Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 3-4/2014

01.12.2014

Assessing strategic voting in the 2008 US presidential primaries: the role of electoral context, institutional rules, and negative votes

verfasst von: D. Sunshine Hillygus, Sarah A. Treul

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 3-4/2014

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We examine the nature and extent of strategic voting in the 2008 US presidential primary. In doing so, we distinguish positive strategic voters—those casting ballots for their second choice in the primary and general election—from negative strategic voters—those casting ballots for a candidate they want to lose in the general election. We find evidence of both types in 2008. Moreover, we show that the likelihood of voting strategically is related to the electoral and institutional context. Specifically, those who prefer trailing candidates and who live in states with open primaries or with elections after John McCain became the presumed nominee were more likely to vote strategically.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
Others have used the term negative strategic voting to refer strictly to partisans who cast a ballot for an opposing party candidate they do not sincerely support (Southwell 1991). In contrast, our definition does not factor in the party affiliation (or registration) of the voter or candidate. As we show, there is a sizeable number of independents and in-partisans who vote for a candidate in the primary they intend to vote against in the general election.
 
2
Cain and Gerber (2002) have a terrific edited volume that offers a comprehensive analysis of hedging versus mischievous voting in California.
 
3
The operationalization of crossover voting actually varies widely in the literature. Some include Independents or unaffiliated voters as crossover voters, while others consider only partisans. Some use measures of party registration, while others use partisan self-identification. See Sides et al. (2002) for further discussion of this point.
 
4
There are a handful of notable exceptions (Geer 1986; Southwell 1989; Alvarez and Nagler 2000).
 
5
The codebook notes that two thirds of respondents were interviewed in the week following Super Tuesday when both the Democratic and Republican contests were competitive. And in the classic work on the topic, Abramson et al. (1992) construct within party rankings so there is no consideration of preferences that might cross party lines.
 
6
Geer (1986) argues that if someone really wants to vote in a primary, she just has to figure out what is necessary to participate. While this is surely true, it also is the case that the competitive context that motivates strategic voting might not emerge until after party registration deadlines have passed. Using voting experiments, Cherry and Kroll (2003) find that negative strategic voting is more likely in open than closed rule conditions.
 
7
Although these data limit our ability to explicitly test for the role of gender and racial attitudes, a cursory analysis suggests that among the Democrats who cast negative strategic votes for Clinton (i.e., they preferred McCain to either Clinton or Obama), only 36 % said they had a favorable view of blacks, compared to 56 % of those who cast a sincere vote for Clinton, 53 % of Democrats generally, and even 43 % of sincere McCain voters.
 
8
Moreover, given the fragmented information environment, coordination might come from social networks, blogs, or message boards rather than political elites. Scholars have challenged the conclusion that Limbaugh was responsible for the increased rate of crossover voting because the trend started even before his announcement (Stephenson 2011; Donovan 2008). Although we are not able to explicitly test for elite/media effects in our data, we do find that negative strategic Clinton voters were more likely than sincere Clinton voters and even sincere McCain voters to say they often watched Fox News. See footnote 36 for more on this point.
 
9
The study was a collaboration between the Associated Press and Yahoo Inc., with support from Knowledge Networks. The KnowledgePanel(R) panel members are chosen via a probability-based sampling method and using known published sampling frames that cover 96 % of the US population. Sampled non-Internet households are provided a laptop computer or MSN TV unit and free Internet service. The wave 1 survey (baseline) was fielded on November 2 2007 to a sample of 3,548 panel members of age 18 years or older who represented a general population sample. The total number of completed interviews at the baseline was 2,714, for a 76.5 % cooperation rate. Using the formula specified in Callegaro and Disogra (2008) to take into account initial recruitment into the KnowledgePanel, this represents a cumulative response rate (CUMRR1) of 11.2 %. This rate is a multiplicative combination of the panel recruitment response rate (AAPOR3), the household profile rate and the survey completion rate, but excludes the household retention rate. The study attempted to re-interview each of the baseline cases for a total of 11 waves. Kruse et al. (2009) and Deng et al. (2013) find little bias in these data from panel attrition and panel conditioning.
 
10
Demographics are measured in a profile survey gathered separately from the panel study. Self-reported vote choice in the primary was asked in either wave 4 or 5 depending on the date of the election in the respondent’s state.
 
11
In all waves, more than 75 % of the sample completed the survey within the first week of being fielded.
 
12
The question was worded as follows: “For each of the following individuals, please select if you have a favorable or unfavorable impression of that person. If you dont know enough about the person to have an opinion, you can say that too” [very favorable; somewhat favorable; somewhat unfavorable; very unfavorable; don’t know enough to say].
 
13
Table 1 shows which candidates were ranked in each wave. Once a candidate dropped out of the race the candidate was not ranked in the subsequent wave. Additionally, Huckabee, who rose to prominence only just before the Iowa Caucus, was not included as a candidate in wave 1 (November 2007). A handful of respondents—less than 4 % in waves 1–3 and 5 % in wave 4—rank all candidates equally.
 
14
We use the standard party identification question from wave 1 of the survey to help avoid conflation with primary voting. Independent leaners are included with partisans.
 
15
We must be cautious in focusing on any particular trend across waves since the number of candidates ranked (and thus the worst ranking possible) varies across waves. We find similar patterns if we instead look at the percentage of voters who rank each candidate first by party—the measure used in subsequent analysis—but we present the full rankings here to clearly illustrate the structure of our key measure.
 
16
Again, individuals could have more than one candidate ranked first.
 
17
Each candidate was evaluated according to the following traits: likeable, decisive, strong, honest, experienced, compassionate, refreshing, ethical, and attractive. The exact question wording is as follows: “Please tell me how well each word describes [INSERT NAME OF CANDIDATE] (not at all well, slightly well, somewhat well, very well). Increasing the number of items used to measure candidate preference helps to reduce the measurement error (Ansolabehere et al. 2008). As an additional robustness check on the effects of measurement error, we reestimate our models, where possible, just for the subset of politically interested respondents (on the assumption that they should have less measurement error in their preference rankings) and find similar patterns in the data.
 
18
It is interesting to note that if we look into the general election, just 8.7 % of general election voters ultimately cast a ballot for the candidate (McCain or Obama) they ranked the highest in November 2007.
 
19
Interestingly, the same is not true for John Edwards voters. This may reflect the fact that those voting for Edwards actually preferred Obama or Clinton but feared a woman or African-American nominee might not be electable in the general election.
 
20
For roughly two-thirds of respondents this was wave 3, thus typically capturing their vote preference before Super Tuesday, when Giuliani, Romney, Huckabee, and McCain were all running at double digits in the polls.
 
21
Given the added complexity and limited payoff of coding all eight candidates (since there was no incentive to cast a negative strategic vote for any of them), we focus here only on the rankings of the three always competitive candidates—McCain, Obama, and Clinton—since these were the candidates who were competitive when all voters were casting ballots. Seventy-five percent of voters cast a ballot for one of these three candidates.
 
22
Although some previous research strictly considers second choice preferences, this seemed too restrictive because so many respondents ranked uncompetitive candidates both first and second.
 
23
To be clear, this is distinct from previous measures of mischievous voting that consider only crossover voters—we deliberately do not consider the party of the candidate or voter in determining if a voter cast a negative strategic or even a mischievous vote.
 
24
For example, Abramson et al. (1992) found that 13 % of primary voters cast (positive) strategic ballots.
 
25
For the sake of comparison with previous research, we looked at negative strategic voters by party identification. We find that 63 % of negative strategic voters were crossover voters, while 37 % were partisans (including leaners) who nonetheless cast a negative strategic ballot for a candidate of their same party. These were, for example, self-identified Democrats who voted for Clinton even though they ranked McCain higher. This suggests that previous research that focuses on crossover voters captures the majority of negative strategic voters, but—at least in 2008—this more restrictive definition would miss a notable subset of voters who cast a negative strategic ballot for a candidate of their own party.
 
26
We relied on actual vote totals as reported by David Leip’s Atlas of US Presidential Elections.
 
27
For example, in her concession speech on 4 June 2008, Clinton remarked that “Nearly 18 million of you cast your votes for our campaign, carrying the popular vote with more votes than any primary candidate in history.”
 
28
However, there is little evidence that Clinton primary voters were especially likely to stay home on Election Day: 5 % of Clinton primary voters did not vote, compared to 4 % of Obama primary voters and 3 % of McCain voters. See Henderson et al. (2010) for a more extensive analysis of the link between primary and general election behavior in the 2008 campaign.
 
29
One interesting side note comes from the comparison of expected and reported behavior of sincere Clinton voters. Although these Clinton voters were no less likely than sincere Obama voters to report voting for McCain by November, in the heat of the competitive primary in April, they were significantly more likely to say they planned to vote for McCain than sincere Obama voters. These results are consistent with other analyses finding that supporters of losing candidates eventually rally behind the party nominee (Henderson et al. 2010). And to the extent that Obama did not win over all Clinton voters, it seems it might be because many never planned to vote for a Democrat in the general election.
 
30
A handful of states have different rules for each party within the state. Given our expectation that negative strategic voting is more common in the Democratic primary, our analysis codes states based on the Democratic party rules. Thus, we code as open any state that allows Republicans to vote in the Democratic primary, has no party registration requirement, allows Independents to vote, or has same day party registration (which can differ from voter registration rules in some states).
 
31
Although McCain did not formally reach a majority of delegates until the March 4 primaries, the media began calling McCain the “presumptive” nominee after Romney dropped out (Helman and Issenberg 2008). Although rather blunt, this measure captures the key transition point in the competitive environment.
 
32
Admittedly, this measure is far from ideal. A preferable measure of electability might ask about the perceived chances of each candidate in each wave. Although the study did ask a similar question about each candidate in wave 3, it was asked only of the subset of respondents who said they would vote in that candidates’ primary—making it inappropriate for our measure of strategic behavior. Even this standard measure of electability has been the subject of considerable criticism since it is so susceptible to projection (Bartels 1987). These are two additional reasons we later focus on the always-competitive candidates.
 
33
All model first differences and predicted probabilities are calculated holding all other variables constant at their means or modes for indicator variables.
 
34
We reestimated the model using polling numbers as a more nuanced measure of competition with similar conclusions. The use of polling numbers, however, is complicated by the fact that competition is less easily characterized in a mulitcandidate than in a two-candidate race (where margin can be used) and there were no polls on the Republican side after March 4. However, replicating the model using McCain and Obama’s absolute poll numbers (using 100 % for McCain after March 4) finds a positive and statistically significant coefficient for McCain’s poll numbers and no relationship with Obama’s poll numbers.
 
35
While this last variable is perhaps surprising, the measure is far from ideal—it is notoriously difficult for survey respondents to articulate the motivations underlying behavior and the other competition measures (support for trailing candidate and the time of election variable) are related to objective electability.
 
36
Although a more extensive analysis is beyond the scope of the article, we do find interesting variation in individual characteristics of those casting negative strategic votes for particular candidates. For example, among negative strategic Clinton voters, 42 % say they watch Fox News “quite a bit” or “a lot” (another 38 % say “some”), compared to 22 % of sincere Clinton voters and even 36 % of sincere McCain voters. Among the Democrats who cast negative strategic votes for Clinton (i.e., they preferred McCain to either Clinton or Obama), only 36 % said they had a favorable view of blacks, compared to 56 % of those who cast a sincere vote for Clinton, 53 % of Democrats generally, and even 43 % of sincere McCain voters. The numbers are obviously small and the analysis cursory, but this is at least suggestive of some of the motivations for negative strategic voting for Clinton.
 
37
Although the number of Democratic voters alone was not decisive in the Michigan Republican primary, exit polls reported that 53 % of Democrats cast their ballot for the more ideologically extreme Rick Santorum.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Abramowitz, A., McGlennon, J., & Rapoport, R. (1981). A note on strategic voting in a primary election. Journal of Politics, 43, 899–904.CrossRef Abramowitz, A., McGlennon, J., & Rapoport, R. (1981). A note on strategic voting in a primary election. Journal of Politics, 43, 899–904.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Abramson, P. R., Aldrich, J. H., Paolino, P., & Rohde, D. W. (1992). “Sophisticated” voting in the 1988 presidential primaries. American Political Science Review, 86(1), 55–69.CrossRef Abramson, P. R., Aldrich, J. H., Paolino, P., & Rohde, D. W. (1992). “Sophisticated” voting in the 1988 presidential primaries. American Political Science Review, 86(1), 55–69.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Adamany, D. (1976). Communications: Cross-over voting and the Democratic party’s reform rules. American Political Science Review, 70, 536–41. Adamany, D. (1976). Communications: Cross-over voting and the Democratic party’s reform rules. American Political Science Review, 70, 536–41.
Zurück zum Zitat Alvarez, R. M., & Nagler, J. (2000). A new approach for modeling strategic voting in multiparty systems. British Journal of Political Science, 30(1), 57–75.CrossRef Alvarez, R. M., & Nagler, J. (2000). A new approach for modeling strategic voting in multiparty systems. British Journal of Political Science, 30(1), 57–75.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alvarez, R. M., & Nagler, J. (2002). Should I stay or should I go? Sincere and strategic crossover. In B. E. Cain & E. R. Gerber (Eds.), Voting at the political fault line: California’s experiment with the blanket primary (pp. 107–123). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Alvarez, R. M., & Nagler, J. (2002). Should I stay or should I go? Sincere and strategic crossover. In B. E. Cain & E. R. Gerber (Eds.), Voting at the political fault line: California’s experiment with the blanket primary (pp. 107–123). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Ansolabehere, S., Rodden, J., & Snyder, J. M. (2008). The strength of issues: Using multiple measures to gauge preference stability, ideological constraint, and issue voting. American Political Science Review, 102(02), 215–232.CrossRef Ansolabehere, S., Rodden, J., & Snyder, J. M. (2008). The strength of issues: Using multiple measures to gauge preference stability, ideological constraint, and issue voting. American Political Science Review, 102(02), 215–232.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Atkeson, L. R. (1999). ‘Sure, I voted for the winner!’: Overreport of the primary vote for the party nominee in the national election studies. Political Behavior, 21(3), 197–215.CrossRef Atkeson, L. R. (1999). ‘Sure, I voted for the winner!’: Overreport of the primary vote for the party nominee in the national election studies. Political Behavior, 21(3), 197–215.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bartels, L. M. (1985). Expectations and preferences in presidential nominating campaigns. American Political Science Review, 79, 804–815.CrossRef Bartels, L. M. (1985). Expectations and preferences in presidential nominating campaigns. American Political Science Review, 79, 804–815.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bartels, L. M. (1987). Candidate choice and the dynamics of the presidential nominating process. American Journal of Political Science, 31(1), 1–30.CrossRef Bartels, L. M. (1987). Candidate choice and the dynamics of the presidential nominating process. American Journal of Political Science, 31(1), 1–30.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bartels, L. M. (1988). Presidential primaries and the dynamics of public choice. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Bartels, L. M. (1988). Presidential primaries and the dynamics of public choice. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Blais, A. (2003). Strategic voting in the 2002 French presidential election. In M. Lewis-Beck (Ed.), The French voter: Before and after the 2002 elections. Hampshire: Palgrave. Blais, A. (2003). Strategic voting in the 2002 French presidential election. In M. Lewis-Beck (Ed.), The French voter: Before and after the 2002 elections. Hampshire: Palgrave.
Zurück zum Zitat Blais, A., Nadeau, R., Gidengil, E., & Nevitte, N. (2001). Measuring strategic voting in multiparty plurality elections. Electoral Studies, 20, 343–352.CrossRef Blais, A., Nadeau, R., Gidengil, E., & Nevitte, N. (2001). Measuring strategic voting in multiparty plurality elections. Electoral Studies, 20, 343–352.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Burden, B. C. (2005). Minor partis and strategic voting in recent US presidential elections. Electoral Studies, 24, 603–18.CrossRef Burden, B. C. (2005). Minor partis and strategic voting in recent US presidential elections. Electoral Studies, 24, 603–18.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Burden, B. C., & Jones, P. E. (2009). Strategic voting in the USA. In B. Gofman, A. Blais, & S. Bowler (Eds.), Duverger’s law of plurality voting: The logic of party competition in Canada, India, the United Kingdom, and the United States. New York,: Springer. Burden, B. C., & Jones, P. E. (2009). Strategic voting in the USA. In B. Gofman, A. Blais, & S. Bowler (Eds.), Duverger’s law of plurality voting: The logic of party competition in Canada, India, the United Kingdom, and the United States. New York,: Springer.
Zurück zum Zitat Cain, B. E., & Gerber, E. R. (2002). California’s blanket primary experiment. In B. E. Cain & E. R. Gerber (Eds.), Voting at the political fault line: California’s experiment with the blanket primary (pp. 3–11). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Cain, B. E., & Gerber, E. R. (2002). California’s blanket primary experiment. In B. E. Cain & E. R. Gerber (Eds.), Voting at the political fault line: California’s experiment with the blanket primary (pp. 3–11). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Callegaro, M., & Disogra, C. (2008). Computing response metrics for online panels. Public Opinion Quarterly, 72(5), 1008–1032.CrossRef Callegaro, M., & Disogra, C. (2008). Computing response metrics for online panels. Public Opinion Quarterly, 72(5), 1008–1032.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cassette, A., Farvaque, E., & Hericourt, J. (2013). Two-round elections, one-round determinants? Evidence from the French municipal elections. Public Choice, 156, 563–591.CrossRef Cassette, A., Farvaque, E., & Hericourt, J. (2013). Two-round elections, one-round determinants? Evidence from the French municipal elections. Public Choice, 156, 563–591.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cherry, T. L., & Kroll, S. (2003). Crashing the party: An experimental investigation of strategic voting in primary elections. Public Choice, 114(3–4), 387–420.CrossRef Cherry, T. L., & Kroll, S. (2003). Crashing the party: An experimental investigation of strategic voting in primary elections. Public Choice, 114(3–4), 387–420.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cox, G. W. (1997). Making votes count: Strategic coordination in the world’s electoral systems (Vol. 7). New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Cox, G. W. (1997). Making votes count: Strategic coordination in the world’s electoral systems (Vol. 7). New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Deng, Y., Hillygus, D. S., Reiter, J. P., Si, Y., & Zheng, S. (2013). Handling attrition in longitudinal studies: The case for refreshment samples. Statistical Science, 28(2), 238–256.CrossRef Deng, Y., Hillygus, D. S., Reiter, J. P., Si, Y., & Zheng, S. (2013). Handling attrition in longitudinal studies: The case for refreshment samples. Statistical Science, 28(2), 238–256.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Donovan, T. (2008). The Limbaugh effect: A rush to judging cross-party raiding in the 2008 democratic nomination contests. The Forum, 6, 2.CrossRef Donovan, T. (2008). The Limbaugh effect: A rush to judging cross-party raiding in the 2008 democratic nomination contests. The Forum, 6, 2.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Geer, J. (1986). Rules governing presidential primaries. Journal of Politics, 48, 1006–25.CrossRef Geer, J. (1986). Rules governing presidential primaries. Journal of Politics, 48, 1006–25.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gerber, E. R., & Morton, R. B. (1998). Primary election systems and representation. Journal of Law and Economics, 41, 2. Gerber, E. R., & Morton, R. B. (1998). Primary election systems and representation. Journal of Law and Economics, 41, 2.
Zurück zum Zitat Hagen, M. G. & Johnston, R. (2004). Causes and consequences of crossover voting in presidential primaries. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, April 15–18, 2004. Hagen, M. G. & Johnston, R. (2004). Causes and consequences of crossover voting in presidential primaries. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, April 15–18, 2004.
Zurück zum Zitat Hedlund, R. D. (1977). Cross-over voting in a 1976 presidential primary. Public Opinion Quarterly, 41, 498–514.CrossRef Hedlund, R. D. (1977). Cross-over voting in a 1976 presidential primary. Public Opinion Quarterly, 41, 498–514.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hedlund, R. D., & Watts, M. W. (1986). The Wisconsin open primary, 1968–1984. American Politics Research, 14, 55–73. Hedlund, R. D., & Watts, M. W. (1986). The Wisconsin open primary, 1968–1984. American Politics Research, 14, 55–73.
Zurück zum Zitat Helman, S. & Issenberg, S. (2008). McCain becomes presumptive GOP nominee. The Boston Globe, February 7. Helman, S. & Issenberg, S. (2008). McCain becomes presumptive GOP nominee. The Boston Globe, February 7.
Zurück zum Zitat Henderson, M., Hillygus, D., & Tompson, T. (2010). ‘Sour grapes’ or rational voting? Voter decision making among thwarted primary voters in 2008. Public Opinion Quarterly, 74(3), 499–529.CrossRef Henderson, M., Hillygus, D., & Tompson, T. (2010). ‘Sour grapes’ or rational voting? Voter decision making among thwarted primary voters in 2008. Public Opinion Quarterly, 74(3), 499–529.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hillygus, D. S. (2007). The dynamics of voter decision making among minor party supporters: The 2000 US presidential election. British Journal of Political Science, 37(2), 225–244.CrossRef Hillygus, D. S. (2007). The dynamics of voter decision making among minor party supporters: The 2000 US presidential election. British Journal of Political Science, 37(2), 225–244.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jewell, M. E. (1974). A caveat on the expanding use of presidential primaries. Policy Studies Journal, 2, 279–83.CrossRef Jewell, M. E. (1974). A caveat on the expanding use of presidential primaries. Policy Studies Journal, 2, 279–83.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Johnston, R. J., & Pattie, C. J. (1991). Tactical voting in Great Britain in 1983 and 1987: An alternative approach. British Journal of Political Science, 21(01), 95–108.CrossRef Johnston, R. J., & Pattie, C. J. (1991). Tactical voting in Great Britain in 1983 and 1987: An alternative approach. British Journal of Political Science, 21(01), 95–108.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kaufmann, K. M., Gimpel, J. G., & Hoffman, A. (2003). A promise fulfilled? Open primaries and repreentation. Journal of Politics, 65(2), 457–76. Kaufmann, K. M., Gimpel, J. G., & Hoffman, A. (2003). A promise fulfilled? Open primaries and repreentation. Journal of Politics, 65(2), 457–76.
Zurück zum Zitat Kousser, T. (2002). Crossing over when it counts: How the motives of voters in blanket primaries are revealed by their actions in general elections. In B. E. Cain & E. R. Gerber (Eds.), Voting at the political fault line: California’s experiment with the blanket primary (pp. 143–170). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Kousser, T. (2002). Crossing over when it counts: How the motives of voters in blanket primaries are revealed by their actions in general elections. In B. E. Cain & E. R. Gerber (Eds.), Voting at the political fault line: California’s experiment with the blanket primary (pp. 143–170). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Kruse, Y., Callegaro, M., Dennis, J., Subias, S., Lawrence, M., DiSogra, C., & Tompson, T. (2009). Panel conditioning and attrition in the AP-Yahoo! News Election Panel Study. In 64th AAPOR Conference. Hollywood, FL: AAPOR. Kruse, Y., Callegaro, M., Dennis, J., Subias, S., Lawrence, M., DiSogra, C., & Tompson, T. (2009). Panel conditioning and attrition in the AP-Yahoo! News Election Panel Study. In 64th AAPOR Conference. Hollywood, FL: AAPOR.
Zurück zum Zitat McKelvey, R. D., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1972). A general theory of the calculus of voting. In J. F. Herndon & J. L. Bernd (Eds.), Mathematical applications in political science. Charlottesville, VA: University of Virginia Press. McKelvey, R. D., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1972). A general theory of the calculus of voting. In J. F. Herndon & J. L. Bernd (Eds.), Mathematical applications in political science. Charlottesville, VA: University of Virginia Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Merolla, J. L. (2009). The effect of information signals on strategic voting in mock mayoral elections. Political Behavior, 31(3), 379–399.CrossRef Merolla, J. L. (2009). The effect of information signals on strategic voting in mock mayoral elections. Political Behavior, 31(3), 379–399.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mooney, A. (2008). Limbaugh urges listeners to vote for Clinton. CNN Political Ticker, December 5. Mooney, A. (2008). Limbaugh urges listeners to vote for Clinton. CNN Political Ticker, December 5.
Zurück zum Zitat Moulitsa, M. (2012). Announcing operation hilarity: Let’s keep the GOP clown show going! Daily Kos, February 15. Moulitsa, M. (2012). Announcing operation hilarity: Let’s keep the GOP clown show going! Daily Kos, February 15.
Zurück zum Zitat Niemi, R. G., Nadeau, R., & Levine, J. (1993). Innumeracy about minority populations. Public Opinion Quarterly, 57, 332–347.CrossRef Niemi, R. G., Nadeau, R., & Levine, J. (1993). Innumeracy about minority populations. Public Opinion Quarterly, 57, 332–347.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Overacker, L. (1926). The presidential primary. New York: MacMillan. Overacker, L. (1926). The presidential primary. New York: MacMillan.
Zurück zum Zitat Pierce, R. (2003). Modelling electoral second choices: thwarted voters in the United States, France, and Russia. Electoral Studies, 22(2), 265–285.CrossRef Pierce, R. (2003). Modelling electoral second choices: thwarted voters in the United States, France, and Russia. Electoral Studies, 22(2), 265–285.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Primo, D. M., Jacobsmeier, M. L., & Milyo, J. (2007). Estimating the impact of state policies and institutions with mixed-level data. State Politics & Policy Quarterly, 7(4), 446–459.CrossRef Primo, D. M., Jacobsmeier, M. L., & Milyo, J. (2007). Estimating the impact of state policies and institutions with mixed-level data. State Politics & Policy Quarterly, 7(4), 446–459.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ranney, A. (1972). Turnout and representation in presidential primary elections. American Political Science Review, 66, 21–37.CrossRef Ranney, A. (1972). Turnout and representation in presidential primary elections. American Political Science Review, 66, 21–37.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Safire, W. (2008). The Bradley effect. The New York Times, September 28, MM30. Safire, W. (2008). The Bradley effect. The New York Times, September 28, MM30.
Zurück zum Zitat Salvanto, A. M., & Wattenberg, M. P. (2002). Peeking under the blanket: A direct look at crossover voting. In B. Cain & E. Gerber (Eds.), Voting at the political fault line (pp. 124–142). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Salvanto, A. M., & Wattenberg, M. P. (2002). Peeking under the blanket: A direct look at crossover voting. In B. Cain & E. Gerber (Eds.), Voting at the political fault line (pp. 124–142). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Sides, J., Cohen, J., & Citrin, J. (2002). The causes and consequences of crossover voting. In B. E. Cain & E. R. Gerber (Eds.), Voting at the political fault line (pp. 77–106). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Sides, J., Cohen, J., & Citrin, J. (2002). The causes and consequences of crossover voting. In B. E. Cain & E. R. Gerber (Eds.), Voting at the political fault line (pp. 77–106). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Southwell, P. L. (1989). Strategic voting in the 1984 Democratic presidential primaries. Social Science Journal, 26(4), 445–53.CrossRef Southwell, P. L. (1989). Strategic voting in the 1984 Democratic presidential primaries. Social Science Journal, 26(4), 445–53.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Southwell, P. L. (1991). Open versus closed primaries: The effect on strategic voting and candidate fortunes. Social Science Quarterly, 44(4), 789–796. Southwell, P. L. (1991). Open versus closed primaries: The effect on strategic voting and candidate fortunes. Social Science Quarterly, 44(4), 789–796.
Zurück zum Zitat Stephenson, E. F. (2011). Strategic voting in open primaries: evidence from Rush Limbaugh’s “operation chaos.” Public Choice, 148(3–4), 445–457. Stephenson, E. F. (2011). Strategic voting in open primaries: evidence from Rush Limbaugh’s “operation chaos.” Public Choice, 148(3–4), 445–457.
Metadaten
Titel
Assessing strategic voting in the 2008 US presidential primaries: the role of electoral context, institutional rules, and negative votes
verfasst von
D. Sunshine Hillygus
Sarah A. Treul
Publikationsdatum
01.12.2014
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 3-4/2014
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-014-0183-1

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3-4/2014

Public Choice 3-4/2014 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner