Skip to main content
Erschienen in: The Review of International Organizations 3/2010

01.09.2010

The World Trade Organization at work: Performance in a member-driven milieu

verfasst von: Manfred Elsig

Erschienen in: The Review of International Organizations | Ausgabe 3/2010

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This article discusses performance in the context of the World Trade Organization (WTO). Applying the framework by Gutner and Thompson and inspired by principal-agent theory, it is argued that existing studies have underspecified the institutional milieu that affects performance. The WTO represents a member-driven organization where Members are part of the international organization (IO) (e.g., through rule-making) and at the same time act outside the IO (e.g., through implementation). Thus, a narrow reading of the IO (focusing on the civil servants and the Director-General and his staff) will not suffice to understand IO performance in the WTO context. Selected evidence is presented to illustrate aspects of the WTO’s inner-working and the institutional milieu of performance. In addition, the article discusses a number of performance parameters, including the relationship between Secretariat autonomy and performance, the role of information, and the mechanisms of performance aggregation. The article ends by cautioning against quick fixes to the system to improve performance.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
These include the 4th protocol on basic telecommunication and 5th protocol on financial services.
 
2
Milieu is understood here predominantly within a rationalist perspective.
 
3
It is important to stress that trade rounds produced unequal welfare effects across and within countries. In addition, the focus on the cooperation problems has shifted over time from negative integration (e.g., tariff reductions, tackling protectionism in agricultural markets, offsetting unilateralism) to positive integration (e.g., compatible technical regulations, the protection of intellectual property rights, stronger dispute settlement).
 
4
There have been many critical studies focusing on welfare transfer from the South to the North resulting from the Uruguay Round, e.g., Finger and Nogués (2002).
 
5
Examples include case studies on the negotiations that brought about a public health related opt-out from the Agreement on Trade-related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS), e.g., Drezner (2007).
 
6
Some recent work on capacity constraints combines process and output measures; see for instance Busch et al. (2008).
 
7
For an overview on economic, international relations and legal explanations for the need of a multilateral trade institution, see World Trade Report (World Trade Organization 2007).
 
8
Recognizing that their relations (…) should be conducted with a view to raising standards of living, ensuring full employment and a large and steadily growing volume of real income and effective demand (…) and expanding the production and exchange of goods; being desirous of contributing to these objectives by entering into reciprocal and mutually advantageous arrangements directed to the substantial reduction of tariffs and other barriers to trade and to the elimination of discriminatory treatment in international commerce (www.​wto.​org).
 
9
Recognizing further that there is a need (…) to ensure that developing countries, and especially the least developed among them, secure a share in the growth in international trade (…) (www.​wto.​org).
 
10
Many studies also suggest that trade liberalization has occurred mainly in unilateral terms or in the regional context, but less through the WTO (World Bank 2005).
 
11
The MFN norm calls for non-discrimination between one’s trading partners. Various MFN exceptions exist, e.g., the enabling clause for a special treatment of developing countries, Art XXIV on regionalism, the long-used practice of providing “waivers” for “temporal” non-compliance, etc.
 
12
The national treatment norm stipulates that foreign produced goods cannot be discriminated against once they have entered the country (for example, an excise tax applicable only to imported goods would be illegal).
 
13
A key concern for Japan during the Uruguay Round in the area of the dispute settlement system was to tame US unilateralism, Interview with a former Japanese trade negotiator, 21 May 2010.
 
14
The WTO has moved towards addressing non-tariff barriers, trade-related concerns (e.g., investment, competition) and non-trade concerns (e.g., human rights, environment, and development).
 
15
I focus on formal PARs, where the principals can delegate, control and sanction based on a “contract.”
 
16
Between Ministerial Conferences more restricted circles where only a handful of ministers may participate are used in an attempt to unblock negotiations.
 
17
In 2009, 20 Members of the WTO lacked direct representation through a Geneva-based ambassador.
 
18
Interview with a former ambassador and Chair of the General Council and the DSB, 17 June 2010.
 
19
In case of conflict over appointing panelists, the DG holds a special right to force selection.
 
20
Re-appointment of a panelist is influenced by external factors (the disputing parties accept the expert) and by internal factors (the panelist is perceived as a team player and is not acting too “autonomously”), see also Shoyer (2003), and Davey (2003).
 
21
Other authors attribute a trustee position to the AB (e.g., Alter 2008); see also Grant and Keohane (2005).
 
22
As AB members are subject to a re-appointment procedure there exists after 4 years an ex post control tool for Members.
 
23
The 1994 Agreement Establishing the WTO (Article VI) reads: 1.There shall be a Secretariat of the WTO (...) headed by a Director-General; 2. The Ministerial Conference shall appoint the Director-General and adopt regulations setting out the powers, duties, conditions of service and term of office of the Director-General; 3. The Director-General shall appoint the members of the staff of the Secretariat and determine their duties and conditions of service in accordance with regulations adopted by the Ministerial Conference; 4. The responsibilities of the Director-General and of the staff of the Secretariat shall be exclusively international in character. In the discharge of their duties, the Director-General and the staff of the Secretariat shall not seek or accept instructions from any government or any other authority external to the WTO (...).
 
24
See procedures to appoint the DG, Doc WT/L/509, 20 January 2003, http://​docsonline.​wto.​org/​DDFDocuments/​t/​WT/​L/​509.​doc.​
 
25
It is not unusual for PPs to try to pressure the DG to appoint specific candidates, interview with a former DG, 8 November 2007.
 
26
The focus is on the Secretariat as it is involved in the four areas defined.
 
27
On the role of the Secretariat in negotiations, see Elsig (2010).
 
28
Yet, the TNC operates under the authority of the General Council (the most important Committee composed of PPs).
 
29
While the AB members are selected by the Members, the AB Secretariat is selected by the DG (in consultation with the AB members), e-mail exchange with an AB member, 3 July 2010.
 
30
Weiler continues: “Like in Freud’s dream theory certain things just have to come out. The views of the Secretariat as to the proper outcome of a dispute will, thus, come out and more invidiously will be consciously and subconsciously pushed upon the Panel” (2001: 205).
 
31
The DG is increasingly involved in the selection process, as parties do not accept proposed panelists.
 
32
Members have substantial influence as they take the decision to launch a case and in most cases attempt to find a solution prior to the start of litigation. In addition, for many WTO Members the role of the private sector is pivotal for litigation (see Shaffer 2003).
 
33
See Footer (2006) for an overview of different Committees.
 
34
Interview with senior WTO official, 31 January 2007.
 
35
However, the WTO is only one player among many in providing trade-related technical assistance and capacity building. A growing number of intergovernmental organizations (e.g., South Centre, Commonwealth Secretariat) and non-governmental organizations offer their services to developing countries. In addition, the WTO joins forces and collaborates in capacity building with other organizations. The WTO participates in various inter-agency efforts, including Aid for Trade, the Enhanced Integrated Framework, and Trade Facilitation. The WTO often plays an “orchestrating” role in this area; see Abbott and Snidal (2010).
 
36
Interview with senior WTO official, 31 January 2007.
 
37
As tasks within the WTO are situated alongside the performance metrics continuum (see Figure 1 in Gutner and Thompson 2010), it is difficult to compare the performance across activities.
 
38
Interview with senior WTO official, 29 January 2007.
 
39
Notice to the staff on the Evaluation Methodology for Monitoring and Evaluating the Technical Assistance Activities (Office(02)40).
 
40
The mandate (terms of reference: TOR) focused on assessing the WTO’s comparative advantage vis-à-vis other agencies, the relevance for participants, the efficiency and management of the overall training and technical assistance, Strategic Review of WTO-provided Training and Technical Assistance (TRTA), WT/COMTD/W/152 and WT/COMTD/W/153.
 
41
The suggestion to outsource is not surprising given the interests of the organizations which evaluators represented.
 
42
“Evaluations” of these activities quickly turn political and are mainly done by insiders of the system (e.g., negotiations among Members to change decision-making rules, reforming dispute settlement).
 
43
The Secretariat is closely watched by the PPs to make sure that it doesn’t engage in simulation exercises on expected effects of regulatory changes on trade flows and national welfare. Simulations are mainly carried out by Members and the results are usually not shared among contracting parties.
 
44
There exists a related argument on the effects of increased legalization and de facto greater transparency in the WTO. This in turn empowers import-competing groups and reduces Members’ ambitions to engage in further liberalization through the WTO (Goldstein and Martin 2000).
 
45
A recent evaluation that also included an assessment of decision-making processes was mandated by former DG Supachai Panitchpakdi (Sutherland et al. 2004). Yet, PPs did not pay much attention to the report.
 
46
A special problem in WTO-sponsored workshops and training activities relates to job fluctuations among participants. A significant number of workshop participants leave government or move within governmental departments following their training. This affects the overall impact of technical assistance related to trade policy.
 
47
While it may seem counterintuitive, some AB members feel unease because their decisions cannot easily be overturned by member states due to existing high thresholds for re-interpreting AB recommendations or for creating new rules and obligations following consensual decision-making procedure. This situation places enormous responsibility on their shoulders (see Pollack 2007: 7).
 
48
The single undertaking principle means that nothing is agreed until everything is agreed. This approach ties together a diverse set of negotiation issues, excludes early harvest of agreed negotiation outcomes, and makes a final (package) agreement only possible if it is acceptable to all Members.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Abbott, K. W., & Snidal, D. (2010). International regulation without international government: improving IO performance through orchestration. Review of International Organizations, 5(3). Abbott, K. W., & Snidal, D. (2010). International regulation without international government: improving IO performance through orchestration. Review of International Organizations, 5(3).
Zurück zum Zitat Alter, K. (2008). Agents or trustees? International courts in their political context. European Journal of International Relations, 14(1), 33–63.CrossRef Alter, K. (2008). Agents or trustees? International courts in their political context. European Journal of International Relations, 14(1), 33–63.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blackhurst, R. (1998). The capacity of the WTO to fulfill its mandate. In A. Krueger (Ed.), The WTO as an international organization. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Blackhurst, R. (1998). The capacity of the WTO to fulfill its mandate. In A. Krueger (Ed.), The WTO as an international organization. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Bown, C. (2009). Self-enforcing trade. Developing countries and WTO dispute settlement. Washington DC: Brookings. Bown, C. (2009). Self-enforcing trade. Developing countries and WTO dispute settlement. Washington DC: Brookings.
Zurück zum Zitat Bown, C., & Hoekman, B. (2008). Developing countries and enforcement of trade agreements: why dispute settlement is not enough. Journal of World Trade, 42(1), 177–203. Bown, C., & Hoekman, B. (2008). Developing countries and enforcement of trade agreements: why dispute settlement is not enough. Journal of World Trade, 42(1), 177–203.
Zurück zum Zitat Busch, M., & Reinhardt, E. (2002). Testing international trade law: Empirical studies of GATT/WTO dispute settlement. In D. Kennedy & J. Southwick (Eds.), The political economy of international trade law: Essays in honor of Robert E. Hudec. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Busch, M., & Reinhardt, E. (2002). Testing international trade law: Empirical studies of GATT/WTO dispute settlement. In D. Kennedy & J. Southwick (Eds.), The political economy of international trade law: Essays in honor of Robert E. Hudec. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Busch, M., Reinhardt, E., & Shaffer, G. (2008). Does legal capacity matter? Explaining dispute initiation and antidumping actions in the WTO. ICTSD Programme on Dispute Settlement. Issue Paper 4. Busch, M., Reinhardt, E., & Shaffer, G. (2008). Does legal capacity matter? Explaining dispute initiation and antidumping actions in the WTO. ICTSD Programme on Dispute Settlement. Issue Paper 4.
Zurück zum Zitat Cottier, T., & Takenoshita, S. (2003). The balance of power in WTO decision-making: towards weighted voting in legislative response. Aussenwirtschaft, 58(2), 171–214. Cottier, T., & Takenoshita, S. (2003). The balance of power in WTO decision-making: towards weighted voting in legislative response. Aussenwirtschaft, 58(2), 171–214.
Zurück zum Zitat Croome, J. (1995). Reshaping the world trading system. Geneva: WTO. Croome, J. (1995). Reshaping the world trading system. Geneva: WTO.
Zurück zum Zitat Davey, W. (2003). The case for a WTO permanent panel body. Journal of International Economic Law, 6(1), 177–186.CrossRef Davey, W. (2003). The case for a WTO permanent panel body. Journal of International Economic Law, 6(1), 177–186.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Davey, W. (2005). The Sutherland Report on dispute settlement: a comment. Journal of International Economic Law, 8(2), 321–328.CrossRef Davey, W. (2005). The Sutherland Report on dispute settlement: a comment. Journal of International Economic Law, 8(2), 321–328.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner, D. (2007). All politics is global: Explaining international regulatory regimes. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Drezner, D. (2007). All politics is global: Explaining international regulatory regimes. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Ehring, L. (2008). Public access to dispute settlement hearings in the World Trade Organization. Journal of International Economic Law, 11(4), 1021–1034.CrossRef Ehring, L. (2008). Public access to dispute settlement hearings in the World Trade Organization. Journal of International Economic Law, 11(4), 1021–1034.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Elsig, M. (2007a). The World Trade Organization’s legitimacy crisis: what does the beast look like? Journal of World Trade, 41(1), 75–98. Elsig, M. (2007a). The World Trade Organization’s legitimacy crisis: what does the beast look like? Journal of World Trade, 41(1), 75–98.
Zurück zum Zitat Elsig, M. (2007b). The EU’s choice of regulatory venues for trade negotiations: a tale of agency power? Journal of Common Market Studies, 45(4), 927–948.CrossRef Elsig, M. (2007b). The EU’s choice of regulatory venues for trade negotiations: a tale of agency power? Journal of Common Market Studies, 45(4), 927–948.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Elsig, M. (2010). Principal-agent theory and the World Trade Organization: complex agency and “missing delegation”. European Journal of International Relations, forthcoming. Elsig, M. (2010). Principal-agent theory and the World Trade Organization: complex agency and “missing delegation”. European Journal of International Relations, forthcoming.
Zurück zum Zitat Elsig, M., & Cottier, T. (2011). Reforming the WTO: The decision-making triangle revisited. In T. Cottier & M. Elsig (Eds.), Governing the World Trade Organization: Past, present and beyond Doha. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Elsig, M., & Cottier, T. (2011). Reforming the WTO: The decision-making triangle revisited. In T. Cottier & M. Elsig (Eds.), Governing the World Trade Organization: Past, present and beyond Doha. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Elsig, M., & Pollack, M. (2010). Agents or trustees? Nomination and appointment of judicial candidates in the WTO Appellate Body. Manuscript. Elsig, M., & Pollack, M. (2010). Agents or trustees? Nomination and appointment of judicial candidates in the WTO Appellate Body. Manuscript.
Zurück zum Zitat Fearon, J. (1998). Bargaining, enforcement and international cooperation. International Organization, 52(2), 269–306.CrossRef Fearon, J. (1998). Bargaining, enforcement and international cooperation. International Organization, 52(2), 269–306.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Finger, M., & Nogués, J. (2002). The unbalanced Uruguay Round outcome: the new areas in future WTO negotiations. World Economy, 25(3), 321–340.CrossRef Finger, M., & Nogués, J. (2002). The unbalanced Uruguay Round outcome: the new areas in future WTO negotiations. World Economy, 25(3), 321–340.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Footer, M. (2006). An institutional and normative analysis of the World Trade Organization. Leiden: Martinus Nijhoff Publishers.CrossRef Footer, M. (2006). An institutional and normative analysis of the World Trade Organization. Leiden: Martinus Nijhoff Publishers.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goldstein, J., & Martin, L. (2000). Legalization, trade liberalization, and domestic politics: a cautionary note. International Organization, 54(3), 603–632.CrossRef Goldstein, J., & Martin, L. (2000). Legalization, trade liberalization, and domestic politics: a cautionary note. International Organization, 54(3), 603–632.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goldstein, J., Rivers, D., & Tomz, M. (2007). Institutions in international relations: understanding the effects of the GATT and WTO on world trade. International Organization, 61(1), 37–67.CrossRef Goldstein, J., Rivers, D., & Tomz, M. (2007). Institutions in international relations: understanding the effects of the GATT and WTO on world trade. International Organization, 61(1), 37–67.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grant, R., & Keohane, R. (2005). Accountability and abuses of power in world politics. American Political Science Review, 99(1), 29–43.CrossRef Grant, R., & Keohane, R. (2005). Accountability and abuses of power in world politics. American Political Science Review, 99(1), 29–43.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gruber, L. (2000). Ruling the world: Power politics and the role of supranational institutions. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Gruber, L. (2000). Ruling the world: Power politics and the role of supranational institutions. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Gutner, T. (2005). Explaining the gaps between mandate and performance: agency theory and World Bank environmental reform. Global Environmental Politics, 5(2), 10–37.CrossRef Gutner, T. (2005). Explaining the gaps between mandate and performance: agency theory and World Bank environmental reform. Global Environmental Politics, 5(2), 10–37.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gutner, T., & Thompson, A. (2010). The politics of IO performance: a framework. Review of International Organizations, 5(3). Gutner, T., & Thompson, A. (2010). The politics of IO performance: a framework. Review of International Organizations, 5(3).
Zurück zum Zitat Guzman, A., & Simmons, B. (2005). Power plays and capacity constraints: the selection of defendants in WTO disputes. Journal of Legal Studies, 34(2), 557–598.CrossRef Guzman, A., & Simmons, B. (2005). Power plays and capacity constraints: the selection of defendants in WTO disputes. Journal of Legal Studies, 34(2), 557–598.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hawkins, D., Lake, D., Nielson, D., & Tierney, M. (Eds.). (2006). Delegation and agency in international organizations. New York: Cambridge University Press. Hawkins, D., Lake, D., Nielson, D., & Tierney, M. (Eds.). (2006). Delegation and agency in international organizations. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Horn, H., & Mavroidis, P. (2008). The WTO dispute settlement system 1995–2006: Some descriptive statistics. Washington DC: World Bank. Horn, H., & Mavroidis, P. (2008). The WTO dispute settlement system 1995–2006: Some descriptive statistics. Washington DC: World Bank.
Zurück zum Zitat Ismail, F. (2009). The role of the chair in the WTO negotiations from the Potsdam collapse in June 2007 to July 2008. Journal of World Trade, 43(6), 1145–1171. Ismail, F. (2009). The role of the chair in the WTO negotiations from the Potsdam collapse in June 2007 to July 2008. Journal of World Trade, 43(6), 1145–1171.
Zurück zum Zitat Kim, M. (2008). Costly procedures: divergent effects of legalization in the GATT/WTO dispute settlement procedures. International Studies Quarterly, 52(3), 657–686.CrossRef Kim, M. (2008). Costly procedures: divergent effects of legalization in the GATT/WTO dispute settlement procedures. International Studies Quarterly, 52(3), 657–686.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Krasner, S. (Ed.). (1983). International regimes. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Krasner, S. (Ed.). (1983). International regimes. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Lipson, M. (2010). Performance under ambiguity: international organization performance in UN peacekeeping. Review of International Organizations, 5(3). Lipson, M. (2010). Performance under ambiguity: international organization performance in UN peacekeeping. Review of International Organizations, 5(3).
Zurück zum Zitat Narlikar, A. (2003). International trade and developing countries: Coalitions in the GATT and WTO. London: Routledge. Narlikar, A. (2003). International trade and developing countries: Coalitions in the GATT and WTO. London: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Nielson, D., & Tierney, M. (2003). Delegation to international organizations: agency theory and World Bank environmental reform. International Organization, 57(2), 241–276.CrossRef Nielson, D., & Tierney, M. (2003). Delegation to international organizations: agency theory and World Bank environmental reform. International Organization, 57(2), 241–276.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Odell, J. (2005). Chairing a WTO negotiation. Journal of International Economic Law, 8(2), 425–448.CrossRef Odell, J. (2005). Chairing a WTO negotiation. Journal of International Economic Law, 8(2), 425–448.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ostry, S. (2002). The Uruguay Round north-south grand bargain: Implications for future negotiations. In D. Kennedy & J. Southwick (Eds.), The political economy of international trade law, essays in honor of Robert E. Hudec. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Ostry, S. (2002). The Uruguay Round north-south grand bargain: Implications for future negotiations. In D. Kennedy & J. Southwick (Eds.), The political economy of international trade law, essays in honor of Robert E. Hudec. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Pollack, M. (2007). Principal-agent analysis and international delegation: red herrings, theoretical clarifications, and empirical disputes. Bruges Political Research Papers No 2. Pollack, M. (2007). Principal-agent analysis and international delegation: red herrings, theoretical clarifications, and empirical disputes. Bruges Political Research Papers No 2.
Zurück zum Zitat Rose, A. (2004). Do we really know that the WTO increased trade? The American Economic Review, 94(1), 98–114.CrossRef Rose, A. (2004). Do we really know that the WTO increased trade? The American Economic Review, 94(1), 98–114.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ruggie, J. (1982). International regimes, transactions, and change: embedded liberalism in the postwar economic order. International Organization, 36(2), 379–415.CrossRef Ruggie, J. (1982). International regimes, transactions, and change: embedded liberalism in the postwar economic order. International Organization, 36(2), 379–415.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sattler, T., & Bernauer, T. (2010). Gravitation or discrimination? Determinants of litigation in the World Trade Organization. European Journal of Political Research, forthcoming. Sattler, T., & Bernauer, T. (2010). Gravitation or discrimination? Determinants of litigation in the World Trade Organization. European Journal of Political Research, forthcoming.
Zurück zum Zitat Shaffer, G. (2003). Defending interests: Public-private partnerships in W.T.O. litigation. Washington DC: Brookings. Shaffer, G. (2003). Defending interests: Public-private partnerships in W.T.O. litigation. Washington DC: Brookings.
Zurück zum Zitat Shoyer, A. (2003). Panel selection in WTO dispute settlement proceedings. Journal of International Economic Law, 6(1), 203–209.CrossRef Shoyer, A. (2003). Panel selection in WTO dispute settlement proceedings. Journal of International Economic Law, 6(1), 203–209.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stasavage, D. (2004). Open-door or closed-door? Transparency in domestic and international bargaining. International Organization, 58(4), 667–704.CrossRef Stasavage, D. (2004). Open-door or closed-door? Transparency in domestic and international bargaining. International Organization, 58(4), 667–704.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Steinberg, R. (2002). In the shadow of law or power? Consensus based bargaining in the GATT/WTO. International Organization, 56(2), 339–374.CrossRef Steinberg, R. (2002). In the shadow of law or power? Consensus based bargaining in the GATT/WTO. International Organization, 56(2), 339–374.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sutherland, P., et al. (2004). The future of the WTO: Addressing institutional challenges in the new millennium. Report of the Consultative Board to the Director-General Supachai Panitchpakdi. Geneva: WTO. Sutherland, P., et al. (2004). The future of the WTO: Addressing institutional challenges in the new millennium. Report of the Consultative Board to the Director-General Supachai Panitchpakdi. Geneva: WTO.
Zurück zum Zitat Thompson, A. (2006). Principal problems: UN weapons inspections in Iraq and beyond. Paper presented at the 2006 Annual Convention of the International Studies Association, San Diego. Thompson, A. (2006). Principal problems: UN weapons inspections in Iraq and beyond. Paper presented at the 2006 Annual Convention of the International Studies Association, San Diego.
Zurück zum Zitat Thompson, A., & Snidal, D. (2005). Guarding the equilibrium: regime management and the WTO. Paper presented at the 2005 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington DC. Thompson, A., & Snidal, D. (2005). Guarding the equilibrium: regime management and the WTO. Paper presented at the 2005 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington DC.
Zurück zum Zitat Van den Bossche, P., & Alexovicova, I. (2005). Effective global economic governance by the World Trade Organization. Journal of International Economic Law, 8(3), 667–690.CrossRef Van den Bossche, P., & Alexovicova, I. (2005). Effective global economic governance by the World Trade Organization. Journal of International Economic Law, 8(3), 667–690.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Weaver, C. (2010). The politics of performance evaluation: independent evaluation at the International Monetary Fund. Review of International Organizations, 5(3). Weaver, C. (2010). The politics of performance evaluation: independent evaluation at the International Monetary Fund. Review of International Organizations, 5(3).
Zurück zum Zitat Weiler, J. H. H. (2001). The rule of lawyers and the ethos of diplomats. Journal of World Trade, 35(2), 191–207.CrossRef Weiler, J. H. H. (2001). The rule of lawyers and the ethos of diplomats. Journal of World Trade, 35(2), 191–207.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Weiss, F. (2007). Transparency as an element of good governance in the practice of the EU and the WTO: overview and comparison. Fordham International Law Journal, 30(5), 1545–1586. Weiss, F. (2007). Transparency as an element of good governance in the practice of the EU and the WTO: overview and comparison. Fordham International Law Journal, 30(5), 1545–1586.
Zurück zum Zitat Winham, G. (1986). International trade and the Tokyo Round negotiation. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Winham, G. (1986). International trade and the Tokyo Round negotiation. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat World Bank. (2005). Global economic prospects 2005. Washington DC: World Bank.CrossRef World Bank. (2005). Global economic prospects 2005. Washington DC: World Bank.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat World Trade Organization. (2007). World trade report 2007. Geneva: WTO. World Trade Organization. (2007). World trade report 2007. Geneva: WTO.
Metadaten
Titel
The World Trade Organization at work: Performance in a member-driven milieu
verfasst von
Manfred Elsig
Publikationsdatum
01.09.2010
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
The Review of International Organizations / Ausgabe 3/2010
Print ISSN: 1559-7431
Elektronische ISSN: 1559-744X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-010-9093-2

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3/2010

The Review of International Organizations 3/2010 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner