretsch et al. 2006). Growth-oriented (Stam and van Stel 2011) and opportunity-driven entrepreneurship in particular (Acs and Varga 2005) contribute to economic growth and job creation (Hathaway 2013). Therefore, examining and understanding the factors that drive entrepreneurial activities is vital. In recent years, research on the connection between institutions and entrepreneurship has increased (Bjørnskov and Foss 2016; Urbano et al. 2019), and many scholars have adopted the institutional theory of North (1990) and the approach by Scott (2014), who distinguishes between regulative, cognitive, and normative institutions. The general hypothesis is that institutions more conducive to entrepreneurship generate higher entrepreneurial activity and consequently improve the economic performance of a given country (Urbano and Alvarez 2014). Researchers often find that regulative institutions like strong property rights, business freedom, and fewer procedures to start a business positively influence entrepreneurial activities (Stenholm et al. 2013; Fuentelsaz et al. 2015). Cognitive institutions like skills and knowledge about doing business are also found to be beneficial (Valdez and Richardson 2013; Urbano and Alvarez 2014; Aparicio et al. 2016). Others find normative factors like the belief that entrepreneurship is a good career choice to be positively related to entrepreneurship (Bosma et al. 2018).
While most research focuses on evidence of cross-country effects generated from panel data using institutional indices, Bjørnskov and Foss (2016:301) argue that assuming homogeneous responses to institutional pressure is a shortcoming of previous literature in that it “merely identif[ies] average treatment effects that can easily hide very different effects across industries or countries.” Scholars like Busenitz et al. (2000) and Gupta et al. (2014) have assessed individual countries’ institutional profiles (CIP) for entrepreneurship, focusing more on the perception of different institutional dimensions and their effect on entrepreneurship. This article follows this direction by presenting a single-country study of the perceived institutional environment for entrepreneurship in South Korea (hereinafter referred to as Korea).
Korea is an interesting case to study entrepreneurship due to its economic development from one of the poorest countries in the 1950s to a highly industrialized member of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) since 1996. This development can largely be contributed to family-led conglomerates like Samsung, Hyundai, or LG, the so-called Chaebol which has been supported and nurtured by the central government throughout Korea’s catch-up phase (Amsden 1989; Jones and SaKong 1985; Joh 2015). Only in the 1990s did the government’s focus shift to technology-oriented venture businesses (Kwon 2010:253) as a new engine for Korea’s dwindling economic growth. At the same time, the Asian Financial Crisis in 1997 legitimized government support for business foundations to fight increasing unemployment (Choi and Kim 2004; Song 2007). After the burst of the dot-com bubble in the early 2000s, however, entrepreneurial activities slowed down, and public support schemes were rationalized. Only when President Park Geun-hye (2013–2017) vowed to transform Korea into “a startup nation” (Cha 2015) under her “Creative Economy” paradigm, new business foundations gained momentum once more. Consequently, the institutional environment in which this happened constitutes a matter of interest.
Figure 1 shows the number of newly established corporations between 2000 and 2019. Between 2000/2 and 2008/1, the average growth rate of new foundations was − 0.6%, but it was 3.6% between 2008/2 and 2017/1. For founders younger than 30 years old, the average growth rate was 7.0%, and for those in their 30 s, it was 2.3% during that period. Moreover, the number of corporations increased by 80% between 2008/1 and 2017/1. Thus, there is a visible increase of newly established corporations in the 2010s.
This study’s goal is to examine Korea’s perceived institutional environment for entrepreneurship as an occupational choice among young Koreans and its recent changes. Considering the three different institutional dimensions (regulative, cognitive, normative), the most salient type of institution in encouraging entrepreneurship can be identified, providing a possible explanation for the increase of newly established corporations. At the same time, the findings hint at the relevance of each institutional dimension for entrepreneurship and their order of change.
The empirical findings draw on data gathered from 31 semi-structured interviews with entrepreneurs and experts on entrepreneurship in Korea. Additional secondary literature, official statistics, and government documents complement the dataset. Together, the data provide a rich source for the identification of important institutional changes and connections between the respective dimensions. In this way, this article provides a thorough analysis of the institutional environment for entrepreneurship in Korea, which, to the author’s knowledge, has not been accomplished so far.
The results indicate that entrepreneurship-friendly regulative institutions have contributed significantly to the rise in business foundations. However, cognitive and especially normative institutions are not yet fully favorable for entrepreneurship despite some initial changes. The findings suggest an institutional asymmetry between the formal and the informal institutions. Yet, in the battle of the conflicting institutional forces, it seems that regulative institutions are more powerful in encouraging entrepreneurship than cognitive and normative institutions are preventing business foundations. This puts the role of informal institutions in entrepreneurial activities into question. Their relevance for the decision to start a business seems to be negligible if regulative institutions are supportive enough. The results also indicate that informal institutions change slower than formal institutions and can hardly be changed top-down—it is up to society or even entrepreneurs themselves to change informal institutions (Elert and Henrekson 2021). This finding contributes also to the theory on institutional change (Williamson 2000). Overall, this paper provides important insights for entrepreneurship scholars concerning the institutional environment for entrepreneurship as well as policymakers from Korea and countries with a similar entrepreneurial history.
The remainder of the article is structured as follows: The “Literature review” section reviews the theoretical and empirical literature related to entrepreneurship and institutions, starting with the conceptualization of entrepreneurship in this paper. The “Methodology” section explains the methodology and data collection. Results from each institutional dimension are presented in the “Results” section. The “Conclusion” section concludes the paper.

Literature review

Conceptualization of entrepreneurship

There is little consensus among scholars on how to define entrepreneurship. Besides the theoretical fragmentation (see also Wennekers and Thurik [1999:31]) and various types of entrepreneurs (Sendra-Pons et al. 2021:2) including Knight’s (1971 [1921]) risk-taking entrepreneur, Schumpeter’s (1983 [1934]:75) innovating entrepreneur, and Kirzner’s (1974:34) alert entrepreneur, there is heterogeneity in empirical studies (Marcotte 2013). Parker (2009:6) argues that different empirical measurements reflect not only the different theoretical approaches but also the diverse scholarly interests. For instance, economists are often interested in the analysis of incentives or occupational choices, so they tend to assess entrepreneurship via business owners and the self-employed. In this context, “necessity entrepreneurs,” who are those facing “no better choices for work,” are often distinguished from “opportunity entrepreneurs,” i.e., those who pursue “a business opportunity for personal interest” (Reynolds et al. 2001:8). Business and entrepreneurship scholars assess entrepreneurship in the light of behavior, cognition, and perception (Parker 2009:6), more frequently taking the Schumpeterian or Kirznerian perspective. Yet, despite the importance of innovations, Schumpeter’s theory is “abstract and not easily operational at the empirical level” (Henrekson and Sanandaji 2020:735). For instance, the concept is transitional, meaning every Schumpeterian entrepreneur sooner or later becomes an owner-manager unless he keeps innovating (Schumpeter 1983 [1934]:78). New firm formation rather than self-employment or small business ownership might be the best empirical proxy available (Nyström 2008:271). Henrekson and Sanandaji (2020:737) also find evidence that newly registered corporations are closest to the Schumpeterian type of entrepreneur, as their legal status reflects higher quality and growth potential.
The study at hand focuses on the institutions that encourage or prevent the type of entrepreneurship that spurs economic growth and job creation. In Korea, self-employment is often characterized as “poor entrepreneurship” with low profits and productivity (Yun 2013:58 f.), so it disqualifies as a measure for entrepreneurship in this study. While also imperfect, the quantitative measure of newly established corporations is the best proxy available because it has a qualitative dimension through its legal status without being too narrowly defined. Additionally, it allows entrepreneurship to be regarded as an occupational choice in the pursuit of an opportunity. It captures the dynamic component of entrepreneurship (Wennekers and Thurik 1999:33) in that it only counts the newly created and not the already existing corporations. Finally, while institutions “shape entrepreneurial behavior along the entire entrepreneurial process” (Valdez and Richardson 2013:1150), the decision to establish a new business is commonly used for assessing the connection between institutions and entrepreneurship.

Institutions and entrepreneurship

Institutions have been ignored within economics due to their complexity (North 1990:16, Williamson 2000:595, Ménard 2018:6) until the statement by North (1990:12) saying that “institutions matter” for economic performance became widely accepted. North (1994:360) defines institutions as “the humanly devised constraints that structure human interaction,” which are “made up of formal constraints (e.g., rules, laws, constitutions), informal constraints (e.g., norms of behavior, conventions, self-imposed codes of conduct), and their enforcement characteristics.” Accordingly, formal and informal institutions form the incentive structure for individual behavior and economic decisions, thereby indirectly influencing the economic outcome. This leads to the common theoretical proposition that institutions can spur or hamper entrepreneurial activities as a form of economic behavior “by providing an appropriate environment or by imposing barriers” (Urbano et al. 2019:24). Most analyses on how institutions affect entrepreneurship are based on North’s institutional theory (Urbano et al. 2019:26).
Although there is a debate about whether or not to address both formal and informal institutions (Bruton et al. 2010), Valdez and Richardson (2013:1150) emphasize that empirical studies concerned with macro-level entrepreneurship should examine a combination of different institutional elements because it not only allows assessing the effect of the institutional environment as a whole but also identifying the most salient institutional variables. The three institutional dimensions proposed by Scott (2014), i.e., regulative, (cultural-)cognitive, and normative institutions, provide a structured approach including both the formal and informal institutions that shape entrepreneurial activities in theory.
The regulative pillar is equivalent to formal institutions (Scott 2014). In the realm of entrepreneurship, regulative institutions comprise, for instance, tax and bankruptcy laws, industry and labor market regulations, government policies, public support schemes, fiscal incentives, and the venture capital market (Valdez and Richardson 2013:1157, Wennekers et al. 2002:41 f.).
Cognitive institutions represent the glasses through which all members of society see reality. In the entrepreneurship literature, there are two streams capturing the cognitive dimension (Valdez and Richardson 2013:1155 f.). The first one is the personality or trait approach which has been criticized for being fruitless (Gartner 1988; Davidsson 2003). The second one assesses cognitive differences at the national level based on the belief that aggregate behavior is influenced by “cognitions that are generally shared in a society” (Valdez and Richardson 2013:1155). However, there is no empirical consensus with regard to this issue. For instance, Thomas and Mueller (2000) test whether the traits innovativeness, risk propensity, internal locus of control, and energy level vary across cultures. Mitchell et al. (2000) investigate whether individual cognitions (“venturing scripts”) are decisive for starting a business and test whether these vary by country due to cultural differences. Busenitz et al. (2000:995) refer to the cognitive pillar as the shared social knowledge about entrepreneurship and prevalent skills necessary to create and run a new business. Based on this reasoning, Simón-Moya et al. (2014) and Pinho (2017) use indicators for education as proxies for the cognitive institutional dimension.
The normative pillar includes “norms of behavior, conventions, [and] self-imposed codes of conduct” (North 1994:360) as well as values which are “conceptions of the preferred or the desirable together with the construction of standards to which existing structures of behaviors can be compared and assessed” (Scott 2014:64). Norms guide people on how to do things (Valdez and Richardson 2013:1157). They arise through social interaction between humans and are maintained by means of social sanctions like shame or disrespect (Dequech 2009:72). However, whenever the rewards for disobedience outweigh the costs of social sanctions and the benefits of compliance, individuals are likely to deviate from social norms (Dequech 2009:74). In the realm of entrepreneurship, normative institutions address, for instance, the degree to which people admire and respect entrepreneurs and entrepreneurship as a career path as well as how society values creative and innovative thinking (Busenitz et al. 2000:995).
Ideally, the three institutional dimensions for entrepreneurship are complementary; however, institutions constantly change. Some argue that because formal institutions are deliberately designed and imposed centrally (Kingston and Caballero 2009:153), they can be altered quickly and overrule inert informal institutions. In contrast, Roland (2009:117) claims that informal institutions change incrementally until formal institutions are under pressure to follow suit. A compromise is to see the different perspectives on institutional change not as substitutes but as complements (Ruttan 2006:252).
Nevertheless, differences in the speed of adjustment can create asymmetries in the institutional system in the short run (North 1990:87 f.). Empirical studies in transition economies have found evidence for supportive and unsupportive institutions existing at the same time, which might undermine entrepreneurial potential (Tonoyan et al. 2010; Puffer et al. 2010; Manolova and Yan 2002; Williams and Vorley 2015).
Many scholars have examined the connection between institutions and entrepreneurial activities empirically with various models as well as sets of data, and some have also tested the link to economic growth. However, results are mixed, also due to differences in conceptualization and measurements of entrepreneurship and institutions (see Table 3 in the appendix for an overview of cross-country studies). Aparicio et al. (2016) find that regulative institutions like private coverage to obtain credit have a positive influence on entrepreneurial activity, whereas the number of procedures to start a business has a negative influence. Similarly, Urbano et al. (2020) state that the number of procedures for starting a new business and private credit coverage significantly explain the entrepreneurial activity. Fuentelsaz et al. (2015) declare that better property rights, more business and labor freedom, as well as better financial and educational capital have a positive influence on entrepreneurial activity, but more fiscal freedom exerts a negative influence. McMullen et al. (2008) find a similar result for property rights and labor freedom.
Valdez and Richardson (2013) note that cognitive institutions in the form of perceived knowledge, skill, experience required to start a new business, and fear of failure as well as normative institutions, measured via a cultural support index, have a positive influence on entrepreneurial activity. Bosma et al. (2018) also mention factors exerting such a positive influence, which are regulative institutions in the form of a smaller size of government and normative institutions in the form of the belief that entrepreneurship is a good career choice. However, Stenholm et al. (2013) declare that only regulatory interventions in the form of business freedom and ease of new business formation positively influence the rate of entrepreneurial activity. They find no significant impact of the cognitive and normative institutional dimensions. Khalilov and Yi (2021) also consider regulative institutions (economic freedom) to drive entrepreneurial activities but not normative institutions (entrepreneurial value). Thus, while there seems to be some agreement with regard to the role of regulative and cognitive institutions, there is ambiguity concerning the role of the normative institutional dimension.
Most of these quantitative cross-country studies directly draw the connection between institutions, startup rates, and economic growth. They also provide a high degree of generalizability. However, they are less helpful for evaluating the perceived institutional environment in a specific context or country, especially when assuming response heterogeneity to institutional pressure that is often neglected (Bjørnskov and Foss 2016). This can be the case, for instance, in emerging or developing economies but even in highly industrialized economies with distinct economic systems like Korea or Japan.
There are some quantitative studies evaluating the institutional environment of single countries. For instance, in his comparative study, Sahiti (2021) notes that although the regulatory environment for starting a business is rather positive, there are obstacles with access to finance, entrepreneurship education, and the overall political stability in Kosovo. Closely based on Scott’s three institutional dimensions, Busenitz et al. (2000) developed the country institutional profile (CIP) survey to measure the perception of the institutional environment for entrepreneurship in single countries. For instance, Gupta et al. (2012) and Gupta et al. (2014) conducted the CIP in Korea in 2009 and found that it ranked low in the regulative, the cognitive, and especially the normative institutional dimensions in comparison to other rapidly emerging major economies like China and India as well as other developing economies like the United Arab Emirates. Yet, Manolova et al. (2008:213), who measured the CIP in Bulgaria, Hungary, and Latvia, arrive at the conclusion that “aggregate measures of the institutional environment for entrepreneurship may mask subtle and persistent differences, especially in the role of deeply embedded and less readily observable influences such as legal and cultural traditions, or social norms and values.”
There are only few qualitative studies about the institutional arrangement for entrepreneurship, although Williams and Vorley (2015:846) suggest that it could provide deeper insights through the perceptions and experiences of entrepreneurs and experts. These views would be important for a better understanding of the institutional environment and the generation of future research questions and hypotheses. Williams and Vorley (2015), who examine how the institutional environment has shaped entrepreneurial activity in Bulgaria, focus on the effect of institutional asymmetries that undermine entrepreneurial activities. In a similar qualitative manner, Puffer et al. (2010) explore how the void of formal institutions in Russia and China affects the relationship between entrepreneurship and institutions. Following the route of Williams and Vorley (2015), the goal of this research is to find indicators for the rise in new business creations by carefully assessing Korea’s perceived institutional environment.

Recent literature on entrepreneurship in Korea

While the literature on Chaebol entrepreneurship is plentiful, research about the recent increase in entrepreneurial activities in Korea is still rare. In 2019, Robyn Klingler-Vidra and Ramon Pacheco Pardo published three articles about the phenomenon. One takes on a developmental state perspective and argues that the government’s Creative Economy Action Plan of President Park Geun-hye had a strong effect on the volume of participants in the entrepreneurial ecosystem by increasing awareness and making entrepreneurship a good career option as well as by providing more and better access to financing (Pacheco Pardo and Klingler-Vidra 2019:324). The qualitative study of Hemmert et al. (2019) explores the entrepreneurial ecosystem (EE) of Seoul according to the domains policy, culture, human capital, finance, markets, and supports. They find that Seoul’s EE is driven by national-level policy programs with a focus on financial support and that it used to lack a conducive culture for entrepreneurship due to uncertainty avoidance and fear of failure. While these studies provide interesting insights, they are not based on institutional theory. To the knowledge of the author, there is no qualitative study of the Korean institutional environment for entrepreneurship yet that explains the recent increase in entrepreneurial activities, measured as newly established corporations. Consequently, the study at hand attempts to fill this gap.

Methodology

Qualitative semi-structured interviews can reveal perceptions about institutional changes from experts on entrepreneurship and about individual experiences by entrepreneurs themselves. The qualitative approach provides a more accurate picture of the perceived institutional environment, and policymakers can profit from a better understanding of how to encourage entrepreneurship via institutional change (McMullen et al. 2008:891). After all, the perception of context is what entrepreneurs react to (Gómez-Haro et al. 2011:1680). Therefore, semi-structured interviews with 14 experts from diverse public and private organizations and 17 Koreans who already (co-)founded and were planning to find (so-called nascent founders) or give up on founding an enterprise were conducted. Questions were based on and derived from the three institutional dimensions explained in the “Literature review” section.
The interviews were conducted between October 2016 and March 2017 in Seoul, Daejeon, and Gyeonggi Province (see Tables 4 and 5 in the appendix for details on interviewees). These locations were targeted because Seoul metropolitan area is the economic center of Korea (Lee 2009:357 f.) and Daejeon is Korea’s national R&D hub (Oh and Yeom 2012).
The sampling method for the recruitment of interviewees was purposive and snowball sampling.1 Entrepreneurs were mostly approached at startup events or via the researcher’s private network. In the selection process, the researcher focused on young founders in their 20 s and 30 s, and in terms of legal form on “Representative Directors” (CEOs) and “Joint Stock Companies” to avoid necessity entrepreneurship. The founders’ gender and educational background as well as industry and level of innovativeness of the business idea were of secondary importance. Questions for entrepreneurs were more comprehensive on the normative aspects.
Many experts were recruited similarly to entrepreneurs, but some were contacted via email after online-based research for accelerators, incubators, etc. Depending on the expert, the questionnaire focused more on specific aspects. For instance, venture capital experts received more questions on financing issues.
Especially early interviews were conducted in English whenever the interviewees agreed. As the researcher’s Korean language skills improved during field research, some interviews could be conducted in Korean. In those cases, a Korean version of the questionnaire was used, which was translated by a bilingual research assistant.
Data saturation occurred at around 30 interviews. Interview recordings were first transcribed by the researcher (interviews in Korean were transcribed by an instructed Korean native speaker). Then, the data were analyzed according to the guidelines suggested by Taylor-Power and Renner (2003). Coding started with the three broad themes, i.e., the regulative, cognitive, and normative institutional dimensions. Interview questions were already framed around these three themes and subthemes which were derived from the literature. However, some questions were openly formulated to allow interviewees to raise new topics and issues. Eventually, three to four subthemes emerged from each theme during the coding process, and for most subthemes, further categories emerged from the answers. These build the structure of the “Results” section. To find possible connections as well as cause and effect relationships between subthemes (Taylor-Power and Renner 2003:5, Saldaña 2009:187), the MAXQDA Code Relations Browser was used to show the closeness and overlap between main themes and all subthemes. In addition to quotes by experts (EP1–EP14) and entrepreneurs (E1–E17) integrated into the text (in italics), Tables 6 , 7 and 8 in the appendix present additional selected interview material.
Since interviewees could not elaborate in detail on some crucial issues, the researcher filled these gaps with secondary data from the literature, statistics, and official documents.

Results

The cognitive institutional pillar

Korea’s public and private sector education system

In international comparison, education levels in Korea stand out. According to the World Bank Education Statistics, Korea had a relatively high net enrolment rate in secondary education (98.01%) and an exceptionally high gross enrolment rate in tertiary education (94.35%) in 2017.2 Pursuant to OECD data, 70% of young adults (25–34 years old) held a tertiary education degree in 2018, which constitutes the highest proportion among OECD countries (OECD 2019:50).3 Korea is also known for its excessive private tutoring system with private educational institutes (hagwŏn). As per the Kostat (2017) Private Education Expenditures Survey, total private sector expenditures for education rose from 18.1 trillion KRW (15.56 billion USD) in 2016 to 18.6 trillion KRW (16 billion USD) in 2017, while the participation rate increased from 67.8 to 70.5%.4 The main reasons for participating in private sector education were to compensate for classes in the public education system (47.4%) and to prepare for higher school levels in the case of high school students (31.2%).
Shin (2012) argues that the high level of tertiary education stems from a combination of imported foreign ideas of universities, high value of education based on Confucianism, and, most importantly, the rapid economic development of Korea since the 1960s. The incremental expansion of education from elementary to graduate level during Korea’s rapid industrialization process explains the high demand for private sector education (Shin 2012:61). Additionally, the government education policy produced bottlenecks at upper education levels that shifted higher with time, up to the national standardized exam for college and university admission (Kim 2002). Therefore, the ultimate purpose of the public and private education system is to prepare students for the competitive Korean College Scholastic Ability Test (KCSAT) that filters the elite from the population at large (Byun et al. 2012:223).5 Since the KCSAT is a standardized multiple-choice test, a homogenous style of teaching by rote and memorizing is widespread.
Reforms of the education system to “eliminate socially undesirable practices associated with school education” (Kim 2002:36) were already implemented under President Kim Young Sam (1993–1998) in 1995 through the 5.31 Education Reform Proposal and the integration of ICT into the education system (Kim 2002:36–38). Moreover, to ease the competitiveness of the KCSAT, adjustments of admission standards to higher education were attempted in 2008 (Jones 2011:40), but they did not entail substantial changes.
The immense importance of the KCSAT for students’ academic future and career paths is regarded as preventing entrepreneurship, as the “traditional Korean education system has nothing to do with entrepreneurship [and] especially high-school education is mainly for passing the entrance examination for the university” (EP3). The Korean education system is perceived as a severe cognitive hindrance for entrepreneurship, hampering students’ ability to think “outside the box.” Entrepreneur E1 remarks that young Koreans “are used to just getting instructions in classes throughout the whole years of schooling. And they are not really used to questioning or ‘going out of the box.’” Experts stress the importance of education but see a lack of creative and innovative thinking:
I believe that the education really matters in this type of [entrepreneurial] process because as a student, you are not asked to create or think of something from scratch, but rather you learn what’s given. And the exam that you do is multiple choice, so you are good at choosing, but you are not good at making something new. But startup is such a creative business. Sometimes, you need to think something from scratch if you really want to disrupt current businesses. But I think we are not trained to be entrepreneurs yet. (EP13)
The Korean education system has also been criticized for not teaching students problem-solving abilities or the ability to manage risks and mistakes, which the interviewees regard as essential for entrepreneurial action:
Education is the problem. [Students] only focus on the KCSAT exam before graduation, [and] even after entering the university, students don’t acquire problem solving ability. (EP11)
The Korean educational system […] is very efficient in terms of selecting, […] screening people. […] And this system makes people more efficient to take the exam. Not the real, you know, creativity or thought. So Korean private or public education always focuses on the textbook problems. How efficient (sic) we solve the test or how fast. And in other words, the people are afraid of answering the wrong question. […] But in real life […] you have to start again if you fail, but if someone is really afraid of failure and the education systems makes people afraid of making mistakes [...] [being] an entrepreneur is something about making mistakes over and over again until you finally find a solution. (EP2)
In 2018, compulsory coding education was integrated into the official curriculum to accommodate the technology- and innovation-driven economy as well as to enhance logical thinking, creativity, and problem-solving ability (Paek 2018). However, experts like EP6 and EP13 remain skeptical whether students would apply coding as a tool for the creation of an innovative business. Even more detrimental, the introduction of coding as a part of the curriculum already opened a new market for coding hagwŏn, intensifying competition and inequality among students (U 2018). Thus, compulsory coding education might result in students cramming to collect another “spec” for their CV without improving actual productivity,6 let alone the ability to apply it when starting a business.
Overall, the Korean education system is perceived as unfavorable for entrepreneurship, as it fails to transmit the necessary knowledge, skills, and abilities for starting a business.

The emergence of entrepreneurship education

There have been efforts to provide entrepreneurship education in Korea. For instance, the Youth BizCool program for elementary, middle, and high school students, which is run by the Ministry of SMEs and Startups (MSS) every year since 2002 (Platum 2014), is mentioned by experts (EP1, EP12). Through this program, students can learn about entrepreneurship, participate in student startup clubs, and listen to experts’ special lectures. The program aims at cultivating an entrepreneurial spirit among students and spreading the knowledge necessary for starting a business. Teachers in charge also receive training and teaching material. The program has been expanded in recent years: While in 2013, only 135 schools took part nationwide, the number rose to more than 500 schools in 2017. The budget for the program in 2018 was around 7.6 billion KRW (6.54 million USD) (MSS 2018).
Moreover, some private sector organizations recognized the shortcomings of the Korean education system and started providing their own educational content. For instance, the Asan Nanum Foundation provides educational programs for students, teachers, parents, and the general public.7 A representative explains the motivation:
Because if you want to foster entrepreneurship among the students, I think the most important part is educating them about problem-solving ability and creative-thinking ability. But Korean education contents are usually for memorization. Not really suitable. So that’s why our foundation is trying […] we are actually making our own educational content. (EP7)
Thus, there is a bottom-up movement for entrepreneurial education at the school level.
At the tertiary education level, entrepreneurship education has increased in recent years. Already in 2013, the Ministry of Education (MOE) planned to contribute 262 billion KRW (225.32 million USD) to adjust curricula and support innovative models for education (OECD 2014:146). Accordingly, universities were required to use 30% of the funds they received from the MOE for the promotion of startups, jobs, and connections between industry and university, including the development of entrepreneurship education.
Universities like the Yonsei University in Seoul and the Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology (KAIST) in Daejeon have established entrepreneurship education for their students including practical training and first-hand experience programs. For instance, in 2014, the “Startup KAIST” movement began to revive entrepreneurship at KAIST and nationwide.8 “K-School” was founded in 2016 upon the initiative of KAIST members, and the Ministry of Science, ICT, and Future Planning (MSIP) supported the idea to establish a graduate program by providing significant funds. Hence, KAIST established a cross-departmental master’s degree in entrepreneurship and innovation, a minor degree in science-based entrepreneurship, as well as a certificate program open to all KAIST students. Interviewee E16, who took part in the entrepreneurship lectures, reports that the program helped him to see the world through an entrepreneur’s eyes, which is something he would not have learned in conventional engineering classes:
The 3-day lean startup program was also very useful […] because it felt more like a training, not teaching, not learning, but a little different, it wasn’t lecture-based, it was more experience-based. We really learned a lot about presentation and presenting our ideas. (E16)
Although entrepreneurship education at the university level is still not pervasive yet, the initiatives can be regarded as initial changes of the cognitive institutional pillar.

The normative institutional pillar

Desirable career paths in Korea

Many interviewees mention two desirable career paths in Korea: regular employment in large enterprises and in the public sector including professions such as a medical doctor, lawyer, and teacher.
So far, the common types of jobs in Korea are either you go for the big company, or you go for the government. Or if you’re retired, especially after the financial crisis, they are forced to retire. And they have to do their own job which is now called self-employed. (EP 2)
Both jobs in large firms and the public sector are perceived as “good jobs” (Lee and Choi 2006:210), and the following explains why becoming an entrepreneur is not. The main reason for preferring employment in a large enterprise is the financial incentive: “If I’m in Korea, I should go for the large cooperation. First of all, for most Koreans, the reason why they choose the big companies is because they get more money and it’s more comfortable or convenient.” (E16).
Regular employment in a large conglomerate guarantees a relatively high income compared to small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs).9 Figure 2 shows that entrance level average annual salaries in large, public, and foreign enterprises are always higher than salaries in SMEs. Annual salaries in SMEs have also been stagnant between 2014 and 2017. These wage gaps are firstly caused by the distorted business structure in Korea with low productivity of SMEs compared to large enterprises (Ahn 2018: 4 f.) and secondly by the increasing labor market duality that intensified because of the labor market deregulation after the Asian Financial Crisis (AFC) in 1997, subsequent labor policy failures and changes in Korea’s industrial structure (Yun 2009). Therefore, regular workers in SMEs receive lower wages and fewer social benefits than regular workers in large firms, while temporary workers in SMEs are even worse off (Schauer 2018:14).
Employment at large enterprises is desirable but competitive. According to Statistics Korea (2021) Business Demography Statistics from 2016 until 2019, 99.9% of Korean firms are SMEs and employ around 82% of the workforce. Moreover, while SMEs suffer labor shortages, the top 500 largest enterprises planned to hire fewer employees in 2016 compared to 2015 due to sluggish economic conditions and company internal issues (FKI 2016). These dire prospects have been fueling youth unemployment and youth labor market inactivity, as young Koreans are reluctant to work for SMEs and postpone graduation until they find a decent job (Yun 2010).
Wages of government officials are comparably modest, and they are determined by rank and salary level (Lee and Choi 2006:202). For example, according to the civil service payroll of 2017 by the Ministry of Personnel Management, a ninth-rank general government official earns between 1,395,800 KRW (1,200.4 USD) (salary level 1) and 3,017,500 (2,595.05 USD) (salary level 31) per month.10 Nevertheless, public sector jobs are still desirable due to high job security. Interviewee E16 continues:
It’s really funny, but in Korea, if you have a safe job, if you get steady money, then it’s a good job in Korea. Like another good job is, [a] public job, is teacher, because it’s also paid by the government. (E16).
Other advantages of public sector jobs are a higher retirement age in contrast to early retirement schemes in the private sector, moderate working hours, and less competition for promotion. Public sector jobs are especially advantageous for women, as they can stay employed after marriage and childbirth (Pak 2016).
However, it is especially Korea’s elderly, and not their children, who prefer the desirable jobs. This is due to Korea’s history of economic development and the AFC. Entrepreneurs believe that their parents’ occupational preferences were shaped by the catch-up phase of economic development. Since Korea used to be a developing country, a stable income, and job security were considered as the route to economic success because it provided the necessary financial resources to support one’s family:
We’ve been in poverty, […] but the main way to get out of that was to put your head down, study, learn, […] make money, don’t starve. Job security. Not lottery. Job security for your family. That’s what success looked like. One generation above. And even these days that’s what success looks like to a lot of people. (E5)
Indeed, there was a shortage of college graduates starting their own business and an oversupply of salaried managers and engineers, who received a sizable remuneration in the 1960s and 1970s (Amsden 1989:221, 229). Instead of new firm formation, the expansion of existing firms was the driver of Korea’s rapid industrialization (Jones and SaKong 1985:170).
An equally important explanation is the shared experience of the economic shock of 1997. Life-time employment, once a substitute for an underdeveloped welfare state and a sign of corporate paternalism preserving social stability (Kim and Finch 2002:122), ended with the failure of the Chaebol. The following labor market flexibilization was regarded as a violation of Confucian values in Korea (Kim and Finch 2002:134), as mass layoffs and non-regular employment became omnipresent. Entrepreneurs report how their own families were affected by the economic hardship and how it shaped their parents’ wishes for their children’s economic safety.
And that’s because we have experienced [the] IMF [crisis]. We saw a lot of people […] losing their job, [going] bankrupt, not just bankrupt, they just owed a lot of money and committed suicide. And my family also had a really difficult situation, financial difficulties, back in 1998, when I was at second grade in middle school. We had a really tough time. So I understand when my mom is worried about my future when I tell her I just want to start my own startup. I understand. Because she experienced that. (E2)
We had the IMF and, in that era, lots of parents turned their children into ‘chickens.’ They are so scared about losing their job. […] Our generation was the biggest generation that was pushed to get a safe job. (E10)
These stories indicate that the shared experience of poverty and economic shock of Korea’s older generation affects the occupational choices of the young generation to minimize socio-economic risks. Taking financial risks by founding one’s own business leads to parental concerns (E8) or even serious conflicts (E15).

The societal ranking system and occupational choices

The desirable career paths are also associated with a high social status resulting from their competitiveness and exclusiveness. This draws back onto a deep-rooted ranking mindset pervasive in Korea. “Education enthusiasm” (Shin 2012:66) as a characteristic of Confucian tradition and the exam-based filtering system as a social heritage have served to select high ability people for positions in public office since the kwagŏ civil service examination system in the early koryŏ Dynasty (918–1392) (Jung 2014:51). Throughout Korea’s rapid industrialization, the civil service exam-based recruitment system became even more meritocratic, as the bureaucracy was essential for state-led development (Lee and Lee 2014:52, Ko and Jun 2015:197). More importantly, however, exam-based filtering systems have “functioned as a way to improve social status” (Shin 2012:66), i.e., climbing the social ladder and enjoying social prestige through passing competitive exams (Lee and Lee 2014:54). The KCSAT in particular creates a nationwide performance ranking among all test takers, which influences all areas of life including one’s place of residence.11
The perception of gaining social prestige by passing competitive exams persists until today as remarked by, for instance, entrepreneur E10 and expert EP5:
There is a word like ipsinyangmyŏng [i.e., rising in the world and gaining fame (author’s note)]. […] This is about […] getting success and going into the government. Means success before Chosŏn dynasty [1392 – 1910 (author’s note)], that concept of success still remains, I think. So, they want to go to the government and [become] a lawyer. Of course, it’s just prestigious and well paid. (E10)
So they [i.e., Korean parents (author’s note)] realized that in order to get into those good schools and Samsung, the score really matters. So that’s why they are pushing them [i.e., their children (author’s note)] to get a good score and entering the good elite school, and after that, just go to the well-known company like the Samsung or become a high-ranked official in the government. And most people strongly believe that that’s the way to having a great life. (EP5)
Thus, Korean society is highly aware of the connections between the education system, the exam-based filtering system, as well as social status, and the societal pressure to conform to these institutional elements is high.
The occupation “entrepreneur” is not compatible with the societal ranking system. Expert EP5 continues: “So becoming an entrepreneur, joining a startup is actually not following that kind of elite path.” On the contrary, starting one’s own business is often interpreted as a sign of underachievement. Eventually, lacking alternatives pushes people to start their own business as already noted by EP2 in the “Desirable career paths in Korea” section.
However, with the current startup trend, expert EP2 and entrepreneur E4 find that the reality of entrepreneurship is increasingly perceived as more nuanced:
But now the young people and young generation realize entrepreneurs are very different from those self-employed moms and pops. It’s more like a structured and more advanced type of doing your own business, which means you have to leverage technology and the money, I mean capital. And also, they are very professional people, right? (EP2)
Korean society? Well… they are still arguing about it. Some people say startups are good, and some say startups are just second or third option when people fail to get a job in big companies. (E4)
Hence, a slight change of perception was observed during the field research.

Social stigma against business failure

Business failure is another issue that stood out during interviews because Korean entrepreneurs usually rely on debt financing, which underlies the so-called joint guarantee system (see more in the “The regulative institutional pillar” section). It means that despite the corporation’s legal identity as the principal borrower, entrepreneurs are the guarantor for their incorporated business and are liable in the case of insolvency.12 In addition, a co-guarantor, often a family member or a friend, is a prerequisite for a bank loan (OECD 2014:143). If a corporation defaults, both guarantor and co-guarantor are held liable to settle obligations. This joint guarantee system creates a social stigma against business failure according to interviewees:
But how to face and how to leverage the failure experience is critical, but in Korea, we have the fear of failure, we can see this issue from two perspectives. First one is financial, and second one is social. […] Social stigma, I also think this is related to the financial breakdown. You go down in your life, so people say ‘See, he is financially broke, he’s not gonna do things, he’s just such a failure.’ He gets a stigma of failure. (EP13)
If a company is insolvent, the owner loses everything. Not just financially but also socially, there is a bad connotation […]. That person is then regarded as a failed human being. (EP14)
The risk of business failure therefore has two dimensions, a financial and a social dimension, which together creates a social stigma against business failure.
Overall, entrepreneurship in Korea is not perceived as a desirable occupation due to its financial uncertainty, a low social status, and a social stigma against business failure.

The regulative institutional pillar

The joint guarantee system

To understand the social stigma against business failure, it is essential to comprehend the joint guarantee system. Throughout Korea’s economic development, its financial system has relied on the banking sector to provide financing for development projects rather than the securities market (Jin et al. 2004, cited in Kwon 2010:252). As credit score-based lending practices were underdeveloped, businesses could secure their loans via collateral. However, loans without collateral were restricted through the amendments in the Banking Act from 1962 and 1969 (Cha and Kim 2010:193). The credit guarantee system was established in 1961, and in 1976, the Korea Credit Guarantee Fund (KODIT) was implemented, followed by the Korea Technology Finance Cooperation (KOTEC) in 1989. Their purpose was to provide preferential credit guarantees to businesses without security solvency.
Nowadays, KODIT provides a guarantee service for promising startups, export businesses, and green growth businesses. KOTEC supplies technology guarantees for startups younger than five years old, for venture and innovative businesses, and other businesses with excellent technology according to KOTEC’s technology appraisal system. KOTEC and KODIT step in as a guarantor and issue a letter of guarantee to the potential creditor. If the business defaults, KOTEC or KODIT pay back the loan to the creditor, and the guarantor is indebted to KOTEC or KODIT. However, guarantees for credits are issued without the requirement of material collateral. Therefore, the joint guarantee system, determined by Art. 437 of the Korean Civil Act and Art. 57 of the Commercial Act,13,14 prevents moral hazard arising from information asymmetry.
And the traditional way of Korean startups financing their business is through joint guarantee. To finance your company, when you borrow money, the borrower should be the company, not you. But because you are related to the company’s destiny, if the company collapses, the duty of repaying is automatically transferred to the CEO. So, you become liable for that. It’s a unique institution, unique system in Korea. (EP13)
The problem of the joint guarantee system as a major obstacle for Koreans to start their own business has been addressed by the Korean government as mentioned by, for example, EP11 and E11:
Every bank has been practicing this [joint guarantee system], personal liability for the founder, they have to succeed, otherwise, they will get in trouble. But even a good entrepreneur can fail. The government pushed to not use the joint guarantee system anymore. (EP11)
As far as I know, in the past one or two years, even if you don’t have money, the opportunities to start a business increased and there are now many companies that invest in early stage. Therefore, those things [i.e., hardship through business failure caused by the joint guarantee system (author’s note)] have become less. The case of joint guarantee system that I mentioned before, it has changed recently, like one or two years ago. (E11)
Over time, both KODIT and KOTEC adjusted the joint guarantee system as it was regarded to be a major obstacle for business foundations. Table 9 in the appendix lists the major reform steps of the joint guarantee system between 2005 and 2016. Until 2010, the reforms eased the joint guarantee requirements for venture businesses and businesses in strategic industries, but in 2011, the scope of exemptions from the joint guarantee system expanded to startups. From 2012 onwards, distinctions were made between individual and corporate businesses. These steps de facto abolished the joint guarantee system for individual businesses and reduced the joint liability for corporations significantly. From 2014 onwards, more focus was put on the exemption of businesses including startups with excellent technology to encourage new business foundations and mitigate the fear of failure.
Eventually, the Financial Service Commission (FSC), a government regulatory authority, announced the complete abolishment of the joint guarantee system for startups younger than five years with a plan to increase the exemptions for startups from 1,400 to up to 40,000 cases (FSC 2015). This reform was implemented in January 2016 and led to an increase of new guarantees issued by KOTEC exempted from the joint guarantee from 332.2 billion KRW (285.7 million USD) in 2015 to 962.5 billion KRW (827.7 million USD) in 2017 (+ 289.7%) and 3,773 beneficiary companies in 2017 compared to 521 in 2015 (+ 724.2%) (KOTEC 2017:40). In the case of KODIT guarantees, the exemptions among startups increased from 319 in 2015 to 4,112 in 2017 and from 25 billion KRW (21.5 million USD) in 2015 to 988.3 billion KRW (849.9 million USD) in 2017 (KODIT 2017:26).
With the continuing loosening of the joint guarantee system, the fundamental property of KOTEC, which mainly consists of contributions from the government and financial companies,15 decreased almost continuously from 28.2 trillion KRW (24.2 billion USD) in 2011 to 19.7 trillion KRW (16.9 billion USD) in 2017. This means that the risks of default have been shifted from entrepreneurs to taxpayers, as government contributions are understood as public goods sourced from the fiscal budget.
Although the joint guarantee system still exists, the related risks of business failure resulting for entrepreneurs have been reduced, which helps explain the recent emergence of young entrepreneurs.

Administrative and industry-specific regulations

When asked about the administrative procedures of setting up a corporation, entrepreneurs did not report any difficulties:
I think founding your own company or a company is very easy, with the regulations […]. We just went to an attorney and asked that attorney to set it up, set the corporation, like Ltd., up. And then he did it, and then we started. We started researching and developing the machine. That’s all. (E1)
This can be attributed to the fact that first, the minimum amount of capital required to establish a stock corporation in Korea is 0 KRW since amendments of the Commercial Act in 2009.Second, according to the 2018 World Bank “Doing Business” report, the procedures to register a company in Korea consist of two steps, namely (1) making a company seal and (2) registering the company with Start-Biz and paying incorporation fees, which takes four days in total and can be done online (WBG 2018). Therefore, in international comparison, Korea ranks ninth in the “Starting a Business” category.
As is the case in other countries, there are industry—and product-specific regulations, for instance—in the pharmaceutical, the medical, and the financial industry, to guarantee product and customer safety standards. Expert EP6 explains:
You know, in China, they adapt the negative regulations. Korea is still a positive regulation system. You know that Uber is illegal in Korea. AirBnB business model is illegal in Korea, because of the regulations. I’m not saying that we have to adapt to everything, but how can we have such innovative companies in Korea […] imagine that they would have started from Korea, they are already illegal. […] So many innovative businesses are illegal in Korea, why? It’s because the regulations cannot keep up with the innovations, that’s it. (EP6)
However, the government under President Moon has recently pushed forward so-called regulatory sandboxes to ease the actualization of innovations in leading industries (Kim and Choi 2019:19–21).

The government’s role in promoting entrepreneurship

Throughout Korea’s economic development, the government has played a central role in promoting selected industries and businesses. However, the belief that technology-driven startups are more flexible, creative, and innovative than conglomerates in old industries became prevalent, especially under President Park Geun-hye (2013–2017). Moreover, startups were also considered as a solution for the increasing youth unemployment (Kim 2014:2). Therefore, President Park’s Creative Economy heavily supported young entrepreneurs. In June 2013, the Action Plan for the Creative Economy was announced including strategies for the “creation of the ecosystem in which creativity is rewarded fairly and it is easy to start a new company” and to “strengthen the competitiveness of the venture and small [and] medium sized company as a key player” (Cha 2015:38). Many interviewees report about the effect of the Creative Economy:
It’s been crazy […]. Ever since the Creative Economy initiative, a lot of the Korean startups you see around you right now, at this hour, you owe it […] to the government initiative. [...] So the Korean entrepreneurship scene is really growing (sic) in the past two to three years because of the government’s role. (E5)
This startup boom is kind of created, artificially created by this current government, because this government started about less than five years ago, and it’s one of their major agenda (sic) to boost startup activities. I think that’s good. They picked the right topic, and growing new startups is very important, very necessary for the Korean economy. (EP3)
This increasing focus on startups found financial expression in the growing budget of the Small and Medium Business Administration (SMBA) and the MSIP (Fig. 3). The budget for the SMBA increased from 6.15 trillion KRW (5.29 billion USD) in 2012 to 8.19 trillion KRW (7.04 billion USD) in 2017. The MSIP’s budget also increased from 13.65 trillion KRW (11.74 billion USD) in 2014 to 14.5 trillion KRW (12.47 billion USD) in 2016. In 2017, the budget was slightly reduced. Together, the budget of the SMBA and the MSIP accounted for almost 6% of the total central government’s budget in 2015 and 2016. After President Moon had taken over the Blue House in 2017, the MSIP was dissolved and the SMBA was upgraded to the MSS. The budget of the MSS exceeded 10 trillion KRW in 2019 (8.6 billion USD), signaling a continued promotion of entrepreneurship.
Table 1 lists the major budget plans to foster startups and entrepreneurs under the Creative Economy initiative from 2014 to 2016, which includes increased startup funding like the tech incubating program for startups (TIPS) and expansion of support programs, including university education programs. Infrastructure measures, such as the expansion of the incubator-like Centers for Creative Economy and Innovation and the development of Pangyo Techno Valley, a technology hub in Gyeonggi Province, were supposed to create regional entrepreneurship ecosystems in support of startup activities.
Table 1
Budget plans for fostering young entrepreneurs, startups, 2014–2016
2014
- increase number of universities providing startup education programs (18 \(\to\) 23)
- expansion of major projects, including Creative Economy-related funding (6.5 trillion KRW \(\to\) 6.55 trillion KRW), which comprises funding for “Offline Creative Economy Towns” (2.3 billion KRW \(\to\) 4.0 billion KRW, 1 \(\to\) 3 locations), “Endless Imagination Rooms” (1 billion KRW \(\to\) 2 billion KRW, 20 \(\to\) 40 locations), etc
2015
- increase the Creative Economy support (7.1 trillion KRW \(\to\) 8.3 trillion KRW)
- develop a high-tech community in Pangyo (district in Seongnam, Gyeonggi Province)
- increase number of Centers for Creative Economy and Innovation (CCEI)
2016
Under Increasing Youth Employment Initiative
- increase number of universities that receive support for their leading startup programs (28 \(\to\) 34)
- merge similar programs of CCEIs and discontinue inefficient ones
Under Developing Growth Potential Initiative
- promote establishing ventures and startups by utilizing Creative Economy Innovation Centers
- develop Second Pangyo Creative Valley
- increase investment in TIPS (36.5 billion KRW \(\to\) 42.5 billion KRW)
This list only includes major budget plans related to startups and entrepreneurship
Source: MOEF (2013), MOEF (2014), MOEF (2015) Budget Proposal
Despite the positive impact of government support, some interviewees described the government’s efforts as too generous and therefore prone to moral hazard, creating wrong incentives for individuals who are not apt to run a business. The above-quoted expert EP3 continues: “[…] but I don’t think their approach is correct. […] I don’t think [TIPS (author’s note)] is a very healthy program because it’s too generous.” (EP3).
The abundant government support for initial financing is said to induce students to start a business for the purpose of obtaining another “spec” and eventually getting hired by a large enterprise: “Actually, some youngsters use that as a career. […] They are not interested in startup companies, not interested in their own company. They just did it so that they can make one line in their CV, resume.” (EP6).
Furthermore, the government has played an active role in developing Korea’s venture capital industry ever since it was initiated in the 1980s (Kenney et al. 2002:75–77). In fact, the immaturity of the Korean VC industry justifies a continued intervention of the Korean government until the present day, which in turn results in a misallocation of investment towards less risky and more mature businesses (Jones 2015:57) and a high dependency of the Korean VC market on the Korean central government.16 Policy financial institutions contributed up to one-third to new fund formation in the VC industry between 2006 and 2016 (KVCA 2016:4).17 Supported by the government, the VC market has grown in recent years: the number of VC companies jumped from 103 firms in 2014 to 115 firms in 2015,18 the amount of new investments steadily increased since 2008, and the number of companies that received VC investment almost doubled between 2006 and 2016, standing at 1,399 in 2018 (see Table 2).
Table 2
New VC investment and number of companies invested, 2006–2018
 
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
New investment
7,333
7,247
10,910
12,333
16,393
21,503
34,249
No. of companies
617
496
560
688
901
1,191
1,399
Unit of new investment: 100 million KRW
Source: Based on KVCA (2016: 5), KVCA (2019)
Experts see the growth of the VC industry as a positive development, but they also regard the government’s role in the VC industry and investment guidelines as a reason for the conservative investment behavior of venture capitalists. Therefore, some recommend an end of government investment activities:
Korea’s VC industry is not mature, so the government needs to drive the VC market. But Korea needs to change in that regard. If the government. doesn’t give money, some VC will close, so the startups cannot get money, that is the problem. But even if some VCs vanish (sic), the good ones would survive. The government should give more money to good VCs instead. 10 years ago, the government needed to drive the VC industry, but not anymore. (EP11)

Conclusion

Drawing on the institutional economic approach by North (1990) and Scott (2014), this article investigated the institutional environment for entrepreneurship in Korea and the latest changes thereof to explain the recent rise in entrepreneurial activities.
Figure 4 plots the major institutional changes against the development of entrepreneurial activities between 2000 and 2019. While there are ambiguous forces with respect to the cognitive and normative institutions in the 2010s, the changes in the regulative dimension are pronounced and therefore can be considered the main drivers of the increase in newly registered corporations.
This study’s results suggest that in comparison to Gupta et al. (2014), regulative institutions have improved since 2009. There are some initial changes in the cognitive and normative dimensions, but they do not seem to be the key drivers of entrepreneurial activities in Korea. This means that despite the obvious asymmetry between the institutional dimensions, newly established corporations have increased. Therefore, the results of this study support the findings in Stenholm et al. (2013) according to which regulative institutions are the main drivers of newly registered corporations. This contrasts with results by Bosma et al. (2018), who find that a small size of the government increases opportunity-driven entrepreneurship, and Valdez and Richardson (2013), who find the cultural-cognitive and normative institutions to be most decisive. It leads to the hypothesis that the different institutional dimensions are not of equal importance for entrepreneurial activities because regulative institutions set stronger incentives for occupational decisions and overrule hindering normative as well as cognitive institutions. Nevertheless, supportive normative and cognitive institutions might still be necessary to legitimize the encouraging regulative institutions in the long term and improve entrepreneurial quality. Additionally, this study also supports the theoretical argument that informal institutions change only after formal institutions.
Policymakers of the Moon administration have already worked on remaining regulative obstacles, e.g., by installing regulatory sandboxes. However, the government must also take possible moral hazards seriously. It is more difficult to give practical advice on the cognitive and normative institutions. Persisting occupational norms will undermine efforts to promote entrepreneurship education. To change the societal sentiment and appreciation for entrepreneurship, creative approaches are necessary, such as spreading a positive image about entrepreneurship via media and content industries.
There are limitations to this research. First, the qualitative single-country approach limits the generalizability of results and statistical inference on causality between institutions and entrepreneurship. Second, methodological issues like the sample selection and mixed language might have caused biases and should be treated with more care in the future.
Despite these flaws, this article provides a qualitative analysis that contributes to the understanding of institutions for entrepreneurship in the Korean context. Future research not only needs to pay attention to the effect of institutions on the quantity but also on the quality of newly established corporations.

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank the editor of the Journal of International Entrepreneurship for seeing potential in my manuscript and allowing me to publish it, and two anonymous reviewers, especially reviewer #2, for their detailed and constructive feedback on my manuscript. They greatly contributed to improving this article.
Open AccessThis article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​.

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Anhänge

Appendix

Tables 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9
Table 3
Overview of literature on relationship between institutions and entrepreneurship (selection)
Author
Objective
Method
Sample
Dependent Variable
Independent variable
Key insights
Aidis et al. (2009)
Examine relationship between individual decision to become an entrepreneur and institutional context
Factor analysis prior to regression
1995–2008, 44 countries
All startups regardless of the legal form
Institutional indicators from Heritage Foundation/Wall Street Journal, through factor analysis reduced to two factors (“rule of law” and “limited state sector”)
Rule of law and limits to the state sector enhance entrepreneurial activity. Impact of rule of law less significant at higher levels of development
Aparicio et al. (2016)
Examine effect of formal and informal institutions on OTEA and subsequent impact on economic growth
Three-stage least-square (3SLS) model with unbalanced panel data
2004–2012, 43 countries, 253 observations
OTEA from GEM
Number of startup procedures and obtaining credit from World Bank Doing Business, confidence in skills from GEM, control of corruption from Worldwide Government Indicators, World Bank
Control of corruption, confidence in skills, and private coverage to obtain credit has positive, number of procedures a negative influence. Positive relationship between OTEA and economic growth
Bosma et al. (2018)
Examine relation between institutional characteristics, types of entrepreneurial activity, and economic growth
Parsimonious growth model
in a 3SLS specification,
two-step procedure
2003–2014, 25 European countries
TEA, OTEA, growth-oriented TEA, and entrepreneurial employee activity from GEM
Regulative: size of government, regulation of credit, labor and business freedom, and financial stability from economic freedom of the world index, Fraser Institute
Cognitive: skill from GEM
Normative: fear of failure, entrepreneurship as a career choice from GEM
Smaller size of government increases TEA and OTEA. Growth-oriented TEA positively associated with financial stability. Skill correlates strongly with TEA, career choice has positive influence on TEA and OTEA
Chowdhury et al. (2015)
Examine impact of institutions on
entrepreneurship
Pooled time-series, cross-sectional research design
2001–2005, 44 countries
Nascent/new firm ownership TEA from GEM; New firm startup entry rate
Property rights protection, freedom from corruption from Heritage Foundation’s Index of Economic Freedom (IEF) and corruption perception index (CPI), tax rates, FDI flows from World Bank, startup procedures from Doing Business, human capital from World Bank Development Indicator
Property rights: Positive on new firm startups and new firm ownership. Freedom of corruption: Positive on new firm ownership. Tax rate: negative on new firm startup. FDI flows: negative on new firm ownership. Startup procedure: negative on new firm startup, positive on new firm ownership. Human capital: negative on new firm ownership
Fuentelsaz et al. (2015)
Analyze and compare influence of formal institutions on different types of entrepreneurship, including OTEA
Regression with fixed- and random effects
2005–2012; 63 countries, 189 observations
OTEA from GEM
Property rights, business freedom, fiscal freedom, labor freedom, financial capital from Heritage Foundation IEF. Educational capital from World Bank
Property rights, business freedom, labor freedom, financial capital, and educational capital have a positive, fiscal freedom a negative influence on OTEA
Khalilov and Yi (2021)
Empirically examine causal associations of institutions and entrepreneurship
Structural Equation Modelling
2014–2016, 19 OECD countries
GEM
Regulative (economic freedom) and normative institutions (entrepreneurial value from GEM)
Normative institutions not a significant driver of entrepreneurship. Regulative institutions drive entrepreneurial activities
Krasniqi and Desai (2016)
Examine institutional conditions shaping cross-national differences for high-growth firms in transition economies
Generalized Least Square (GLS) regression
1998–2009, 26 transition countries, 78 observations
High-growth firms, measured as the percentage share of fast-growing firms from World Bank
Formal: tax administration, trade and customs regulations, tax rate, business licensing/permits. Informal: functioning of judiciary/ courts, anti-competitive practices of competitors, policy uncertainty, corruption
From Business Environment and Enterprise Performance Survey dataset from World Bank/ European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
Interaction between formal and informal institutions positively influences high-growth firms. Implies that social norms could help to accommodate adverse effects of formal institutions and regulatory burden
McMullen et al. (2008)
Examine relationship between economic freedom and OTEA
Regression analysis
2002/2003, 37 countries
OTEA from GEM
Trade, fiscal, freedom from government, monetary, investment, financial, labor freedom, property rights, business freedom, and freedom from corruption from Heritage Foundation/ Wall Street Journal IEF
Significant positive influence of property rights and labor freedom on OTEA
Sambharya and Musteen (2014)
Examine influence of institutional environment on OTEA
GLS regression
2000–2005, 43 countries
OTEA from GEM
Regulative: regulatory quality from World Governance Indicators index
published by World Bank
Cognitive: uncertainty avoidance, institutional collectivism, power distance from GLOBE
Normative: market openness from IEF, Heritage Foundation
Cognitive dimensions of institutional environment are strong predictors of the OTEA
Stenholm et al. (2013)
Examine influence of institutions on rate and type of entrepreneurial activity
Structural equation modeling with maximum likelihood estimation
2007–2009, 63 countries
Entry rate: Newly registered limited liability companies per 1.000 working-age people from World Bank Group’s Entrepreneurship Survey’s entry density
Regulative: business freedom from IEF, ease of starting, ease of closing from Doing Business, property rights (IEF). Cognitive: opportunity perception, knows an entrepreneur, skills. Normative: high status, media attention, all from GEM. Conducive: entrepreneurial ecosystem
Business freedom and ease of new business formation positively influence the rate of entrepreneurial activity. Cognitive and normative institutions have no significant impact. Conducive dimension significant for type of entrepreneurial activity
Urbano and Alvarez (2014)
Examine influence of institutions on probability of becoming an entrepreneur
Binominal logistic regression
2008, 30 countries, 36,525 individuals
TEA from GEM
Regulative: business legislation, procedures and venture capital from International Institute for Management Development, World Competitiveness Yearbook. Cognitive: skills, fear of failure and knowing entrepreneurs from GEM. Normative: career choice, high status and media attention from GEM
Fewer procedures to start a business, higher media attention and better entrepreneurial skills, less fear of business failure, and better knowing of entrepreneurs increase the probability of becoming an entrepreneur
Urbano et al. (2020)
Examine interrelationships among institutional environment, entrepreneurial activity, and economic growth
GLS regression
2004–2012, 14 developing countries, 78 observations
OTEA from GEM
Number of procedures to start a new business and credit coverage from Doing Business; Human Development Context from the United Nations Development Program; Access to communication from National Experts Survey
Number of procedures to start a new business, private credit coverage, and access to communication significantly explain OTEA
Valdez and Richardson (2013)
Examine influence of institutional environment on entrepreneurial activity
Multiple regression
2005–2007, 52 countries
OTEA from GEM
Regulative: economic freedom from Heritage Foundation/Wall Street Journal IEF. Cultural-cognitive: perceived knowledge, skill, and experience required to start a new business and fear of failure from GEM. Normative: cultural support index created from GEM
Cultural-cognitive and normative institutions have positive influence on OTEA
OTEA: opportunity-motivated Total early-stage Entrepreneurial Activity (TEA)
Table 4
List of interviewed experts
No
Legal title/role
Date
Interview length
Location of interview
Organization
EP1
Staff member
16.11.2016
Written Form, Korean
Seoul, Seodaemun-gu
University Support Center for Entrepreneurship
EP2
CEO and Founder
29.11.2016
1h08m31s
Seoul, Gangnam-gu
Private business
EP3
Professor
07.12.2016
1h18m10s
Daejeon, Yuseong-gu
Public institute
EP4
Visiting professor
08.12.2016
1h18m42s
Daejeon, Yuseong-gu
Public institute
EP5
Managing director
31.01.2017
1h03m03s
Seoul, Gangnam-gu
Private organization
EP6
PR director
16.02.2017
2h03m51s, plus 15 m Guided Tour
Seongnam, Pangyo (Gyeonggi Province)
Public organization
EP7
Manager
27.02.2017
29m54s, plus 30 m Guided Tour
Seoul, Gangnam-gu
Private foundation
EP8
Professor
27.02.2017
Written Form
Seoul, Gwanak-gu
Public university
EP9
Professor
02.03.2017
About 50 m, Notes
Seoul, Gwanak-gu
Public university
EP10
Policy researcher
08.03.2017
Written Form, Korean
Seoul, Dongjak-gu
Public institute/ministry
EP11
Associate
23.03.2017
About 1 h, Notes
Seoul, Gangnam-gu
Private venture business
EP12
Staff member
27.03.2017
Written Form, Korean
Daejeon, Seo-gu
Public institute
EP13
Researcher
30.03.2017
1h02m03s
Seoul, Gangnam-gu
Private, non-profit organization
EP14
Professor
31.03.2017
About 1 h, Notes
Seoul, Seodaemun-gu
Private university
Table 5
List of interviewed entrepreneurs
No
Legal title/role
Date
Interview length
Location of interview
Legal form of business
Age
Gender
Industry/product
Age of business
No. of employees
E1
Representative Director, Co-founder
08.11.2016
52m17s
Daejeon, Yuseong-gu
Joint Stock Company
37
Female
Machinery
2 years
2 Founders
E2
Not Employed, Nascent Founder
14.11.2016
1h08m31s
Seoul, Seongdong-gu
-
32
Male
IT-service
-
0
E3
Representative Director, Founder
15.11.2016
57m14s
Seoul, Seongdong-gu
Joint Stock Company
43
Female
IT-service (SNS)
4 years
4
E4
Employee, Nascent Founder
17.11.2016
About 1 h, Notes
Seongnam, Pangyo (Gyeonggi Province)
-
35
Male
IT-service (Platform Business)
-
0
E5
Co-founder, US Operations Director, Student
19.11.2016
1h07m55s
Seoul, Gangnam-gu
Joint Stock Company
24
Male
Private Sector Education
6 months
2 Co-founders, Several Employees
E6
Owner/Founder, Representative
02.12.2016
57m27s, Korean
Seoul, Gangnam-gu
Individual Business
37
Female
Retail
10 months
2
E7
Co-representative, Co-founder
15.12.2016
1h00m01s
Seoul, Gangnam-gu
Joint Stock Company
32
Female
Fintech Service
1 year
10 according to Webpage
E8
Representative Director, Founder
21.12.2016
1h05m32s, Korean
Seoul, Gangnam-gu
Joint Stock Company
34
Male
Business Consulting
5 years
2 Partners
E9
Student, Nascent Founder
15.01.2016
49m10s, Korean
Seoul, Dongjak-gu
-
25
Male
Import/Export
-
0
E10
Representative, Co-founder, Student
03.03.2017
1h22m39s
Seoul, Seongbuk-gu
Joint Stock Company
25
Male
Financial Service
1 year
2
E11
Chief Operating Officer, Co-founder
03.03.2017
46m04s, Korean
Seoul, Gangnam-gu
Joint Stock Company
30
Male
IT-service (HR Management Service)
2.5 years
24
E12
Representative Director, Co-founder
10.03.2017
1h03m44s
Seoul, Gangnam-gu
Joint Stock Company
30
Male
Software for Drones
2 years
8
E13
Representative Director, Co-founder
15.03.2017
51m05s
Seoul, Gangnam-gu
Joint Stock Company
35
Male
IT-service (Music Industry)
2 years
3
E14
Representative Director, Co-founder
21.03.2017
1h13m09s
Seoul, Jongno-gu
Joint Stock Company
33
Male
Wearable Device
1.5 years
8
E15
Chief Technical Officer, Co-founder
21.03.2017
46m26s
Seoul, Jongno-gu
Joint Stock Company
34
Male
Wearable Device
1.5 years
8
E16
Student, former Nascent Founder
24.03.2017
57m03s
Daejeon, Yuseong-gu
-
27
Male
Renewable Energy
-
2 Co-founders
E17
Representative Director, Co-founder
03.04.2017
1h18m13s, Korean
Suwon (Gyeonggi Province)
Limited Liability Company
30
Male
Business Consulting
1 year
6 Freelancers
Table 6
Selected answers by interviewees—cognitive institutional dimension
No
Answer
Korea’s public and private sector education system
E1
I think young Koreans want something stable, something secure. [Interviewer: Why do you think that?] Because that’s how our educational system teaches them
E4
Koreans are trapped in a cage, they don’t learn to think outside the box, but they have to memorize a lot. So there are many smart people, but they are not brilliant enough and they are all too similar. […] In the US [I] didn’t need to memorize things, [I] just had to use my brain and think to find the solution/answer. That’s something the Korean education system is lacking
E5
You gotta learn the right tools, how to make your product fit the market, you know, how to just have that founder mindset, all those things. Korean education is not so [good] in terms of producing founders and people who are going out there starting a business. […] And policy, just system wise, there are no business classes at all, there is no job training, you just read books and you know, it’s like, on these traditional subjects. That’s not very entrepreneurial
The Emergence of Entrepreneurship Education
E16
First, the professor’s courses were very helpful in a way that…as an engineer, as a student, although you see problems, you don’t see them as a business. You don’t think that you can solve this by doing a business. But if you take this course, I think basically you get an entrepreneur’s goggles, glasses, and during the study time, or even later when you get the job, when you are assigned to a project, you can always relate to a business
EP3
And until very recently, actually, you know, last year I started the first entrepreneurship course here, and [before that] there was no course […] teaching entrepreneurship. I was really surprised, so it’s a very recent thing
EP6
We brag about the coding education. “You see my son started coding education. He’s just 4 years old” So what? He learns coding, he learns how to make a program, then what else do you teach him?
EP13
Korean students, they are friendly towards IT devices, but it’s not true that all Koreans learn coding. It’s a recent education trend that the government is executing. But IT is just a tool. What we learned in school is that it’s just a tool…so we…even though we have tools, we don’t know how to use these tools
Source: Transcriptions of interviews conducted by the author. Spelling errors corrected for readability. Translations of interviews conducted in Korean language by the author
Table 7
Selected answers by interviewees—normative institutional dimension
No
Answer
Desirable career paths in Korea
E2
Public officer is a well-known job where you don’t have to take any risk. So you can have a really stable income source, even though it’s not a lot. Especially Korean old people tend to like that and push their children a lot. […]
E5
So many parents here are against their kids going down this risky and failure prone track. And that’s a part of their education at home. You know. You don’t need me to say it, but it’s like, “Go get a stable professional job with a license that you can take like a bar exam, and you have it for life, and you can always have it”. That’s what they prefer
E8
They worried at first [when I decided to start my own business (author’s note)]. My parents. [Interviewer: Why?] Because it is a collective thinking of Korean traditional parents to think about the aspects of financial income and job security
E10
And government, they don’t really pay a lot, but they will never get fired. They have pension, and still, we have a lot of cultural, Asian cultural thing that working for the government is something like ancient
China or Korea, they have those tests, right?
E15
Actually, there was a really big fight [when I wanted to start my first business (author’s note)]. Because my parents really wanted me to live a normal life, normal job and normal marriage. They really wanted a grandson. A peaceful family
E16
I think it’s because Korea developed really fast, like in my parents’ generation, they were really really poor. And because they experienced the poverty, they want their children to have a secure job. I think that’s why for most Korean, job safety is Nr. 1 value. And next comes the amount of income
The societal ranking system and occupational choices
E4
In my opinion, they [my friends (author’s note)] have no idea [about entrepreneurship (author’s note)]. Most of them have no idea even what startups are. Some of my young friends know what I am doing. They think it’s great, but only few people want to work with me
EP5
The people, the parents and everybody sees it as kind of desirable to become doctor. And also get a job at a well-known company like Samsung or become a government servant, official. So becoming an entrepreneur is not such a popular choice here. And people seize that it’s really, really difficult to become successful. Maybe that’s why
Social stigma against business failure
E9
In Korea, there are many such examples, we use the following word: impossibility to make a comeback. […] It is the state where it is impossible to survive, you live, but it’s not much different from dying, these examples are there, this image is there and people’s thinking. This is really big. Bigger than you would think. In the case of my friend’s father whose business failed, they had to constantly move since he was young. It’s not only difficult for yourself, but your whole family suffers. Those examples are numerous. And it’s not your individual mistake but a problem of the system. It’s not that you did something bad and spread the money, it’s legal and you challenged something, and it’s one failure. But it doesn’t last one year but 10, 20, 30 years, perhaps until you die. Living like that because of a one-time failure, there are many people like that in my surrounding
EP2
It’s my personal responsibility to let them know what will happen to them [(i.e., failed founders (author’s note)]. Because actually, they don’t really know. Although the damage maybe will be slightly less than before, but [it is] still the same. If you fail you have a huge financial debt and also your career is gone, and your family will be in big trauma. That’s why sometimes I hesitate to tell them the truth. Because they are who start right here. They believe they don’t really fail, right?
EP5
And it’s kind of true that if you have a failure as an entrepreneur, it’s not that easy to recover from [it]. […] And people are kind of afraid that if you fail once, you’re not able to recover from it. Your social status will stay at that level, as a loser. A failure
EP14
Failed entrepreneurs are discarded by their own family because of the high debt burden. In fact, all private property is taken by creditors as the owner must take all responsibility. And this is regardless of the business code [commercial law (author’s note)]. It is a credit allocation practice because credit-based loan is not very popular, but instead, collateral-based loan is common. So in the case of failure, all collateral will go to the creditor
Source: Transcriptions of interviews conducted by the author. Spelling errors corrected for readability. Translations of interviews conducted in Korean language by the author
Table 8
Selected answers by interviewees—regulative institutional dimension
No
Answer
The joint guarantee system as an institutional obstacle for entrepreneurship
EP13
So, if it’s investment, and if the duty is not transferred to you, but separated to the investor, then you would not fear failure. […] You would not be bankrupt or kicked out of the society financially. You can still exist, and you still can survive from the failure. […]
Administrative and industry-specific regulations
E3
Well, in terms of IT industry [there are no regulative obstacles in starting a business (author’s note)], but in terms of pharmaceutical or biotechnology science, that would be different
EP13
And secondly, deregulation, they are trying to reduce the grey area that startups are facing when making new businesses
EP3
So for young people in Korea during these 3 or 4 years, it was relatively easy to start their own business, regardless of whether their idea is good or not. […]
EP12
Regulations were resolved and the government’s policy also became more focused on the leap in growth of early stage (young) startup businesses. However, it is still insufficient. For example, the service of drones is still difficult
The government’s role in promoting entrepreneurship
E12
[Nowadays (author’s note)] there are so many news, there are startup people everywhere, it’s something touchable, something catchable. The government is actually making that kind of atmosphere in the baseline, directly or indirectly. The government plan for supporting the startup is a very strict criterion of how people value the startup. Like in a lot of ways, I don’t really agree with how the government is supporting startups, I think there are much better ways out there, but anyway, they have their way. And because the government has a way and they have a lot of funding, funds, so the Korean startup ecosystem is kind of following the government
E14
The government’s role was very big in Korea. Actually, when I was a graduate school student, in 2012, I went to the US just to look around. And I can see many startups there. And then after I get back to Korea, at that time, there are not many startups in Korea. But after 2 years, many startups were growing in the US, and Korean government was also trying to make a startup economy. They think we need the startup economy. So they push this part. And invest money to the startup area. Government’s role was very big for Korean startups
EP3
There are many programs, which support, you know, early-stage startups. So, for example one program called TIPS. I think a lot of government people and private people think this is a very successful program. [But] I don’t think it’s a very healthy program because it’s too generous
EP12
From each government department of the SMBA and MSIP there is plenty of various support. Apart from the professional startup institutes, there is steady and increasing support and events for startups
EP13
Our government, they also realized that to boost Korean economic growth, so they made from regulative perspective, from government policy perspective, they made lots and lots of startup sponsorship programs. It’s massive, it’s really massive, there are a lot of programs that startups can apply and the support you can get is immense. Actually, Korea’s startup boom currently, the recent startup boom is actually made by the government. So the number of startups has increased a lot and many are financed by the government’s money. So, the main policy change is that they made lots of startup sponsorship programs
Actually, most of the [Venture Capital] money, most of the fund, it’s coming from the government side. So…still it’s conservative. […] It’s not tax money. What I mean by government money is, like, pensions. Like institutional investor
EP5
And because the government actually, they provide lots of money, not only direct support, but they also provide money for the venture capital industry. So lots of money, the fund is actually matched by the government’s money, public money, which means that they’re prone to be in control of the government. They have to follow some government guidelines. So it has been said that Korean VC are not taking enough risk
EP11
Also, a program called TIPS has been created by the government, it’s a program like in Israel where the government matches the fund if someone invests in a startup, then they will back this investment with more money
The government also trusts the VCs more, so it’s a good progress
VC get fundraising from the government; their money comes from the tax. In that case, the most important thing is not to lose money, therefore, VC focus on not losing the money, even if the return is not big. VC is almost like debt financing
Source: Transcriptions of interviews conducted by the author. Spelling errors corrected for readability. Translations of interviews conducted in Korean language by the author
Table 9
Reforms of the KOTEC and KODIT joint guarantee system, 2005–2016
Year
Adjustments in the joint guarantee system
2005
Joint guarantee requirements eased for venture enterprises with good share dispersion
Complete exemption: less than 30% share by one person, technology ratings A and above or financial ratings AA and above (A for external audit enterprises)
Representative director or actual CEO only: Technology ratings BBB and above or financial ratings A and above
2006
“Representative director or actual CEO only” principle expanded to include the following:
Inno-biz enterprises with technology ratings BBB and above
Guarantees for KOTEC A + Member enterprises
Enterprises in local strategic industries with technology ratings BBB and above
Guarantees worth 50 million KRW and below per company
2010
Joint guarantee requirements eased for venture enterprises with institutional investments: Enterprises that show excellence in the investment share ratio of institutional investors and the investment amount compared to the guarantee amount
50% reduction in joint guarantor liability for CEOs of venture firms: Venture firms that have received R&D special guarantee support, in the development stage of R&D, technology ratings A and above, guarantee amounts 500 million and below
2011
Reducing the scope of guarantee providers to representatives and actual business managers of the enterprise for business starters that obtained BBB or higher Technology Rating Grades (TRG) (30 million KRW or less, 5 years or less)
2012
Abolishment of joint guarantee system for individual business owners, and if there is a designated business owner, only owner is responsible for joint guarantee (before: Joint representative, actual business manager, spouses, parents or children are liable)
In corporations, only representative director is liable, except when there is more than one business manager (in that case, 1/n) (before: representative, actual business manager, oligopolistic shareholder, parents or children are liable)
2013
Individual businesses: Only joint owner/actual business manager as per registration certificate is liable
Corporations: One official actual business manager (i.e., CEO, limited liability employee, largest shareholder)
2014
Special measure for liability exemption for excellent startups in terms of technology (TRG AAA) and ethics for five years
2015
Include non-startup excellent technology companies (TRG A) in the liability exemption
Reevaluation of discriminative components against former obligors whose legal liabilities expired or are completed, change terms and condition for companies that paid off subrogate debts
New risk and monitoring system, Fraud Transaction Warning System to handle potential risks from elimination of joint guarantee requirements for startups
2016
New Startup Guarantee Program that expanded the scope of exemption from the joint guarantee to startups of less than 5 years. Signing collaboration agreements with 17 commercial banks to spread such exemptions in the financial sector
Source: Based on KOTEC Annual Reports 2010–2016
1.
Questionnaire for entrepreneurs
Note: The original questionnaire contained some questions that were not relevant for the objective of this study and are therefore not shown.
 

Situation of Entrepreneurs/Startups in Korea

1.
From your point of view, could you briefly describe the recent development regarding Korean startups excluding foreign startups.
 
2.
When you think of your own experiences or experiences of friends or people you know, what is the image of entrepreneurs in the Korean society? Are they seen as deviant or rebellious?
 
3.
When you think of occupational choices in Korea, what is typically a desirable occupation among young people?
 

Personal Occupational Choice

1.
What was the motivation behind your current occupational decision?
 
2.
Which other aspects did you consider in the decision-making process regarding your occupation?
 
3.
How did your social surrounding, especially your parents, family, and friends, react upon your occupational decision?
 
4.
In what ways did you get support from family members or friends in starting your business?
 

Worries and Risks

1.
If you think about your business, what risks or threats do you think your business is exposed to?
 
2.
How do you deal with the risks related to your business? Could you maybe give an example?
 
3.
How does the Korean business environment relate to these risks?
 
4.
Think hypothetically: If your business would fail, how would you deal with this failure? What would you do afterwards?
 
5.
In your opinion, how is business failure related to personal failure? And how do you define personal failure?
 
6.
Can you think of an example – maybe among your friends or people you know – about how the Korean society treats people whose business has failed?
 

Regulations and Government Policies

1.
Which regulative obstacles or difficulties (laws, regulations, policies) did you encounter along the process of starting your business?
 
2.
And on the contrary, what was relatively easy?
 
3.
What kinds of support did you receive from the central or local government or other actors like universities or private actors?
 
4.
What other options to get support did you or would you consider?
 
2.
Questionnaire for experts
 

Institutional Change, Regulative Dimension

1.
From your point of view, could you first briefly describe the recent development regarding Korean entrepreneurs and startups excluding foreign startups.
 
2.
In what way has the regulative environment in terms of laws, regulations, or government policies for entrepreneurs changed in the past 5 to 10 years?
 
3.
After the IMF crisis there has already been a startup boom (alongside the worldwide growth of internet-based companies), which created companies like Naver Corp. Could you explain differences and similarities in institutional terms between this first startup boom and the current one?
 
4.
What kind of problems do you see in the current entrepreneurial activities?
 

Business Environment and Support

1.
What kind of support can young people who want to start a business receive from the central government/the local government/private organizations/universities?
 
2.
What kind of support can entrepreneurs who failed receive from the central government/the local government/private organizations/universities if they want to start a business again?
 
3.
What about receiving financial resources? How do Korean startups usually finance themselves? Would you say it is easy or difficult to get financial support from the government/investors or other sources?
 
4.
Can you say something to bankruptcy laws in Korea? How do they work for entrepreneurs (strict?), and do you think they influence the decision to start a business?
 

Education and Risk

1.
How does the Korean education system prepare young people to become entrepreneurs?
 
2.
What would you recommend for the Korean education system to change to foster entrepreneurship or to improve the quality of entrepreneurs?
 
3.
How do you think Korean entrepreneurs are prepared for the risk of starting a business?
 
4.
Are Koreans in general rather afraid of the risk related to starting a business and if yes, why?
 

Social Institutions

1.
What else (other than possibly financial risk) do you think holds young Koreans back from starting a business?
 
Fußnoten
1
Purposive sampling is a nonprobabilistic sampling technique, which is based on the researcher’s specific selection criteria or subjective judgement about the quality of participants (Etikan 2016:2). This sampling technique is limited in drawing conclusions about the total population due to sampling bias (Etikan 2016:4).
 
2
Net enrolment ratio: number of children of (secondary) school age enrolled in (secondary) school divided by number of children of (secondary) school age. Gross enrolment ratio: number of individuals enrolled in tertiary education divided by number of individuals of tertiary education age.
 
3
Classification according to the International Standard Classification of Education (ISCED), see OECD (2019: 19) for details.
 
4
All values in Korean Won (KRW) hereafter are converted into US-Dollar (USD) with the exchange rate of 01.01.2020 (1,000 KRW = 0.86 USD).
 
5
The KCSAT exam is developed and managed by the Korean Institute for Curriculum and Evaluation (KICE), which is commissioned by the Ministry of Education (MOE). The test format is mostly multiple choice. The score report includes not only the standard score but also percentile rank, which allows the results to be compared with all exam participants in Korea.
 
6
The term “spec” is used in Korean for various qualifications, certificates and experiences that are regarded as beneficial for one’s attractiveness in the labor market as they indicate a student’s competitiveness.
 
7
The Asan Nanum Foundation is a non-profit foundation established in 2011 to commemorate the 10th anniversary of the death of Hyundai’s late founder and chairman Chung Ju-yung.
 
8
Similar initiatives existed during the first venture boom in the late 1990s and early 2000s; however, the activities slowed down and revived only after the change of the president of KAIST in 2013.
 
9
In Korea, SMEs and small businesses are defined by their sector-specific average sales figures of the last three years.
 
10
Monthly remuneration varies by type of government official and is adjusted regularly.
 
11
Despite President Roh Moo-hyun’s (2003–2008) regional equity policy, centralization remains strong in Korea. See Lee (2009) for details on regional policies and balanced growth strategy in Korea.
 
12
Ninety percent of incorporated businesses in Korea are stock companies, so-called chusikhoesa, which is often mistranslated to Limited Liability Company (yuhanhoesa). But regardless of the legal business form and the respective degree of limited liability, the joint guarantee system is determined by the Commercial Law and the Civil Law in Korea (KET 2016).
 
13
English version: “Article 437 (Defense by Surety of Peremptory Notice and Inquiry): If an obligee has demanded performance of the obligation from the surety, upon proving that the principal obligor has sufficient means to effect performance and that the execution would be easy, the surety may enter a plea as a defense that the obligee must demand from the principal obligor and that he must first levy execution on the property of the principal obligor: Provided, That if the surety has assumed an obligation jointly and severally liable with the principal obligor, this shall not be apply.” Source: Civil Act (Enforcement Date 20.12.2016).
 
14
English version: “Article 57 (Joint and Several Obligations among Multiple Obligors, or between Obligor and Guarantor): (1) If two or more persons assume obligations arising out of transactions that are commercial activities in respect of one or all of them, they shall be jointly and severally liable for the obligations. (2) Where there is a guarantor, if the guaranty itself is a commercial activity, or if the principal obligation has arisen out of a commercial activity, the principal obligor and the guarantor shall be jointly and severally liable for the obligation.” Source: Commercial Act (Enforcement Date 02.03.2016).
 
15
The KOTEC Annual Report 2016 (KOTEC 2016:26) states: “The contributions from the government are transferred from the government’s General Account to KOTEC to facilitate KOTEC’s supply fund for technologically innovative SMEs with weak collateral capabilities. The contributions are provided to KOTEC every year directly from the government’s fiscal budget (KRW 50 billion in 2014 [43 million USD], 40 billion [34.4 million USD] in 2015 and 80 billion KRW [68.8 million USD] in 2016) in the form of public goods assigned to protect and foster technology startups and SMEs.”.
 
16
As a sign that government support is taken for granted, the KVCA states on its English homepage: “It is generally accepted that the Korean government plays an important role in supporting private fund-raising and investment in the market.” (KVCA n.d.).
 
17
Beside the strong role of the government in the fund-raising stage, Lee (2008:217–219) lists the short life span of outside funds with a duration of usually five years, IPO as the dominant exit form due to an underdeveloped M&A market, and the increasing proportion of expansion-staged invested firms as characteristics of the Korean VC market.
 
18
In 2018, 133 VC firms were registered.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Ahn CY (2018) Income-led growth and innovative growth policies in Korea: challenges, rebalancing, and a new business ecosystem, KEI Acad Pap Ser, May Ahn CY (2018) Income-led growth and innovative growth policies in Korea: challenges, rebalancing, and a new business ecosystem, KEI Acad Pap Ser, May
Zurück zum Zitat Aidis R, Estrin S, Mickiewicz (2009) Entrepreneurial entry: which institutions matter? IZA Discussion Paper 4123 Aidis R, Estrin S, Mickiewicz (2009) Entrepreneurial entry: which institutions matter? IZA Discussion Paper 4123
Zurück zum Zitat Amsden AH (1989) Asia’s next giant: South Korea and late industrialization. Oxford University Press, New York Amsden AH (1989) Asia’s next giant: South Korea and late industrialization. Oxford University Press, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Audretsch DB, Keilbach MC, Lehmann EE (2006) Entrepreneurship and economic growth. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRef Audretsch DB, Keilbach MC, Lehmann EE (2006) Entrepreneurship and economic growth. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cha DS, Kim I (2010) Development of Korea’s financial policies and the financial market. In: Sung KJ (ed) Development experience of the Korean economy. Kyung Hee University Press, Seoul, pp 189–211 Cha DS, Kim I (2010) Development of Korea’s financial policies and the financial market. In: Sung KJ (ed) Development experience of the Korean economy. Kyung Hee University Press, Seoul, pp 189–211
Zurück zum Zitat Cha DW (2015) The creative economy of the Park Geun-hye administration. Korea’s Economy 30:35–47 Cha DW (2015) The creative economy of the Park Geun-hye administration. Korea’s Economy 30:35–47
Zurück zum Zitat Choi YK, Kim DI (2004) Changes in the labor markets and industrial relations. In: Chung DK, Eichengreen BJ (eds) The Korean economy beyond the crisis. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, Northampton, pp 218–238 Choi YK, Kim DI (2004) Changes in the labor markets and industrial relations. In: Chung DK, Eichengreen BJ (eds) The Korean economy beyond the crisis. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, Northampton, pp 218–238
Zurück zum Zitat Davidsson P (2003) The domain of entrepreneurship research: some suggestions. In: Katz JA, Shepherd DA (eds) Cognitive approaches to entrepreneurship research. Emerald Group Publishing Limited, Bingley, pp 315–372CrossRef Davidsson P (2003) The domain of entrepreneurship research: some suggestions. In: Katz JA, Shepherd DA (eds) Cognitive approaches to entrepreneurship research. Emerald Group Publishing Limited, Bingley, pp 315–372CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Financial Services Commission (FSC) (2015) ch’angŭi hyŏksin kiŏp chiwŏnŭl wihan kŭmyunggaehyŏk, 40nyŏnmanŭi chŏngch’aekpojŭng tae kaep’yŏn - chungsogiŏp sin pojŭngch’egye kujuk (Financial Reform for the Support of Creative and Innovative Businesses, Great Restructuring of the 40-Year-Old Guarantee System - Building a Modern Guarantee System). Website of Financial Services Commission. https://www.fsc.go.kr/downManager?bbsid=BBS0029&no=100365. Accessed 26 Mar 2020. In Korean Financial Services Commission (FSC) (2015) ch’angŭi hyŏksin kiŏp chiwŏnŭl wihan kŭmyunggaehyŏk, 40nyŏnmanŭi chŏngch’aekpojŭng tae kaep’yŏn - chungsogiŏp sin pojŭngch’egye kujuk (Financial Reform for the Support of Creative and Innovative Businesses, Great Restructuring of the 40-Year-Old Guarantee System - Building a Modern Guarantee System). Website of Financial Services Commission. https://​www.​fsc.​go.​kr/​downManager?​bbsid=​BBS0029&​no=​100365. Accessed 26 Mar 2020. In Korean
Zurück zum Zitat Jin TH, Kim DY, Ham JH (2004) Development direction of the Korean financial system. Bank of Korea Quart Econ Anal 10(2):1–31 Jin TH, Kim DY, Ham JH (2004) Development direction of the Korean financial system. Bank of Korea Quart Econ Anal 10(2):1–31
Zurück zum Zitat Joh SW (2015) Chaebols as South Korean entrepreneurship. In: Yu TFL, Yan HD (eds) Handbook of East Asian Entrepreneurship. Routledge, Abingdon, New York, pp 157–168 Joh SW (2015) Chaebols as South Korean entrepreneurship. In: Yu TFL, Yan HD (eds) Handbook of East Asian Entrepreneurship. Routledge, Abingdon, New York, pp 157–168
Zurück zum Zitat Jones LP, SaKong I (1985) Government, business, and entrepreneurship in economic development: The Korean case. Council of East Asian Studies Harvard University, Cambridge, London Jones LP, SaKong I (1985) Government, business, and entrepreneurship in economic development: The Korean case. Council of East Asian Studies Harvard University, Cambridge, London
Zurück zum Zitat Jones RS (2011) Sustaining rapid growth in Korea through innovation. Korea’s Economy 23:35–43 Jones RS (2011) Sustaining rapid growth in Korea through innovation. Korea’s Economy 23:35–43
Zurück zum Zitat Jones RS (2015) Spurring the development of venture capital in Korea. Korea’s Economy 30:55–63 Jones RS (2015) Spurring the development of venture capital in Korea. Korea’s Economy 30:55–63
Zurück zum Zitat Kim SS, Choi YS (2019) The innovative platform programme in South Korea: economic policies in innovation-driven growth. Foresight and STI Governance 13(3):13–22CrossRef Kim SS, Choi YS (2019) The innovative platform programme in South Korea: economic policies in innovation-driven growth. Foresight and STI Governance 13(3):13–22CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kim Y (2015) taejolssinip yŏnbongp’yŏnggyun 3ch’ŏn48manwŏn…taegiŏp, chunggi 1.5pae (College Graduates’ Average Annual Salary is 30.48 million KRW…in Large Enterprises, 1.5 Times Higher than in SMEs). Yonhap News, Seoul. https://www.yna.co.kr/view/AKR20150416056100003. Accessed 26 Mar 2020. In Korean Kim Y (2015) taejolssinip yŏnbongp’yŏnggyun 3ch’ŏn48manwŏn…taegiŏp, chunggi 1.5pae (College Graduates’ Average Annual Salary is 30.48 million KRW…in Large Enterprises, 1.5 Times Higher than in SMEs). Yonhap News, Seoul. https://​www.​yna.​co.​kr/​view/​AKR2015041605610​0003. Accessed 26 Mar 2020. In Korean
Zurück zum Zitat Kim YS (2014) Ways to activate youth employment: focusing on government-funded job programs and promotion of entrepreneurship. KDI Focus 35:1–9 Kim YS (2014) Ways to activate youth employment: focusing on government-funded job programs and promotion of entrepreneurship. KDI Focus 35:1–9
Zurück zum Zitat Kirzner IM (1974) Competition and entrepreneurship. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, London Kirzner IM (1974) Competition and entrepreneurship. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, London
Zurück zum Zitat Knight FH (1971) [1921]) Risk, uncertainty and profit. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, London Knight FH (1971) [1921]) Risk, uncertainty and profit. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, London
Zurück zum Zitat Korea Institute of Entrepreneurship and Technology (KET) (2016) swiun ‘chusikhoesa’ kiban ch’angŏbŭi yŏksŏl - ‘sinyongbullyangja’ro kanŭn chirŭmgil (Paradox of the Easy Establishment of a Stock Company - Shortcut Going Through a ‘Delinquent Borrower’). Website of Korea Institute of Entrepreneurship and Technology. https://ket-nyet.org/2016/09/25/blog-53/. Accessed 26 Mar 2020. In Korean Korea Institute of Entrepreneurship and Technology (KET) (2016) swiun ‘chusikhoesa’ kiban ch’angŏbŭi yŏksŏl - ‘sinyongbullyangja’ro kanŭn chirŭmgil (Paradox of the Easy Establishment of a Stock Company - Shortcut Going Through a ‘Delinquent Borrower’). Website of Korea Institute of Entrepreneurship and Technology. https://​ket-nyet.​org/​2016/​09/​25/​blog-53/​. Accessed 26 Mar 2020. In Korean
Zurück zum Zitat Kwon OY (2010) The Korean economy in transition: an institutional perspective. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, NorthamptonCrossRef Kwon OY (2010) The Korean economy in transition: an institutional perspective. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, NorthamptonCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lee S (2008) The development of venture capital industry and the role of government in Korea: venture boom vs. post-boom. KDI J Econ Policy 30, 1: 213–246 Lee S (2008) The development of venture capital industry and the role of government in Korea: venture boom vs. post-boom. KDI J Econ Policy 30, 1: 213–246
Zurück zum Zitat Lee SY, Lee S (2014) Civil service reforms and the development of Korea. The Korean J Pol Stud 29(1):47–67CrossRef Lee SY, Lee S (2014) Civil service reforms and the development of Korea. The Korean J Pol Stud 29(1):47–67CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat North DC (1990) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge [i.a.] North DC (1990) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge [i.a.]
Zurück zum Zitat North DC (1994) Economic performance through time. Am Econ Rev 84(3):359–368 North DC (1994) Economic performance through time. Am Econ Rev 84(3):359–368
Zurück zum Zitat Oh DS, Yeom I (2012) Daedeok Innopolis in Korea: From science park to innovation cluster. World Technopolis Review 1(2):141–154CrossRef Oh DS, Yeom I (2012) Daedeok Innopolis in Korea: From science park to innovation cluster. World Technopolis Review 1(2):141–154CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pak C (2016) ch’wiŏbyŏsŏngŭi il·kajŏngyangnip silt’aewa chŏngch’aekchŏk hamŭi (Work-family balance and in working women and its policy implications (sic)). pogŏnbokchip’orŏm (Health and Welfare Policy Forum) 06: 18–36. In Korean Pak C (2016) ch’wiŏbyŏsŏngŭi il·kajŏngyangnip silt’aewa chŏngch’aekchŏk hamŭi (Work-family balance and in working women and its policy implications (sic)). pogŏnbokchip’orŏm (Health and Welfare Policy Forum) 06: 18–36. In Korean
Zurück zum Zitat Parker SC (2009) The economics of entrepreneurship. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef Parker SC (2009) The economics of entrepreneurship. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Platum (2014) ch’ŏngsonyŏn pijŭk’ul, chinhak·ch’angŏp·ch’wiŏmmodello kakkwang (Youth BizCool, spotlight on entering university, starting a business and finding a job). http://platum.kr/archives/17303. Accessed 26 March 2020. In Korean Platum (2014) ch’ŏngsonyŏn pijŭk’ul, chinhak·ch’angŏp·ch’wiŏmmodello kakkwang (Youth BizCool, spotlight on entering university, starting a business and finding a job). http://​platum.​kr/​archives/​17303. Accessed 26 March 2020. In Korean
Zurück zum Zitat Saldaña J (2009) The coding manual for qualitative researchers. SAGE Publications, Los Angeles Saldaña J (2009) The coding manual for qualitative researchers. SAGE Publications, Los Angeles
Zurück zum Zitat Schauer J (2018) Labor market duality in Korea. IMF Working Paper WP/18/126 Schauer J (2018) Labor market duality in Korea. IMF Working Paper WP/18/126
Zurück zum Zitat Schumpeter JA (1983) [1934]) The theory of economic development: an inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycle. Transaction Publishers, New Brunswick, London Schumpeter JA (1983) [1934]) The theory of economic development: an inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycle. Transaction Publishers, New Brunswick, London
Zurück zum Zitat Scott WR (2014) Institutions and organizations: Ideas, interests, and identities, 4th edn. SAGE Publications, Los Angeles Scott WR (2014) Institutions and organizations: Ideas, interests, and identities, 4th edn. SAGE Publications, Los Angeles
Zurück zum Zitat Stam E, van Stel A (2011) Types of entrepreneurship and economic growth. In: Szirmai A, Naudé AW, Goedhuys M (eds) Entrepreneurship, innovation, and economic development. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 78–95CrossRef Stam E, van Stel A (2011) Types of entrepreneurship and economic growth. In: Szirmai A, Naudé AW, Goedhuys M (eds) Entrepreneurship, innovation, and economic development. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 78–95CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wennekers S, Uhlaner L, Thurik R (2002) Entrepreneurship and its conditions: a macro perspective. Int J Entrep Educ 1(1):25–64 Wennekers S, Uhlaner L, Thurik R (2002) Entrepreneurship and its conditions: a macro perspective. Int J Entrep Educ 1(1):25–64
Zurück zum Zitat Williamson OE (2000) The new institutional economics: taking stock, looking ahead. J Econ Lit XXXVIII: 595–613 Williamson OE (2000) The new institutional economics: taking stock, looking ahead. J Econ Lit XXXVIII: 595–613
Zurück zum Zitat Yun JW (2009) Labor market polarization in South Korea: the role of policy failures in growing inequality. Asian Surv 49(2):268–290CrossRef Yun JW (2009) Labor market polarization in South Korea: the role of policy failures in growing inequality. Asian Surv 49(2):268–290CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Yun JW (2010) The myth of Confucian capitalism in South Korea: overworked elderly and underworked youth. Pac Aff 83(2):237–259CrossRef Yun JW (2010) The myth of Confucian capitalism in South Korea: overworked elderly and underworked youth. Pac Aff 83(2):237–259CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Yun JW (2013) Sacrificing entrepreneurship? The labor politics of small businesses in Korea and Japan. Korea Observer 44(1):55–86 Yun JW (2013) Sacrificing entrepreneurship? The labor politics of small businesses in Korea and Japan. Korea Observer 44(1):55–86
Metadaten
Titel
Institutional change and entrepreneurship as occupational choice—The case of South Korea
verfasst von
Diana Schüler
Publikationsdatum
17.03.2022
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Journal of International Entrepreneurship / Ausgabe 3/2023
Print ISSN: 1570-7385
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7349
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10843-022-00313-2

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3/2023

Journal of International Entrepreneurship 3/2023 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner