Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Quantitative Marketing and Economics 1/2014

01.03.2014

Competition and product innovation in dynamic oligopoly

verfasst von: Ronald L. Goettler, Brett R. Gordon

Erschienen in: Quantitative Marketing and Economics | Ausgabe 1/2014

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We investigate the relationship between competition and innovation using a dynamic oligopoly model that endogenizes both the long-run innovation rate and market structure. We use the model to examine how various determinants of competition, such as product substitutability, entry costs, and innovation spillovers, affect firms’ equilibrium strategies for entry, exit, and investment in product quality. We find an inverted-U relationship between product substitutability and innovation: the returns to innovation initially rise for all firms but eventually, as the market approaches a winner-take-all environment, laggards have few residual profits to fight over and give up pursuit of the leader, knowing he will defend his lead. The increasing portion of the inverted-U reflects changes in firm’s investment policy functions, whereas the decreasing portion arises from the industry transiting to states with fewer firms and wider quality gaps. Allowing market structure to be endogenous yields different results compared to extant work that fixes or exogenously varies the market structure.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
We define the long-run innovation rate as the average rate at which the industry’s frontier quality improves, averaged across the ergodic set of states. In Pakes and McGuire (1994), the long-run innovation rate equals the exogenous rate at which the outside good’s quality improves, as discussed in Appendix A.
 
2
To clarify our terminology, a firm is a leader if its product quality is greater than or equal to all other firms in the industry. Since multiple firms can exist at this industry frontier, there can be multiple lead firms. A laggard is any firm with a quality level strictly below the frontier product quality.
 
3
Analyses of dynamic oligopoly with differentiated products include the study of collusive pricing (Fershtman and Pakes 2000), competition among hospitals (Gowrisankaran and Town 1997), advertising dynamics (Dubé et al. 2005), and oblivious equilibrium (Weintraub et al. 2008).
 
4
Other work considers different forms of innovation spillovers. Levin and Reiss (1998) incorporate spillovers by allowing a firm’s innovation outcome to depend on the investment levels of all firms in the industry. Similarly, Kamien et al. (1992) capture innovation spillovers in the form of research joint ventures. For our purposes, the key notion behind the innovation spillover is that a laggard firm’s R&D is more efficient.
 
5
Work in endogenous growth theory also considers quality-ladder models (e.g., Grossman and Helpman 1991; Aghion and Howitt 1992) to study topics ranging from competition in international trade to optimal policies for national economic growth.
 
6
Borkovsky (2012) studies a more realistic innovation process in a dynamic quality-ladder model where firms time the release of new innovations and can stockpile successful innovations.
 
7
Although the scale of a 0, x jt , and market size M are arbitrary, we consider levels of a 0 on the order of one which implies a leader’s innovation rate will range from .1 to .9 for x values roughly spanning one to nine. We therefore think of investment (and market size) as being measured in millions to yield investment and profit levels typically observed.
 
8
Doraszelski and Satterthwaite (2010) define an investment transition function, such as f(τ | x, ω, s), as being unique investment choice (UIC) admissible if the function leads to a unique investment choice for the firm.
 
9
We choose the bound such that the outside good’s share is less than .001, so that firms’ profits would not improve much if the outside good were even further behind.
 
10
The distribution of scrap values could be a function of ω.
 
11
Iskhakov et al. (2013) examines leapfrogging behavior in the context of a dynamic duopoly model with cost-reducing investments.
 
12
We include a complementary slackness condition due to the non-negativity constraint on investment.
 
13
The averages we report in the simulations are not necessarily from the recurrent class of states. The innovation rate we report corresponds to the steady-state innovation rate if the initial state falls in the recurrent class, otherwise the measure we report is simply the average over the first 100 years.
 
14
To relate these costs to a particular industry, consider that Intel’s 2012 4th-quarter net income was $2.5 billion. Since cost estimates of semiconductor fabrication plants are typically around $3 billion, our range of entry costs seems at least plausible. For estimates of fabrication plants costs, see http://​finance.​yahoo.​com/​news/​Construction-Of-Chip-twst-2711924876.​html, http://​topics.​nytimes.​com/​top/​news/​business/​companies/​taiwan-semiconductor-manufacturing-company-ltd/​index.​html, and http://​www.​optessa.​com/​industries_​semi.​htm, all accessed on 2.8.13.
 
15
Many of our model’s parameters could be reasonably chosen, via calibration or formal estimation, using industry data. The R&D efficiency and spillover parameters, a 0 and a 1, could be estimated using data on R&D expenditures and product innovation outcomes. Quality preferences, γ, could be estimated using standard demand data or calibrated based on data from similar industries. Income can be chosen based on Census information or knowledge of the relevant consumer demographics. Under log utility, the maximum amount any firm can charge is y.
 
16
For some parameterizations, we can find equilibria with absorbing states where no firms invest. These equilibria typically either have a single leader at the frontier with multiple laggards below the entry threshold or all firms at the frontier. The laggards serve to deter potential entrants, and the leader prefers not to invest because it could induce the laggards to exit, prompting entry by new firms at a higher quality level. These parameterizations seem unrealistic and so we avoid them, in part by having scrap values that induce distant laggards to exit.
 
17
See Song (2011) for a dynamic oligopoly model of research joint ventures.
 
18
PMC = 0.78 corresponds to \(\frac {1}{\pi /\sqrt {6}}\), the inverse of the standard deviation of a logit error term. A PMC of 1.56 is therefore equivalent to doubling the coefficients on all terms in the utility function while maintaining the standard variance of the logit error.
 
19
In some markets, PMC evolves over time. When idiosyncratic shocks are perception errors about unknown product quality, PMC intensifies as consumers learn firms’ qualities. Consider the search engine market, born in the 1990’s with the sequential entry of Excite, Yahoo!, WebCrawler, Lycos, Infoseek, Altavista, Inktomi, AskJeeves, Google, MSN, Overture, and Alltheweb. Consumer uncertainty was initially high regarding search engine quality because most people lacked experience in the domain and evaluating the quality of a given query was difficult. Over time, the search engines refined their algorithms and consumers gained general experience with web-based search technologies. Four years after entering, Google led the U.S. search query market with a 29.2 % market share and now maintains its market dominance with a 65.6 % share, according to comScore. Google’s profits have soared as its competitors struggle (PCWorld 2010, Forbes 2011).
 
20
For values of 1 / σ ε < 0.3, the industry continues to fill up with an increasing number of firms (as illustrated on the left-hand side of Fig. 3d) and industry innovation continues to drop for reasons explained in this section. For values of 1 / σ ε > 1. 9, entry continues to fall (as illustrated on the right-hand side of Fig. 3d) and the industry moves closer to a persistent monopoly with industry innovation continuing to decline.
 
21
The bottom row of Fig. 5 plots the policy functions to show the absorbing states when the laggard is sufficiently far behind the leader (who is always at 30 for these plots). Figure 5d and e depicts policy functions for duopolies with high and low PMC, respectively. Figure 5f considers a triopoly to show that the presence of the third firm (at ω = 14) only has a small effect on the other two firms’ innovation policies, by comparing panel (e) to (f). Note that the leader’s higher innovation for ω 2 < 14 results from the third firm being at ω 3 = 14. When both laggards in Fig. 5f are tied at ω 2 = ω 3 = 14 or lower, neither invests. Even with low PMC, the residual profits are insufficient motivation to invest when they are far behind the leader.
 
22
To draw a comparison with the results in Aghion et al. (2005) and Goettler and Gordon (2011) conduct a comparative static in PMC in a nondurable version of their model where the laggard is at most one step behind the leader. Figure 11 of Goettler and Gordon (2011) shows that industry innovation increases in PMC and they claim the same result would hold even if the maximum quality gap between the firms is widened. That claim is correct, but only for moderate increases in the maximum quality gap. If the maximum gap is sufficiently wide that a laggard eventually gives up (as in the current paper), then innovation is decreasing in PMC because the point of giving up is reached more quickly the higher is PMC.
 
23
The industry innovation rate at an arbitrary state s equals one minus the probability that all frontier firms fail to innovate: \(1 - (1 - f\left (\tau = 1 \right |\bar {x}(s)))^{\sum _{j=1}^{J(s)} I(\omega _{j} = \bar {\omega })}\) where \(\bar {x}(s)\) is the investment by each firm at the frontier and the exponent gives the number of firms at the frontier.
 
24
(2010) does, however, find that process R&D (to lower costs) increases as import tariffs fall.
 
25
PM set λ = − 4, γ = 3, and report ω∗ = 12. However, the GAUSS code for their model (http://​www.​economics.​harvard.​edu/​faculty/​pakes/​program), uses a value of 12 for the point of concavity after scaling by 3 and shifting by − 4. The corresponding value for ω∗ on the ω grid (0, 1, 2, … ) is 16 / 3.
 
26
The positive relationship between δ and profits in PM would extend to values lower than 0.4 if we were to increase the maximum number of firms, which becomes binding at δ = 0.4 in these simulations.
 
27
For our model, we can calculate an alternative measure of consumer surplus without imposing \(\bar {\omega }_{max}\). To compute this alternative measure, we simulate the model using policy functions obtained from the model that imposes \(\bar {\omega }_{max}\) but track and use the absolute quality grid when computing consumer surplus in each period. When equilibrium in our model never yields a monopoly, the equilibrium policies are good approximations to the policies when \(\bar {\omega }_{max}\) is relaxed. When the constraint is relaxed, the difference is much greater, particularly when δ is low.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Aaker, D. (1991). Managing brand equity. New York: Free Press. Aaker, D. (1991). Managing brand equity. New York: Free Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica, 60(2), 323–351.CrossRef Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica, 60(2), 323–351.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Aghion, P., Bloom, N., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Howitt, P. (2005). Competition and innovation: an inverted-U relationship. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 701–728. Aghion, P., Bloom, N., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Howitt, P. (2005). Competition and innovation: an inverted-U relationship. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 701–728.
Zurück zum Zitat Aghion, P., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Howitt, P., Prantl, S. (2009). The effects of entry on incumbent innovation and productivity. Review of Economics and Statistics, 91(1), 20–32.CrossRef Aghion, P., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Howitt, P., Prantl, S. (2009). The effects of entry on incumbent innovation and productivity. Review of Economics and Statistics, 91(1), 20–32.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Arrow, K. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In R. Nelson (Ed.), The rate and direction of inventive activity. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Arrow, K. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In R. Nelson (Ed.), The rate and direction of inventive activity. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Berry, S., Levinsohn, J., Pakes, A. (1995). Automobile prices in market equilibrium. Econometrica, 63(4), 841–890.CrossRef Berry, S., Levinsohn, J., Pakes, A. (1995). Automobile prices in market equilibrium. Econometrica, 63(4), 841–890.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Besanko, D., Doraszelski, U., Kryukov, Y., Satterthwaite, M. (2010). Learning-by-doing, organizational forgetting, and industry dynamics. Econometrica, 78, 453–508.MathSciNetCrossRef Besanko, D., Doraszelski, U., Kryukov, Y., Satterthwaite, M. (2010). Learning-by-doing, organizational forgetting, and industry dynamics. Econometrica, 78, 453–508.MathSciNetCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bloom, N., Schankerman, M., Van Reenen, J. (2013). Identifying technology spillovers and product market rivalry. Econometrica, 81(4), 1347–1393.MathSciNetCrossRef Bloom, N., Schankerman, M., Van Reenen, J. (2013). Identifying technology spillovers and product market rivalry. Econometrica, 81(4), 1347–1393.MathSciNetCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Borkovsky, R. (2012). The timing of version releases: A dynamic duopoly model. Working paper, University of Toronto. Borkovsky, R. (2012). The timing of version releases: A dynamic duopoly model. Working paper, University of Toronto.
Zurück zum Zitat Borkovsky, R., Doraszelski, U., Kryukov, Y. (2012). A dynamic quality ladder model with entry and exit: exploring the equilibrium correspondence using the homotopy method. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 10(2), 197–229.CrossRef Borkovsky, R., Doraszelski, U., Kryukov, Y. (2012). A dynamic quality ladder model with entry and exit: exploring the equilibrium correspondence using the homotopy method. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 10(2), 197–229.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bronnenberg, B., Dubé, J.P., Mela, C., Albuquerque, P., Erdem, T., Gordon, B.R., Hanssens, D., Hitsch, G., Hong, H., Sun, B. (2008). Measuring long-run marketing effects and their implications for long-run marketing decisions. Marketing Letters, 19, 367–382.CrossRef Bronnenberg, B., Dubé, J.P., Mela, C., Albuquerque, P., Erdem, T., Gordon, B.R., Hanssens, D., Hitsch, G., Hong, H., Sun, B. (2008). Measuring long-run marketing effects and their implications for long-run marketing decisions. Marketing Letters, 19, 367–382.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Caplin, A., & Nalebuff, B. (1991). Aggregation and imperfect competition: on the existence of equilibrium. Econometrica, 59, 25–59.MathSciNetCrossRef Caplin, A., & Nalebuff, B. (1991). Aggregation and imperfect competition: on the existence of equilibrium. Econometrica, 59, 25–59.MathSciNetCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chen, Y., & Schwartz, M. (2010). Product innovation incentives: Monopoly vs. Competition. Working paper, Georgetown University. Chen, Y., & Schwartz, M. (2010). Product innovation incentives: Monopoly vs. Competition. Working paper, Georgetown University.
Zurück zum Zitat Cohen, W.M. (1995). Empirical studies of innovative activity. In P. Stoneman (Ed.), Handbook of the economics of innovation and technological change. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers. Cohen, W.M. (1995). Empirical studies of innovative activity. In P. Stoneman (Ed.), Handbook of the economics of innovation and technological change. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.
Zurück zum Zitat Cohen, W.M., & Levin, R. (1989). Empirical studies of innovation and market structure. In R. Schmalensee & R. Willig (Eds.), Handbook of industrial organization (vol. 2, pp. 1059–1107). Amsterdam: North-Holland. Cohen, W.M., & Levin, R. (1989). Empirical studies of innovation and market structure. In R. Schmalensee & R. Willig (Eds.), Handbook of industrial organization (vol. 2, pp. 1059–1107). Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Zurück zum Zitat Cohen, W.M., & Levinthal, D.A. (1989). The implications of Spillovers for R&D investment and welfare: a new perspective. In A. Link & K. Smith (Eds.), Advances in applied micro-economics, Vol. 5: The factors affecting technological change. Greenwich: JAI Press. Cohen, W.M., & Levinthal, D.A. (1989). The implications of Spillovers for R&D investment and welfare: a new perspective. In A. Link & K. Smith (Eds.), Advances in applied micro-economics, Vol. 5: The factors affecting technological change. Greenwich: JAI Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Dasgupta, P., & Stiglitz, J. (1980). Industrial structure and the nature of innovative activity. Economic Journal, 90(358), 266–293.CrossRef Dasgupta, P., & Stiglitz, J. (1980). Industrial structure and the nature of innovative activity. Economic Journal, 90(358), 266–293.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Day, G. (1994). The capabilities of market-driven organizations. Journal of Marketing, 58, 37–52.CrossRef Day, G. (1994). The capabilities of market-driven organizations. Journal of Marketing, 58, 37–52.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Doraszelski, U. (2003). An R&D race with knowledge accumulation. RAND Journal of Economics, 34(1), 19–41.CrossRef Doraszelski, U. (2003). An R&D race with knowledge accumulation. RAND Journal of Economics, 34(1), 19–41.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Doraszelski, U., & Satterthwaite, M. (2010). Computable Markov-perfect industry dynamics. RAND Journal of Economics, 41(2), 215–243.MathSciNetCrossRef Doraszelski, U., & Satterthwaite, M. (2010). Computable Markov-perfect industry dynamics. RAND Journal of Economics, 41(2), 215–243.MathSciNetCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dubé, J.P., Hitsch, G., Manchanda, P. (2005). An empirical model of advertising dynamics. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 3, 107–144.CrossRef Dubé, J.P., Hitsch, G., Manchanda, P. (2005). An empirical model of advertising dynamics. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 3, 107–144.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dutta, S., Narasimhan, O., Rajiv, S. (1999). Success in high-technology markets: is marketing capability critical. Marketing Science, 18(4), 547–568.CrossRef Dutta, S., Narasimhan, O., Rajiv, S. (1999). Success in high-technology markets: is marketing capability critical. Marketing Science, 18(4), 547–568.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ericson, S., & Pakes, A. (1995). Markov-perfect industry dynamics: a framework for empirical work. Review of Economic Studies, 62(1), 53–82.CrossRef Ericson, S., & Pakes, A. (1995). Markov-perfect industry dynamics: a framework for empirical work. Review of Economic Studies, 62(1), 53–82.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fershtman, C., & Pakes, A. (2000). A dynamic oligopoly with collusion and price wars. RAND Journal of Economics, 31(2), 207–236.CrossRef Fershtman, C., & Pakes, A. (2000). A dynamic oligopoly with collusion and price wars. RAND Journal of Economics, 31(2), 207–236.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gilbert, R. (2006). Looking for Mr. Schumpeter: where are we in the competition-innovation debate? In A. Jaffe, J. Lerner, S. Stern (Eds.), Innovation policy and the economy (vol. 6). Gilbert, R. (2006). Looking for Mr. Schumpeter: where are we in the competition-innovation debate? In A. Jaffe, J. Lerner, S. Stern (Eds.), Innovation policy and the economy (vol. 6).
Zurück zum Zitat Gilbert, R., & Newbery, D.M. (1982). Preemptive patenting and the persistence of monopoly. American Economic Review, 72, 514–526. Gilbert, R., & Newbery, D.M. (1982). Preemptive patenting and the persistence of monopoly. American Economic Review, 72, 514–526.
Zurück zum Zitat Goettler, R.L., & Gordon, B.R. (2011). Does AMD Spur intel to innovate more? Journal of Political Economy, 119(6), 1141–1200.CrossRef Goettler, R.L., & Gordon, B.R. (2011). Does AMD Spur intel to innovate more? Journal of Political Economy, 119(6), 1141–1200.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gowrisankaran, G., & Town, R.J. (1997). Dynamic equilibrium in the hospital industry. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 6(1), 45–74.CrossRef Gowrisankaran, G., & Town, R.J. (1997). Dynamic equilibrium in the hospital industry. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 6(1), 45–74.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Greenstein, S., & Ramey, G. (1998). Market structure, innovation, and vertical product differentiation. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 16, 285–311.CrossRef Greenstein, S., & Ramey, G. (1998). Market structure, innovation, and vertical product differentiation. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 16, 285–311.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Griliches, Z. (1998). The search for R&D Spillovers. In R&D and productivity: The econometric evidence. University of Chicago Press. Griliches, Z. (1998). The search for R&D Spillovers. In R&D and productivity: The econometric evidence. University of Chicago Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman, G.M., & Helpman, E. (1991). Quality ladders in the theory of growth. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 43–61.CrossRef Grossman, G.M., & Helpman, E. (1991). Quality ladders in the theory of growth. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 43–61.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Han, J., & Kim, N. (2001). Entry barriers: A Dull-, One-, or two-edged sword for incumbents? Unraveling the paradox from a contingency perspective. Journal of Marketing, 65(1), 1–14.CrossRef Han, J., & Kim, N. (2001). Entry barriers: A Dull-, One-, or two-edged sword for incumbents? Unraveling the paradox from a contingency perspective. Journal of Marketing, 65(1), 1–14.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hof, R.D. (2011). Lessons from Sematech. Technology Review. Published by MIT, 25 July. Hof, R.D. (2011). Lessons from Sematech. Technology Review. Published by MIT, 25 July.
Zurück zum Zitat Iskhakov, F., Rust, J., Schjerning, B. (2013). The dynamics of Bertrand price competition with cost-reducing investments. Working paper, Georgetown University. Iskhakov, F., Rust, J., Schjerning, B. (2013). The dynamics of Bertrand price competition with cost-reducing investments. Working paper, Georgetown University.
Zurück zum Zitat Kamien, M.I., Muller, E., Zang, I. (1992). Research joint ventures and R&D cartels. American Economic Review, 82(5), 1293–1306. Kamien, M.I., Muller, E., Zang, I. (1992). Research joint ventures and R&D cartels. American Economic Review, 82(5), 1293–1306.
Zurück zum Zitat Karakaya, F., & Stahl, M.J. (1989). Barriers to entry and market entry decisions in consumer and industrial goods markets. Journal of Marketing, 53(2), 80–91.CrossRef Karakaya, F., & Stahl, M.J. (1989). Barriers to entry and market entry decisions in consumer and industrial goods markets. Journal of Marketing, 53(2), 80–91.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Khanna, T. (1995). Racing behavior technological evolution in the high-end computer industry. Research Policy, 24, 933–958.CrossRef Khanna, T. (1995). Racing behavior technological evolution in the high-end computer industry. Research Policy, 24, 933–958.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Klemperer, P. (1995). Competition when consumers have switching costs: An overview with applications to industrial organization, macroeconomics, and international trade. Review of Economic Studies, 62(4), 515–539.CrossRef Klemperer, P. (1995). Competition when consumers have switching costs: An overview with applications to industrial organization, macroeconomics, and international trade. Review of Economic Studies, 62(4), 515–539.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lee, T., & Wilde, L. (1980). Market structure and innovation: A reformulation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94, 429–436.CrossRef Lee, T., & Wilde, L. (1980). Market structure and innovation: A reformulation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94, 429–436.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lerner, J. (1997). An empirical exploration of a technology race. RAND Journal of Economics, 28, 228–247.CrossRef Lerner, J. (1997). An empirical exploration of a technology race. RAND Journal of Economics, 28, 228–247.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Levin, R.C., & Reiss, P.C. (1998). Cost-reducing and demand-creating R&D with Spillovers. RAND Journal of Economics, 19(4), 538–556.CrossRef Levin, R.C., & Reiss, P.C. (1998). Cost-reducing and demand-creating R&D with Spillovers. RAND Journal of Economics, 19(4), 538–556.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Levin, R.C., Cohen, W.M., Mowery, D.C. (1985). R&D appropriability, opportunity, and market structure: New evidence on some schumpeterian hypotheses. American Economic Review, 75(2), 20–24. Levin, R.C., Cohen, W.M., Mowery, D.C. (1985). R&D appropriability, opportunity, and market structure: New evidence on some schumpeterian hypotheses. American Economic Review, 75(2), 20–24.
Zurück zum Zitat Levin, R.C., Klevorick, A.K., Nelson, R.R., Winter, S.G. (1987). Appropriating the returns from industrial research and development. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3, 783–831.CrossRef Levin, R.C., Klevorick, A.K., Nelson, R.R., Winter, S.G. (1987). Appropriating the returns from industrial research and development. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3, 783–831.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Loury, G. (1979). Market structure and innovation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 93, 395–410.CrossRef Loury, G. (1979). Market structure and innovation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 93, 395–410.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nickell, S. (1996). Competition and corporate performance. Journal of Political Economy, 104, 724–746.CrossRef Nickell, S. (1996). Competition and corporate performance. Journal of Political Economy, 104, 724–746.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ofek, E., & Sarvary, M. (2003). R&D, marketing, and the success of next-generation products. Marketing Science, 22(3), 355–370.CrossRef Ofek, E., & Sarvary, M. (2003). R&D, marketing, and the success of next-generation products. Marketing Science, 22(3), 355–370.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pakes, A., & McGuire, P. (1994). Computing Markov-perfect Nash equilibria: Numerical implications of a dynamic differentiated product model. RAND Journal of Economics, 25(4), 555–589.CrossRef Pakes, A., & McGuire, P. (1994). Computing Markov-perfect Nash equilibria: Numerical implications of a dynamic differentiated product model. RAND Journal of Economics, 25(4), 555–589.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Reinganum, J. (1983). Uncertain innovation and the persistence of monopoly. American Economic Review, 73(4), 741–748. Reinganum, J. (1983). Uncertain innovation and the persistence of monopoly. American Economic Review, 73(4), 741–748.
Zurück zum Zitat Reuters (2011). Goldman cuts intel to sell as supply glut looms, shares fall, May 19, accessed on 10/24/2013 at www.reuters.com/article/2011/05/19/us-intel-research-goldman-idUSTRE74I4 T120110519. Reuters (2011). Goldman cuts intel to sell as supply glut looms, shares fall, May 19, accessed on 10/24/2013 at www.reuters.com/article/2011/05/19/us-intel-research-goldman-idUSTRE74I4 T120110519.
Zurück zum Zitat Scherer, F. (1967). Market structure and the employment of scientists and engineers. American Economic Review, 57, 524–531. Scherer, F. (1967). Market structure and the employment of scientists and engineers. American Economic Review, 57, 524–531.
Zurück zum Zitat Schumpeter, J. (1942). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. New York: Harper. Schumpeter, J. (1942). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. New York: Harper.
Zurück zum Zitat Soberman, D., & Gatignon, H. (2005). Research issues at the boundary of competitive dynamics and marketing evolution. Marketing Science, 24(1), 165–174.CrossRef Soberman, D., & Gatignon, H. (2005). Research issues at the boundary of competitive dynamics and marketing evolution. Marketing Science, 24(1), 165–174.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Song, M. (2011). A dynamic analysis of cooperative research in the semiconductor industry. International Economic Review, 52(4), 1157–1177.MathSciNetCrossRef Song, M. (2011). A dynamic analysis of cooperative research in the semiconductor industry. International Economic Review, 52(4), 1157–1177.MathSciNetCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sutton, J. (1991). Sunk cost and market structure: Price competition, advertising, and the evolution of concentration. Cambridge: MIT Press. Sutton, J. (1991). Sunk cost and market structure: Price competition, advertising, and the evolution of concentration. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Teshima, K. (2010). Import competition and innovation at the plant level: Evidence from Mexico. Working paper, Instituto Tecnologico Autonomo de Mexico. Teshima, K. (2010). Import competition and innovation at the plant level: Evidence from Mexico. Working paper, Instituto Tecnologico Autonomo de Mexico.
Zurück zum Zitat The New Yorker (2006). Deal sweeteners by James Surowiecki, 27 November. The New Yorker (2006). Deal sweeteners by James Surowiecki, 27 November.
Zurück zum Zitat The New Yorker (2007). Running on fumes by Elizabeth Kolbert, 5 November. The New Yorker (2007). Running on fumes by Elizabeth Kolbert, 5 November.
Zurück zum Zitat Vives, X. (2008). Innovation and competitive pressure. Journal of Industrial Economics, 56(3), 419–469.CrossRef Vives, X. (2008). Innovation and competitive pressure. Journal of Industrial Economics, 56(3), 419–469.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Weintraub, G.Y., Benkard, C.L., Van Roy, B. (2008). Markov perfect industry dynamics with many firms. Econometrica, 76(6), 1375–1411.MathSciNetCrossRef Weintraub, G.Y., Benkard, C.L., Van Roy, B. (2008). Markov perfect industry dynamics with many firms. Econometrica, 76(6), 1375–1411.MathSciNetCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wernerfelt, B. (1984). A resource based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 5(2), 171–180.CrossRef Wernerfelt, B. (1984). A resource based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 5(2), 171–180.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Competition and product innovation in dynamic oligopoly
verfasst von
Ronald L. Goettler
Brett R. Gordon
Publikationsdatum
01.03.2014
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Quantitative Marketing and Economics / Ausgabe 1/2014
Print ISSN: 1570-7156
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-711X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-013-9142-2