Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Quantitative Marketing and Economics 1/2008

01.03.2008

The discriminatory incentives to bundle in the cable television industry

verfasst von: Gregory S. Crawford

Erschienen in: Quantitative Marketing and Economics | Ausgabe 1/2008

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

An influential theoretical literature supports a discriminatory explanation for product bundling: it reduces consumer heterogeneity, extracting surplus in a manner similar to second-degree price discrimination. This paper tests this theory and quantifies its importance in the cable television industry. The results provide qualified support for the theory. While bundling of general-interest cable networks is estimated to have no discriminatory effect, bundling an average top-15 special-interest cable network significantly increases the estimated elasticity of cable demand. Calibrating these results to a simple model of bundle demand with normally distributed tastes suggests that such bundling yields a heterogeneity reduction equal to a 4.7% increase in firm profits (and 4.0% reduction in consumers surplus). The results are robust to alternative explanations for bundling.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
See Reuters (2003), GAO (2003), Squeo and Flint (2004), FCC (2006).
 
2
Negative correlation, however, is not necessary for bundling to be profitable (McAfee et al. 1989).
 
3
McAfee et al. (1989) extend the analysis of Adams and Yellen (1976) to consider mixed bundling, the offering of both component and bundled sales, and show it always yields (weakly) greater profits than pure bundling. The reason for this is clear: it maintains the benefits of bundling (if any) and strictly increases the number of prices available to capture surplus. Despite this fact, mixed bundling is relatively uncommon, perhaps due to the added administrative costs associated with offering both bundled and component goods.
 
4
Note that in this specification there are no income effects nor any complementarity or substitutability in demand, two issues that we discuss further below.
 
5
Bakos and Brynjolfsson (1999, Footnote 21): “A sequence {v i } is called stationary in the wide sense if \(E\{|v_i|^2\} < \infty\) for all i, and the covariance Cov(v s+i, v s ) does not depend on s. This condition is satisfied, for example, if all v i are identically distributed with finite mean and variance, and \(\rho_{i,j} = \rho^{|i-j|}\) for some ρ in (0,1), and for all i and j.”
 
6
Strictly speaking, this proposition extends Bakos and Brynjolfsson (1999) Proposition 3 to allow for correlation in tastes. As stated, it is correct, as A4 is strong enough to allow for the more general correlation structure.
 
7
This may seem counter-intuitive. For a fixed level of demand (e.g. rotate a linear demand curve around its intersection with the quantity axis), a monopolists profit is higher the more inelastic is demand. Bundling, however, simultaneously shifts out and flattens the aggregate demand curve.
 
8
Recent exceptions may include sport networks. We discuss this issue in more detail in the next subsection.
 
9
Both Armstrong (1999) and Bakos and Brynjolfsson (1999) note that this assumption might be violated if preferences for components are correlated with one or more underlying variables (esp. income). For example, high-income households might be willing to pay more than low-income households for all cable networks. In this case, Armstrong (1996) shows that the “almost-optimal” tariff would be a menu of cost-based two-part tariffs (with the menu designed to sort households by income) and Bakos and Brynjolfsson (1999) note that the properties of their propositions can be restored by conditioning on income. We include demographic variables (including income) as demand shifters for each offered cable bundle in our econometric model in part to account for this concern. See Crawford and Shum (2006) and Xiao et al. (2006) for analyses that allow for menus of product bundles.
 
10
As noted in BB, if preferences for components are i.i.d., the single-crossing condition (SCDC) is not particularly restrictive. It is satisfied for most common demand functions, including the logit specification used in our empirical tests. If, however, preferences for components are positively correlated or differ dramatically in their dispersion (as measured by σ), the assumption may not hold and there is no guarantee bundling reduces heterogeneity and increases profits. This provides power for our empirical tests.
 
11
For convenience, Bakos and Brynjolfsson (1999) focus on the across-component average willingness-to-pay for a bundle. The aggregate effects of bundling, however, apply equally to demand for the whole bundle: under A1–A3, mean WTP for the bundle increases at rate n while the standard deviation increases at rate \(\sqrt{n}\). The coefficient of variation for the bundle, \(\sigma_{\mbox{\tiny bun}}/\mu_{\mbox{\tiny bun}}\), therefore decreases at rate \(\sqrt{n}\). We consider both the per-good and aggregate implications in Appendix 1.
 
12
Alternative formulations of this proposition are possible (e.g. evaluating the elasticity at a given quantity, at the mean of consumer preferences, or evaluating each elasticity at its profit-maximizing price). We chose the given form as that provides the most natural empirical implementation. See footnote 25 for the implication of this choice for our empirical tests.
 
13
Versus an average 1995 price of $17.33 for the most popular bundle in our data.
 
14
Indeed if it were not so, one might expect cable systems to optimally unbundle relatively expensive basic networks as they do premium networks. Footnote 20 describes a desire for movement in this direction for sports networks.
 
15
The impact of complementarity in demand on the cable elasticity would depend on how complementarities varied within the distribution of households. If (as seems likely) preferences in high-WTP households exhibited stronger complementarities than in low-WTP households, the bundle demand curve would likely shift out and rotate clockwise with additions to the bundle, decreasing the (absolute value of the) elasticity of cable demand.
 
16
Premium networks have recently begun “multiplexing” their programming, i.e. offering multiple channels under a single network/brand (e.g. HBO, HBO 2, HBO Family, etc.).
 
17
With the rise of digital cable, many cable systems now offer more service tiers. These were not available, however, in the time period we study.
 
18
Early methods to block consumption relied on electromechanical “traps” placed at the link between the household and the cable distribution system. Most (but not all) systems now offer “addressable” converters which control access via electronic communication with the cable headend.
 
19
Cable networks typically charge moderate fees to cable systems, ranging from nothing to $1.00 or more per subscriber per month. By contrast, premium networks charge higher fees, up to several dollars per subscriber per month for HBO.
 
20
Witness the recent disputes between ESPN and Cox and the NFL Network and Time Warner/Cablevision over the possible unbundling of sports networks (e.g. www.​keepespn.​com, www.​makethemplayfair​.​com, Gentile 2004 and Thompson 2006).
 
21
For example, Direct Broadcast Satellite providers of multi-channel programming in competition with cable systems face no technological constraint but also engage in widespread bundling.
 
22
While there are over 11,000 systems in the sample, persistence in non-response over time as well as incomplete reporting of critical variables required imposing a large number of conditions in order for a system to be included in each sample. Missing information on prices, quantities, and reporting dates were responsible for the majority of the exclusions.
 
23
At the time of the sample data, the heterogeneity in carriage and allocation of a given network to a given service across systems was largely driven by two factors: variation in the tiering strategies taken by different MSOs (with a given strategy typically implemented in most but not all of an MSO’s systems) and variation in local tastes for programming (influencing especially carriage decisions). See footnote 32 for more on this issue.
 
24
This is a reliable measure of market size as it defines the set of households available to purchase cable services from each system.
 
25
Evaluating the elasticity at \(p^{*}_{\mbox{\tiny No MTV}}\) turns out to be difficult as we do not observe this price in the data and simulating it would require modeling firms’ optimal pricing decisions. Instead, we evaluate the elasticity at the observed bundle prices, themselves a weighted average of the optimal No-MTV and MTV bundle prices. If anything, this biases us against finding evidence of the discriminatory theory as that price is too high for the No-MTV bundle (over-estimating its elasticity) and too low for the With-MTV bundle (under-estimating its elasticity). Alternatives (e.g. evaluating elasticities at a given quantity) yielded stronger support for the discriminatory theory but made it more confusing to measure the profit and welfare effects (which necessarily had to be evaluated at profit-maximizing prices).
 
26
Examples of the former include TBS, USA, and TNT. Examples of the latter (with their primary type of programming) include ESPN (Sports), CSPAN (Public Affairs), and QVC (Home Shopping).
 
27
This is not perfect, however. As noted by a referee, tastes for some pairs of special-interest networks may be independent or even positively correlated (e.g. sports and action networks). We do not dispute that. The claim here is that, on average, tastes for a special-interest network and an existing bundle are more likely to be negatively correlated than tastes for a general-interest network and a bundle.
 
28
Estimation using logit and nested logit models simplifies the estimating equations when some products are bundles that include the contents of other products (Crawford 2000). This and a lack of precision on the nesting parameter(s) in the nested logit model led us to prefer the logit specification.
 
29
In particular, estimating using only one bundle per market—whether the lowest or highest quality—yielded similar (though less precise) results.
 
30
The logic of this argument is that households have preferences for the set of services offered by cable systems, but are unlikely to care about the size or identity of provider of those services. There is little branding of cable systems (in contrast to cable networks). This may not be true in the long run, however, if certain providers provide (unobservably) higher quality cable services. The nature of the product in cable helps alleviate this concern. It is easy to enumerate the things that matter to consumers about cable service; most important by far is the set of program networks they can watch and these are observed by the econometrician. Other features (signal quality, customer service, etc.) are likely of second-order importance to demand and regardless unlikely to be correlated with programming cost shifters.
 
31
The identification assumption may be described by assumptions on the following generic reduced form for cable prices:
$$p_{sn} = c_{sn} + \epsilon_{sn} $$
where p sn measures the price of good s in market n, c sn is its marginal cost, and ε sn measures unmodeled cost and demand shocks to cable prices (including markups). Then if E(c sn c sn) ≠ 0 and E(ε sn ε sn) = 0, prices in other markets will be valid instruments for prices in market n. The nature of MSO bargaining for programming networks justifies the correlation in marginal costs across markets within an MSO. The validity of the assumption on ε is discussed in what follows.
 
32
This may not be as severe a problem as would appear at first glance. In cable, while local systems typically select what networks to offer, the decision to offer one or more expanded basic services and the decision of where to place networks, if offered, among these services is typically made by the MSO (GAO 2003). In addition, as most systems offer most networks (cf. Table 3), the econometric identification of tastes for networks is driven as much by the service on which a network is offered as whether it is carried at all. As such, it is the allocation of networks across services that is the important source of possible correlation with the econometric error, at least for the most popular networks. Since this decision is made by the MSO, it is unlikely to be correlated with tastes for cable in any particular market. This is less true for less popular networks, where endogeneity may therefore be a greater concern.
 
33
See Crawford and Shum (2006) for some related work on this problem.
 
34
Specifically, one can reject the null hypothesis \(H_0: \partial \epsilon_{bb} / \partial X_{k} < 0\) v. \(H_A: \partial \epsilon_{bb} / \partial X_{c}>0\) at size 0.05.
 
35
In particular, similar (unreported) regressions on more recent cable data from yielded similar results.
 
36
See Section 4.2.1 for a detailed description of the instruments.
 
37
Not reported are results using as instruments prices of other systems within the same MSO but outside the state or region of the given system. While consistent with the results presented here, the estimates are qualitatively similar, but less precise. For these reasons, we maintain a preference for the results presented above.
 
38
To accurately quantify the benefits of bundling, we would ideally calculate the effect on consumers, producers, and total welfare of alternative bundling strategies pursued by systems. To do so, however, requires estimates of the preferences for networks underlying the demand for cable bundles, namely their means, μ j ’s, variances, \(\sigma_j^2\)’s, and correlations, ρ j,k’s. This is quite challenging and the topic of a separate work in progress (Crawford and Yurukoglu 2007).
 
39
We focus exclusively on changes in preference heterogeneity via \(\sigma_{\mbox{\tiny bun}}\) as that is the primary consequence of bundling under the discriminatory theory.
 
40
See, e.g. Halfon (2003, footnote 78) and FCC (2003). While possibly high for the period we study, the qualitative conclusions we draw are similar across a range of marginal cost estimates.
 
41
This suggests mean preferences for cable service bundles are, on average, approximately 2.40 times their standard deviation.
 
42
Note that these results only quantify the profit and welfare consequences from the heterogeneity reduction caused by bundling. It ignores the (positive) effects to both profit and welfare of increases in the mean of preferences due to the addition of a valuable network to the bundle.
 
43
An exception is the Nashville Network.
 
44
Kagan Media Research (2005) “estimates TV channel operators would need to raise per-capita channel carriage fees by a multiple of four to offset a 50% loss of subscribers from big basic bundles.” Furthermore, Rennhoff and Serfes (2005) present a theoretical analysis of competition between program networks and cable systems with and without bundling and find costs to cable systems would increase without bundling.
 
45
Much of this proof follows ideas in Bakos and Brynjolfsson (1999, Appendix).
 
46
Letting \(\epsilon = \mu - p^*_n\) suggests we are looking at non-marginal changes in price. An alternative proof would show the elasticity of the bundle demand curve increases with bundle size when evaluate at its mean. Empirical implementation of that approach is more difficult, however, leading us to favor the given approach.
 
47
In particular, \(\frac{n - \omega A(n)}{n - \frac{\omega A(n)}{2}}~ \tilde{p}_n \geq \frac{n - \omega}{n - \frac{\omega}{2}}~ \tilde{p}_n\) simplifies to A(n) ≤ 1.
 
48
Note sign\((\partial / \partial \eta) = -\)sign\((\partial / \partial n)\).
 
49
Only results for the instruments are reported in the table.
 
50
Note since all systems that offer an Expanded Service also offer a basic service, separate parameters are not identified for the Expanded I parameters in the second column. For an analogous reason, separate parameters are not identified for either Expanded Service in the third column.
 
51
Note that because of the cross-equation restrictions on β and γ, identification obtains as long as the instruments are valid for at least one of the endogenous prices.
 
52
Not all systems belong to an MSO. To address this issue, we pool systems with a single owner and treat them as other MSOs: including as a value for the instrument in market n the average price for all single-owner systems other than that in n. While the argument advocating marginal costs are correlated is weaker in this case than in the case of a common owner, single-owner systems tend to be smaller than average and, due to a common disadvantage when bargaining with network providers, have similar marginal costs.
 
53
Specifically 16 networks * 3 services = 48 specifications.
 
54
The problem of imprecision seen in the third column of the price regressions was exacerbated in the network carriage specifications. For some networks, only one or two of the 168 systems that offered a second expanded basic service carried that network on that service, implying an inability to identify the effects of any instruments. Analogously to that described above, identification of the parameters of interest requires the instruments have power for carriage on at least one service.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Adams, W., & Yellen, J. (1976). Commodity bundling and the burden of monopoly. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90, 475–498.CrossRef Adams, W., & Yellen, J. (1976). Commodity bundling and the burden of monopoly. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90, 475–498.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Angrist, J., & Krueger, A. (2001). Instrumental variables and the search for identification: From supply and demand to natural experiments. NBER Working Paper 8456. Angrist, J., & Krueger, A. (2001). Instrumental variables and the search for identification: From supply and demand to natural experiments. NBER Working Paper 8456.
Zurück zum Zitat Armstrong, M. (1996). Multiproduct non-linear pricing. Econometrica, 64(1), 51–75.CrossRef Armstrong, M. (1996). Multiproduct non-linear pricing. Econometrica, 64(1), 51–75.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Armstrong, M. (1999). Price discrimination by a multi-product firm. Review of Economic Studies, 66, 151–168.CrossRef Armstrong, M. (1999). Price discrimination by a multi-product firm. Review of Economic Studies, 66, 151–168.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bakos, Y., & Brynjolfsson, E. (1999). Bundling information goods: Pricing, profits, and efficiency. Management Science, 45(2), 1613–1630.CrossRef Bakos, Y., & Brynjolfsson, E. (1999). Bundling information goods: Pricing, profits, and efficiency. Management Science, 45(2), 1613–1630.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bakos, Y., & Brynjolfsson, E. (2000). Bundling and competition on the Internet. Marketing Science, 19(1), 63–82.CrossRef Bakos, Y., & Brynjolfsson, E. (2000). Bundling and competition on the Internet. Marketing Science, 19(1), 63–82.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berry, S. (1994). Estimating discrete choice models of product differentiation. Rand Journal of Economics, 25(2), 242–262.CrossRef Berry, S. (1994). Estimating discrete choice models of product differentiation. Rand Journal of Economics, 25(2), 242–262.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berry, S., Levinsohn, J., & Pakes, A. (1995). Automobile prices in market equilibrium. Econometrica, 63, 841–890.CrossRef Berry, S., Levinsohn, J., & Pakes, A. (1995). Automobile prices in market equilibrium. Econometrica, 63, 841–890.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bresnahan, T., & Gordon, R. (1996). The economics of new goods: An introduction. In T. Bresnahan, R. Gordon (Eds.), The Economics of New Goods. University of Chicago Press. Bresnahan, T., & Gordon, R. (1996). The economics of new goods: An introduction. In T. Bresnahan, R. Gordon (Eds.), The Economics of New Goods. University of Chicago Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Carlton, D., & Perloff, J. (2001). Modern Industrial Organization (3rd ed.). Harper Collins Carlton, D., & Perloff, J. (2001). Modern Industrial Organization (3rd ed.). Harper Collins
Zurück zum Zitat Chae, S. (1992). Bundling subscription TV channels: A case of natural bundling. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 10, 213–230.CrossRef Chae, S. (1992). Bundling subscription TV channels: A case of natural bundling. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 10, 213–230.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chipty, T. (1995). Horizontal integration for bargaining power: Evidence from the cable television industry. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 4(2), 375–97.CrossRef Chipty, T. (1995). Horizontal integration for bargaining power: Evidence from the cable television industry. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 4(2), 375–97.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chipty, T. (2001). Vertical integration, market foreclosure, and consumer welfare in the cable television industry. American Economic Review, 91(3), 428–453.CrossRef Chipty, T. (2001). Vertical integration, market foreclosure, and consumer welfare in the cable television industry. American Economic Review, 91(3), 428–453.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Crawford, G. (2000). The impact of the 1992 cable act on household demand and welfare. RAND Journal of Economics, 31(3), 422–449.CrossRef Crawford, G. (2000). The impact of the 1992 cable act on household demand and welfare. RAND Journal of Economics, 31(3), 422–449.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Crawford, G., & Cullen, J. (2007). Bundling, product choice, and efficiency: Should cable television networks be offered À La Carte? Information Economics and Policy (in press). Crawford, G., & Cullen, J. (2007). Bundling, product choice, and efficiency: Should cable television networks be offered À La Carte? Information Economics and Policy (in press).
Zurück zum Zitat Crawford, G., & Shum, M. (2006). Empirical modeling of endogenous quality choice: The case of cable television. Mimeo, University of Arizona. Crawford, G., & Shum, M. (2006). Empirical modeling of endogenous quality choice: The case of cable television. Mimeo, University of Arizona.
Zurück zum Zitat Crawford, G., & Yurukoglu, A. (2007). Demand, pricing, and bundling in subscription television markets. Mimeo, University of Arizona. Crawford, G., & Yurukoglu, A. (2007). Demand, pricing, and bundling in subscription television markets. Mimeo, University of Arizona.
Zurück zum Zitat Einav, L. (2007). Seasonality in the U.S. motion picture industry. RAND Journal of Economics, 38(1). Einav, L. (2007). Seasonality in the U.S. motion picture industry. RAND Journal of Economics, 38(1).
Zurück zum Zitat GAO (2003). Issues related to competition and subscriber rates in the cable television industry. Discussion paper, General Accounting Office, GAO-04-8. GAO (2003). Issues related to competition and subscriber rates in the cable television industry. Discussion paper, General Accounting Office, GAO-04-8.
Zurück zum Zitat Gentile, G. (2004). ESPN ends ugly fight with Cox over fees. Associated Press. Gentile, G. (2004). ESPN ends ugly fight with Cox over fees. Associated Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Griliches, Z., & Cockburn, I. (1994). Generics and new goods in pharmaceutical price indexes. American Economic Review, 84(5), 1213–1232. Griliches, Z., & Cockburn, I. (1994). Generics and new goods in pharmaceutical price indexes. American Economic Review, 84(5), 1213–1232.
Zurück zum Zitat Halfon, J. (2003). The failure of cable deregulation: A blueprint for creating a competitive, proconsumer cable television marketplace. United States Public Interest Research Group. Halfon, J. (2003). The failure of cable deregulation: A blueprint for creating a competitive, proconsumer cable television marketplace. United States Public Interest Research Group.
Zurück zum Zitat Hausman, J., Leonard, G., & Zona, D. (1994). Competitive analysis with differentiated products. Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, 34, 159–180. Hausman, J., Leonard, G., & Zona, D. (1994). Competitive analysis with differentiated products. Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, 34, 159–180.
Zurück zum Zitat Hazlett, T., & Spitzer, M. (1997). Public Policy Towards Cable Television: The Economics of Rate Controls. MIT Press. Hazlett, T., & Spitzer, M. (1997). Public Policy Towards Cable Television: The Economics of Rate Controls. MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Kagan World Media (1998). Economics of Basic Cable Television Networks. Discussion paper, Kagan World Media. Kagan World Media (1998). Economics of Basic Cable Television Networks. Discussion paper, Kagan World Media.
Zurück zum Zitat Lancaster, K. (1971). Consumer Demand: A New Approach. Columbia University Press. Lancaster, K. (1971). Consumer Demand: A New Approach. Columbia University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat McAfee, R. P., McMillan, J., & Whinston, M. (1989). Multiproduct monopoly, commodity bundling, and correlation of values. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103, 371–383.CrossRef McAfee, R. P., McMillan, J., & Whinston, M. (1989). Multiproduct monopoly, commodity bundling, and correlation of values. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103, 371–383.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mitchener, B., & Kanter, J. (2004). EU member states back record fine for microsoft. Wall Street Journal, March 24, 2004. Mitchener, B., & Kanter, J. (2004). EU member states back record fine for microsoft. Wall Street Journal, March 24, 2004.
Zurück zum Zitat Nalebuff, B. (2004). Bundling as an entry barrier. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(1), 159–187.CrossRef Nalebuff, B. (2004). Bundling as an entry barrier. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(1), 159–187.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nevo, A. (2001). Measuring market power in the ready-to-eat cereal industry. Econometrica, 69, 307–342.CrossRef Nevo, A. (2001). Measuring market power in the ready-to-eat cereal industry. Econometrica, 69, 307–342.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Noam, E. M. (1985). Economics of scale in cable television: A multiproduct analysis. In E. M. Noam (Ed.), Video Media Competition: Regulation, Economics, and Technology. Columbia University Press. Noam, E. M. (1985). Economics of scale in cable television: A multiproduct analysis. In E. M. Noam (Ed.), Video Media Competition: Regulation, Economics, and Technology. Columbia University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Petrin, A. (2003). Quantifying the benefits of new products: The case of the minivan. Journal of Political Economy, 110, 705–729.CrossRef Petrin, A. (2003). Quantifying the benefits of new products: The case of the minivan. Journal of Political Economy, 110, 705–729.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rennhoff, A., & Serfes, K. (2005). The role of upstream-downstream competition on bundling decisions: Should regulators force firms to unbundle? Mimeo, Drexel University. Rennhoff, A., & Serfes, K. (2005). The role of upstream-downstream competition on bundling decisions: Should regulators force firms to unbundle? Mimeo, Drexel University.
Zurück zum Zitat Reuters (2003). US lawmaker urges a la Carte cable channel rates. Reuters News Service. Reuters (2003). US lawmaker urges a la Carte cable channel rates. Reuters News Service.
Zurück zum Zitat Rochet, J.-C., & Chone, P. (1998). Ironing, sweeping, and multidimensional screening. Econometrica, 66(4), 783–826.CrossRef Rochet, J.-C., & Chone, P. (1998). Ironing, sweeping, and multidimensional screening. Econometrica, 66(4), 783–826.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rochet, J.-C., & Stole, L. (2000). The economics of multidimensional screening. Mimeo, University of Chicago. Rochet, J.-C., & Stole, L. (2000). The economics of multidimensional screening. Mimeo, University of Chicago.
Zurück zum Zitat Salinger, M. (1995). A graphical analysis of bundling. Journal of Business, 68(1), 85–98.CrossRef Salinger, M. (1995). A graphical analysis of bundling. Journal of Business, 68(1), 85–98.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Saloner, G., Shepard, A., & Podolny, J. (2001). Strategic Management. Wiley. Saloner, G., Shepard, A., & Podolny, J. (2001). Strategic Management. Wiley.
Zurück zum Zitat Schmalensee, R. (1984). Gaussian demand and commodity bundling. Journal of Business, 62, S211–S230. Schmalensee, R. (1984). Gaussian demand and commodity bundling. Journal of Business, 62, S211–S230.
Zurück zum Zitat Squeo, A. M., & Flint, J. (2004). Should cable be a la Carte not flat rate? Wall Street Journal. Squeo, A. M., & Flint, J. (2004). Should cable be a la Carte not flat rate? Wall Street Journal.
Zurück zum Zitat Stigler, G. (1963). United States v. Loew’s Inc.: A note on block booking. In P. Kurland (Ed.), The Supreme Court Review: 1963 (pp. 152–157). University of Chicago Press. Stigler, G. (1963). United States v. Loew’s Inc.: A note on block booking. In P. Kurland (Ed.), The Supreme Court Review: 1963 (pp. 152–157). University of Chicago Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Stigler, G. (1968). A note on block booking. In G. Stigler, R. D. Irwin (Eds.), The Organization of Industry. Stigler, G. (1968). A note on block booking. In G. Stigler, R. D. Irwin (Eds.), The Organization of Industry.
Zurück zum Zitat Stole, L. (2003). Price discrimination in competitive environments. Mimeo, University of Chicago. Stole, L. (2003). Price discrimination in competitive environments. Mimeo, University of Chicago.
Zurück zum Zitat Thompson, A. (2006). NFL v. cable is turning into a real nailbiter. Wall Street Journal. Thompson, A. (2006). NFL v. cable is turning into a real nailbiter. Wall Street Journal.
Zurück zum Zitat Varian, H. (2003). Intermediate Microeconomics (6th ed.). Norton Varian, H. (2003). Intermediate Microeconomics (6th ed.). Norton
Zurück zum Zitat Waterman, D. H., & Weiss, A. A. (1996). The effects of vertical integration between cable television systems and pay cable networks. Journal of Econometrics, 72, 357–95.CrossRef Waterman, D. H., & Weiss, A. A. (1996). The effects of vertical integration between cable television systems and pay cable networks. Journal of Econometrics, 72, 357–95.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Whinston, M. (1990). Tying, foreclosure, and exclusion. American Economic Review, 80(4), 837–859. Whinston, M. (1990). Tying, foreclosure, and exclusion. American Economic Review, 80(4), 837–859.
Zurück zum Zitat Wildman, S., & Owen, B. (1985). Program competition, diversity, and multichannel bundling in the New Video Industry. In E. M. Noam (Ed.) Video Media Competition: Regulation, Economics, and Technology. Columbia University Press. Wildman, S., & Owen, B. (1985). Program competition, diversity, and multichannel bundling in the New Video Industry. In E. M. Noam (Ed.) Video Media Competition: Regulation, Economics, and Technology. Columbia University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Xiao, P., Chan, T., & Narasimhan, C. (2006). Product bundles under three-part tariffs. Mimeo, Washington University. Xiao, P., Chan, T., & Narasimhan, C. (2006). Product bundles under three-part tariffs. Mimeo, Washington University.
Metadaten
Titel
The discriminatory incentives to bundle in the cable television industry
verfasst von
Gregory S. Crawford
Publikationsdatum
01.03.2008
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Quantitative Marketing and Economics / Ausgabe 1/2008
Print ISSN: 1570-7156
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-711X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-007-9031-7