Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Quantitative Marketing and Economics 3/2010

01.09.2010

A simple test for distinguishing between internal reference price theories

verfasst von: Tülin Erdem, Michael L. Katz, Baohong Sun

Erschienen in: Quantitative Marketing and Economics | Ausgabe 3/2010

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

A large literature demonstrates the empirical importance of internal reference price effects. There are several theories regarding how and why these effects arise. We offer a simple test that distinguishes between the two leading theories based on economically rational behavior: price as a signal of quality and price as a predictor of future prices. Our test builds on differences in how past consumer purchases interact with internal reference prices. We first validate the reliability of our test by applying it to synthetic data. We then apply our test to purchases of ketchup and diapers and find: (1) quality signaling is the dominant mechanism behind reference price effects in both categories; (2) consistent with the quality-signaling theory, reference price effects diminish as various measures of consumer experience increase; but (3) in both categories there are many individuals for whom price-prediction effects dominate quality-signaling effects.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
There are models of new product introduction and consumer learning in which either a low introductory price (Tirole 1992, page 111) or an inefficiently high introductory price (Bagwell and Riordan 1991) can signal high quality. In the former model, a product’s mean price increases over time, whereas in the latter, a product’s mean price decreases.
 
2
Perhaps less plausibly, quality signaling can also arise in a one-period model in which all consumers are uninformed about quality. Signaling can be sustained when firms charging higher prices signal higher quality, but have lower unit sales due to the nature of consumer tastes. This mechanism requires that firms have exogenously given quality levels and marginal costs that increase in quality.
 
3
Guadagni and Little labeled this past-purchase term as “brand loyalty.” The broader literature, however, uses brand loyalty to refer both to positive state dependence (positive past purchase feedback) and unobserved heterogeneity. As discussed by Keane (1997), our Eq. 2 is the standard operationalization of positive state dependence. We account for unobserved heterogeneity separately in our model. Hence, we do not adopt the brand loyalty label for our past-purchase (use experience) variable.
 
4
Additional discussion of the inventory variable is presented in the Appendix.
 
5
An alternative approach to updating would be to update reference prices conditional on category purchase. In addition to failing to mesh with empirical findings (see Briesch et al. 1997 for a survey of the literature), this alternative approach suffers from a lack of internal consistency. To see why, observe that, if at least some consumers buy at low prices rather than at high, this behavior suggests that households check prices when they are high as well as low. Updating reference prices only when households make purchases would underestimate the reference price.
 
6
The role of memory also merits attention in passing. Although such effects can, in theory, be important, past work has shown that they do not matter much empirically (see Briesch et al. 1997). Hence, we do not include them in our model.
 
7
Katz and Shapiro (1986) provided an early test of the information-based kinked demand theory using scanner panel data for coffee.
 
8
Erdem et al. (2003) have shown that the best model of ketchup prices is that they fluctuate around a mean while exhibiting serial correlation. Those authors assume there is no learning about the price process over time; households are assumed either to know the process exactly or not to know it all, and the former assumption fits the data better than does the latter.
 
9
In addition, this may indicate that the consumer has a high overall willingness to pay for the product (otherwise the household would have foregone purchasing entirely). This would be true under either mechanism.
 
10
Although we leave the issue for another paper, it is also worth observing that there may be other implications of the two mechanisms that could be used to determine their joint presence. For example, as shown by Hendel and Nevo (2006b), the price-expectations mechanism gives rise to certain predictions about the relationship between prices and interpurchase durations that the presence of a quality-signaling mechanism would not offset. In the present paper, we implicitly account for purchase timing by modeling purchase incidence, which is allowed to be a function of inventories, but we do not offer a full model of inventory behavior.
 
11
We also checked for situations whether zero brand sales were observed for an extended and consecutive periods of time. Although zero brand sales for few consecutive periods occur (which are usually the cases when zero sales are correlated with consumer preferences) at some stores, prolonged/extended and consecutive zero sales were very rare.
 
12
The mean prices of the excluded brands were generally less than those of Huggies and Pampers, but greater than those of Luvs and store brands. Thus, it does not appear that the excluded brands were targeted at especially price-conscious consumers.
 
13
A large number of households in our dataset purchased diapers on only one occasion, suggesting that they were making purchases for children temporarily visiting. Alternatively, although our data set covers a high percentage of stores in each city, it is possible that what appear in our sample as single-purchase households are actually households that made repeated purchases at stores outside of our sample. In any event, we exclude these households from our analysis because we have no means of measuring their experience.
 
14
After other exclusions, we lost only 16 households in Chicago and 21 households in Atlanta due to this restriction.
 
15
The median interpurchase time for ketchup was 10.45 weeks. The mean and standard deviation of interpurchase times were 12.46 weeks and 7.36 weeks, respectively.
 
16
For each estimation, we used an initialization period to set the initial values of the reference price and experience measures. Based on the distribution of interpurchase times, we used an initialization period of 21 weeks for diapers and 24 weeks for ketchup. We also tried several other period lengths, and our results were insensitive to the specific choices.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Bagwell, K., & Riordan, M. H. (1991). High and declining prices signal product quality. The American Economic Review, 81(1), 224–239. Bagwell, K., & Riordan, M. H. (1991). High and declining prices signal product quality. The American Economic Review, 81(1), 224–239.
Zurück zum Zitat Briesch, R. A., Krishnamurthi, L., Mazumdar, T., & Raj, S. P. (1997). A comparative analysis of reference price models. Journal of Consumer Research, 24(2), 202–214.CrossRef Briesch, R. A., Krishnamurthi, L., Mazumdar, T., & Raj, S. P. (1997). A comparative analysis of reference price models. Journal of Consumer Research, 24(2), 202–214.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Caves, R. E., & Greene, D. P. (1996). Brands’ quality levels, prices and advertising outlays: empirical evidence on signals and information costs. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 14(1), 29–52.CrossRef Caves, R. E., & Greene, D. P. (1996). Brands’ quality levels, prices and advertising outlays: empirical evidence on signals and information costs. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 14(1), 29–52.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Erdem, T., Imai, S., & Keane, M. (2003). A model of consumer brand and quantity choice dynamics under price uncertainty. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 1(1), 5–64.CrossRef Erdem, T., Imai, S., & Keane, M. (2003). A model of consumer brand and quantity choice dynamics under price uncertainty. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 1(1), 5–64.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Erdem, T., Keane, M., & Sun, B. (2008). A dynamic model of brand choice when price and advertising signal product quality. Marketing Science, 27(6), 1111–1125.CrossRef Erdem, T., Keane, M., & Sun, B. (2008). A dynamic model of brand choice when price and advertising signal product quality. Marketing Science, 27(6), 1111–1125.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guadagni, P. M., & Little, J. D. C. (1983). A logit model of brand choice calibrated on scanner data. Marketing Science, 2(3), 203–238.CrossRef Guadagni, P. M., & Little, J. D. C. (1983). A logit model of brand choice calibrated on scanner data. Marketing Science, 2(3), 203–238.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hendel, I., & Nevo, A. (2006a). Measuring the implications of sales and consumer inventory behavior. Econometrica, 74(6), 1637–1673.CrossRef Hendel, I., & Nevo, A. (2006a). Measuring the implications of sales and consumer inventory behavior. Econometrica, 74(6), 1637–1673.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hendel, I., & Nevo, A. (2006b). Sales and consumer inventory. The Rand Journal of Economics, 37(3), 543–561.CrossRef Hendel, I., & Nevo, A. (2006b). Sales and consumer inventory. The Rand Journal of Economics, 37(3), 543–561.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–292. Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–292.
Zurück zum Zitat Kalyanaram, G., & Little, J. D. C. (1994). An empirical analysis of latitude of price acceptance in consumer package goods. Journal of Consumer Research, 21(3), 408–418. Kalyanaram, G., & Little, J. D. C. (1994). An empirical analysis of latitude of price acceptance in consumer package goods. Journal of Consumer Research, 21(3), 408–418.
Zurück zum Zitat Kalyanaram, G., & Winer, R. S. (1995). Empirical generalizations from reference price research. Marketing Science, 14(3, Part 2), G161–G169.CrossRef Kalyanaram, G., & Winer, R. S. (1995). Empirical generalizations from reference price research. Marketing Science, 14(3, Part 2), G161–G169.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Katz, M. L., & Shapiro C. (1986). Consumer shopping behavior in the retail coffee market. In Empirical approaches to consumer protection, Federal Trade Commission. Katz, M. L., & Shapiro C. (1986). Consumer shopping behavior in the retail coffee market. In Empirical approaches to consumer protection, Federal Trade Commission.
Zurück zum Zitat Keane, M. (1993). Simulation estimation for panel data models with limited dependent variables. In G. S. Maddala, C. R. Rao & H. D. Vinod (Eds.), The handbook of statistics. Amsterdam: North Holland. Keane, M. (1993). Simulation estimation for panel data models with limited dependent variables. In G. S. Maddala, C. R. Rao & H. D. Vinod (Eds.), The handbook of statistics. Amsterdam: North Holland.
Zurück zum Zitat Keane, M. P. (1997). Modeling heterogeneity and state dependence in consumer choice behavior. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 15(3), 310–327.CrossRef Keane, M. P. (1997). Modeling heterogeneity and state dependence in consumer choice behavior. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 15(3), 310–327.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lattin, J. M., & Bucklin, R. E. (1989). Reference effects of price and promotion on brand choice behavior. Journal of Marketing Research, 26(3), 299–310. Lattin, J. M., & Bucklin, R. E. (1989). Reference effects of price and promotion on brand choice behavior. Journal of Marketing Research, 26(3), 299–310.
Zurück zum Zitat Lichtenstein, D. R., & Burton, S. (1989). The relationship between perceived and objective price-quality. Journal of Marketing Research, 26, 429–443.CrossRef Lichtenstein, D. R., & Burton, S. (1989). The relationship between perceived and objective price-quality. Journal of Marketing Research, 26, 429–443.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mayhew, G. E., & Winer, R. S. (1992). An empirical analysis of internal and external reference prices using scanner data. Journal of Consumer Research, 19, 62–70.CrossRef Mayhew, G. E., & Winer, R. S. (1992). An empirical analysis of internal and external reference prices using scanner data. Journal of Consumer Research, 19, 62–70.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mazumdar, T., & Papatla, P. (1995). Loyalty differences in the use of internal and external reference prices. Marketing Letters, 6(2), 111–122.CrossRef Mazumdar, T., & Papatla, P. (1995). Loyalty differences in the use of internal and external reference prices. Marketing Letters, 6(2), 111–122.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McFadden, D. (1974). Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice behavior. In P. Zarenmbka (Ed.), Frontiers in econometrics. New York: Academic Press. McFadden, D. (1974). Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice behavior. In P. Zarenmbka (Ed.), Frontiers in econometrics. New York: Academic Press.
Zurück zum Zitat McFadden, D. (1989). A method of simulated moments for estimation of discrete response models without numerical integration. Econometrica, 54, 1027–1058. McFadden, D. (1989). A method of simulated moments for estimation of discrete response models without numerical integration. Econometrica, 54, 1027–1058.
Zurück zum Zitat Pakes, A. (1987). Patents as options: some estimates of the value of holding european patent stocks. Econometrica, 57, 755–784. Pakes, A. (1987). Patents as options: some estimates of the value of holding european patent stocks. Econometrica, 57, 755–784.
Zurück zum Zitat Rao, A. R., & Monroe, K. B. (1989). The effect of price, brand name and store name on buyers’ perceptions of product quality: an integrative review. Journal of Marketing Research, 26, 351–357.CrossRef Rao, A. R., & Monroe, K. B. (1989). The effect of price, brand name and store name on buyers’ perceptions of product quality: an integrative review. Journal of Marketing Research, 26, 351–357.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Slonim, R., & Garbarino, E. (2009). Similarities and differences between stockpiling and reference effects. Managerial and Decision Economics, 30, 351–371.CrossRef Slonim, R., & Garbarino, E. (2009). Similarities and differences between stockpiling and reference effects. Managerial and Decision Economics, 30, 351–371.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stiglitz, J. E. (1987). The causes and consequences of the dependence of quality on price. Journal of Economic Literature, 25, 1–48. Stiglitz, J. E. (1987). The causes and consequences of the dependence of quality on price. Journal of Economic Literature, 25, 1–48.
Zurück zum Zitat Sun, B. (2005). Promotion effect on endogenous consumption. Marketing Science, 24(3), 430–443.CrossRef Sun, B. (2005). Promotion effect on endogenous consumption. Marketing Science, 24(3), 430–443.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sun, B., Neslin, S., & Srinivasan, K. (2003). Measuring the impact of promotions on brand switching under rational consumer behavior. Journal of Marketing Research, 40(4), 389–405.CrossRef Sun, B., Neslin, S., & Srinivasan, K. (2003). Measuring the impact of promotions on brand switching under rational consumer behavior. Journal of Marketing Research, 40(4), 389–405.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Thaler, R. (1985). Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science, 4(3), 199–214. Thaler, R. (1985). Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science, 4(3), 199–214.
Zurück zum Zitat Tirole, J. (1992). The theory of industrial organization (2nd ed.). Cambridge: MIT. Tirole, J. (1992). The theory of industrial organization (2nd ed.). Cambridge: MIT.
Zurück zum Zitat Winer, R. S. (1986). A reference price model of brand choice for frequently purchased products. Journal of Consumer Research, 13(2), 250–256. Winer, R. S. (1986). A reference price model of brand choice for frequently purchased products. Journal of Consumer Research, 13(2), 250–256.
Zurück zum Zitat Winer, R. S. (1988). Behavioral perspective on pricing: buyers’ subjective perceptions of price revisited. In T. Devinney (Ed.), Issues in pricing: theory and research (pp. 35–57). Lexington: Lexington Books. Winer, R. S. (1988). Behavioral perspective on pricing: buyers’ subjective perceptions of price revisited. In T. Devinney (Ed.), Issues in pricing: theory and research (pp. 35–57). Lexington: Lexington Books.
Metadaten
Titel
A simple test for distinguishing between internal reference price theories
verfasst von
Tülin Erdem
Michael L. Katz
Baohong Sun
Publikationsdatum
01.09.2010
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Quantitative Marketing and Economics / Ausgabe 3/2010
Print ISSN: 1570-7156
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-711X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-010-9087-7

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3/2010

Quantitative Marketing and Economics 3/2010 Zur Ausgabe