Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 1-2/2017

07.11.2016

Inequality, extractive institutions, and growth in nondemocratic regimes

verfasst von: Nobuhiro Mizuno, Katsuyuki Naito, Ryosuke Okazawa

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 1-2/2017

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This study investigates the effect of income inequality on economic growth in nondemocratic regimes. We provide a model in which a self-interested ruler chooses an institution that constrains his or her policy choice. The ruler must care about the extent of citizens’ support in order to remain in power. Under an extractive institution, the ruler can extract a large share of citizens’ wealth, but faces a high probability of losing power because of low public support. We show that inequality affects the ruler’s tradeoff between the expropriation of citizens’ wealth and his or her hold on power. Substantial inequality among citizens makes support for the ruler inelastic with respect to his or her institutional choice. The ruler therefore chooses an extractive institution, which impedes investment and growth. These results provide an explanation for the negative relationship between inequality and growth as well as the negative relationship between inequality and institutional quality, both of which are observed in nondemocratic countries.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
We borrow the term “extractive institutions” from Acemoglu et al. (2001, 2002). Acemoglu et al. (2002, p. 1235) use the term to refer to institutions that “concentrate power in the hands of a small elite and create a high risk of expropriation for the majority of the population”. We also consider institutions to be extractive when the property rights of citizens are not protected and the ruler in power can expropriate a large share of citizens’ wealth.
 
2
Based on the Polity IV dataset (Center for Systemic Peace 2012), we classify the political regime of a country as follows. First, following Persson and Tabellini (2009), the regime of a country in a given year is classified as a nondemocracy if the score of the polity2 variable from the Polity IV dataset is less than zero and as a democracy otherwise. Then, we define a country as a nondemocracy if the periods of nondemocratic rule are longer than those of democracy between 1960 and 2005. The measure of inequality is the simple average of the Gini coefficients from 1960 to 2005, as provided by the UNU-WIDER World Income Inequality Database (UNU-WIDER 2008). Note that controlling for different definitions of inequality, resulting from different units of observation and the definition of income, among others, does not change the results. Per-capita income is obtained from the Penn World Table 8.0 (Feenstra et al. 2015).
 
3
The measure of inequality is the same as in Fig. 1. The measures of governance quality are from the Worldwide Governance Indicators (Kaufmann et al. 2011).
 
4
Acemoglu and Robinson (2000) and Bourguignon and Verdier (2000) also consider an environment in which the elites’ policy choices affect their hold on power and analyze how inequality affects those choices. Acemoglu and Robinson (2000) provide a model in which elites attempt to prevent revolution by making concessions to citizens, such as temporary income redistributions or franchise extensions. Income inequality increases the citizens’ incentive to revolt and thereby affects the elites’ concessions. Bourguignon and Verdier (2000) propose a model in which the ruling elites choose a fraction of the poor to receive educational subsidies. Inequality affects the elite’s policy choices through the financial burden of the educational subsidies and the threat of income redistribution.
 
5
We restrict political participation to the old generation for simplicity. This restriction does not play any crucial role in the following analysis.
 
6
North and Weingast (1989), analyzing the institutions of seventeenth-century England, argue that a parliament limiting the ruler’s behavior can make the ruler commit credibly to giving up the option of confiscation. Wright (2008) also argues that authoritarian regimes wanting to facilitate private investment will establish legislatures so as to commit credibly to restricting expropriation. Congleton (2011) points out that even kings in the Middle Ages agreed to establish council or parliament constraining royal taxation to expand their tax base.
 
7
In Online Appendix A, we present an extension of the model in which the policy is determined through bargaining between the ruler in power and citizens. In this environment, the ruler’s taxation is constrained by the bargaining power of citizens.
 
8
A similar formulation is used in Grossman and Noh (1994) and Overland et al. (2005). In both studies, as in this article, a ruler derives utility from his or her own consumption and faces the probability of losing power. The ruler’s probability of retaining power depends on the expected utility of a representative producer in Grossman and Noh (1994) and on the level of domestic capital in Overland et al. (2005). We refer to this probability [given by (5)] as the “survival probability,” as in Grossman and Noh (1994).
 
9
Acemoglu and Robinson (2006, p. 25) state that “The citizens are excluded from the political system in nondemocracy, but they are nonetheless the majority and they can sometimes challenge the system, create significant social unrest and turbulence, or even pose a serious revolutionary threat.”
 
10
The negative relationship between a ruler’s survival probability and the share of opposing citizens can be interpreted in several ways. First, when the opponents of a ruler arm themselves, the rebel force will be stronger if it is larger. Second, even if a ruler commands a strong standing army that can repress antigovernment demonstrations, the more citizens participating in a demonstration, the larger is the cost of repression for the ruler. This is because a large number of victims of repression may result in sanctions from the international community, which can bring about the ruler’s downfall. Third, since the per capita cost of participating in antigovernment demonstrations declines as the number of participants increases, demonstrations are more likely to take place when more citizens oppose the government. Tullock (1974) and Kuran (1989) analyze such a strategic complementarity in the theory of revolution. Fourth, if the leaders of a military coup need a pretext for replacing an incumbent ruler, low public support for the incumbent is perfect for it.
 
11
For example, this cost includes losses associated with the inefficient allocation of government posts to members of the ruler’s family or the resources used to conceal the misappropriation of tax revenues.
 
12
Therefore, we do not consider the dynamics of income inequality, as it is beyond the scope of this study.
 
13
We assume an interior solution, which exists when \(\zeta\) is sufficiently large.
 
14
This formulation is based on the models of clientelism developed in Robinson and Torvik (2005) and Robinson et al. (2006).
 
15
Note that it is suboptimal for the incumbent ruler to choose an institution such that \(\psi \left( {\bar{\tau }} \right) > 1 + \xi /2\) and \(\psi \left( {\bar{\tau }} \right) < 1 - \xi /2\). If \(\psi \left( {\bar{\tau }} \right) > 1 + \xi /2\), the survival probability and payoff of the ruler will be zero. If \(\psi \left( {\bar{\tau }} \right) < 1 - \xi /2\), the ruler can increase \(\bar{\tau }\) without reducing his or her survival probability.
 
16
This mechanism is similar to the probabilistic voting model (Lindbeck and Weibull 1987; Dixit and Londregan 1996; Persson and Tabellini 2000). In the probabilistic voting model, the less dispersed the distribution of citizens’ political preferences, the more the politicians must be concerned about their welfare since the fraction of supporters is more responsive to the policy choice.
 
17
To ensure the interior solution \(p\left( {\bar{\tau }^{*} \left( \xi \right);\xi } \right) < 1\), the parameter \(\chi\) must be sufficiently small. Note that \(p\left( {\bar{\tau }^{*} \left( \xi \right);\xi } \right) < 1\) when \(\chi = 1\).
 
18
Online Appendix B also provides an intuitive explanation on these results.
 
19
Note that the distribution of relative human capital remains unchanged through generations regardless of the shape of distribution in the initial period.
 
20
We provide more detailed explanations in Online Appendix D.
 
21
According to Deininger and Squire (1996), the average Gini coefficient is 0.342 in South Korea (1953–1988), 0.335 in Indonesia (1964–1993), 0.296 in Taiwan (1964–1993), and 0.401 in Singapore (1973–1989).
 
22
Deiniger and Squire (1996) report that the mean of Gini coefficients is 0.573 in Brazil (1960–1989), 0.518 in Chile (1968–1994), 0.515 in Columbia (1970–1991), and 0.480 in Peru (1971–1994).
 
23
Although the hazard rate of an equal-income economy is less than that of an unequal-income economy in the range where relative income is small, we do not consider this to be a serious problem in terms of our results. The equilibrium institution is affected by the level of the hazard rate around the relative income of the threshold citizen. It is natural to think that autocratic rulers need less political support than democratic leaders. Hence, the relative income of the threshold citizen would exceed the average. Figure 4 shows that the range where the negative relationship between inequality and the hazard rate holds includes the mean.
 
24
Our focus is not on quantitative predictions but on whether the mechanism of the model is robust to an alternative shape of the income distribution.
 
25
This negative relationship between inequality and political stability is consistent with Alesina and Perotti (1996).
 
26
We do not calculate the equilibrium survival probability since we would need to specify the values of \(n\) and \(\chi\).
 
27
See Hill (1969).
 
28
See Stone (1965) and Hill (1969) for more details on the crisis situations faced by aristocrats and their causes.
 
29
Acemoglu et al. (2005b) provide empirical evidence that the expansion of Atlantic trade contributed to economic growth in the Western world. They argue that in countries with better access to Atlantic trade, the large profit they accrued enhanced the political power of merchant classes, which brought about an institutional change to protect property rights.
 
30
For the average Gini coefficients in these countries, see footnote 21.
 
31
In 1976, 62% of sub-Saharan African countries, 63% Middle East and North African countries, and 100% Central and East Europe/Former Soviet Union countries were classified as “Not Free.”
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D. (2005). Politics and economics in weak and strong states. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1199–1226.CrossRef Acemoglu, D. (2005). Politics and economics in weak and strong states. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1199–1226.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91, 1369–1401.CrossRef Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91, 1369–1401.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2002). Reversal of fortune: Geography and institutions in the making of the modern world income distribution. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1231–1294.CrossRef Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2002). Reversal of fortune: Geography and institutions in the making of the modern world income distribution. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1231–1294.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J.A. (2005a). Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. In Aghion, P. & Durlauf, S. N. (Eds.), Handbook of economic growth (Vol. 1A, pp. 385–472). Elsevier, Amsterdam. Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J.A. (2005a). Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. In Aghion, P. & Durlauf, S. N. (Eds.), Handbook of economic growth (Vol. 1A, pp. 385–472). Elsevier, Amsterdam.
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2005b). The rise of Europe: Atlantic trade, institutional change, and economic growth. American Economic Review, 95, 546–579.CrossRef Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2005b). The rise of Europe: Atlantic trade, institutional change, and economic growth. American Economic Review, 95, 546–579.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2000). Why did the West extend the franchise? Democracy, inequality, and growth in historical perspective. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 1167–1199.CrossRef Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2000). Why did the West extend the franchise? Democracy, inequality, and growth in historical perspective. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 1167–1199.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2006). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press. Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2006). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. New York: Crown Business. Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. New York: Crown Business.
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., Robinson, J. A., & Verdier, T. (2004). Kleptocracy and divide-and-rule: A model of personal rule. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2, 162–192.CrossRef Acemoglu, D., Robinson, J. A., & Verdier, T. (2004). Kleptocracy and divide-and-rule: A model of personal rule. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2, 162–192.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alesina, A., & Angeletos, G.-M. (2005). Corruption, inequality, and fairness. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1227–1244.CrossRef Alesina, A., & Angeletos, G.-M. (2005). Corruption, inequality, and fairness. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1227–1244.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alesina, A., & Perotti, R. (1996). Income distribution, political instability, and investment. European Economic Review, 40, 1203–1228.CrossRef Alesina, A., & Perotti, R. (1996). Income distribution, political instability, and investment. European Economic Review, 40, 1203–1228.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alesina, A., & Rodrik, D. (1994). Distributive politics and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 465–490.CrossRef Alesina, A., & Rodrik, D. (1994). Distributive politics and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 465–490.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Banerjee, A., & Duflo, E. (2003). Inequality and growth: What can the data say? Journal of Economic Growth, 8, 267–299.CrossRef Banerjee, A., & Duflo, E. (2003). Inequality and growth: What can the data say? Journal of Economic Growth, 8, 267–299.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barreto, R. A. (2000). Endogenous corruption in a neoclassical growth model. European Economic Review, 44, 35–60.CrossRef Barreto, R. A. (2000). Endogenous corruption in a neoclassical growth model. European Economic Review, 44, 35–60.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barro, R. J. (2000). Inequality and growth in a panel of countries. Journal of Economic Growth, 5, 5–32.CrossRef Barro, R. J. (2000). Inequality and growth in a panel of countries. Journal of Economic Growth, 5, 5–32.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Besley, T., & Kudamatsu, M. (2008). Making autocracy work. In E. Helpman (Ed.), Institutions and economic performance (pp. 452–510). Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Besley, T., & Kudamatsu, M. (2008). Making autocracy work. In E. Helpman (Ed.), Institutions and economic performance (pp. 452–510). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Birdsall, N., Ross, D., & Sabot, R. (1995). Inequality and growth reconsidered: Lessons from East Asia. World Bank Economic Review, 9, 477–508.CrossRef Birdsall, N., Ross, D., & Sabot, R. (1995). Inequality and growth reconsidered: Lessons from East Asia. World Bank Economic Review, 9, 477–508.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bourguignon, F., & Verdier, T. (2000). Oligarchy, democracy, inequality and growth. Journal of Development Economics, 62, 285–313.CrossRef Bourguignon, F., & Verdier, T. (2000). Oligarchy, democracy, inequality and growth. Journal of Development Economics, 62, 285–313.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson, R. M., & Morrow, J. D. (2003). The logic of political survival. Cambridge: MIT Press. Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson, R. M., & Morrow, J. D. (2003). The logic of political survival. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Center for Systemic Peace. (2012). Polity IV project: Political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2012. Vienna: Center for Systemic Peace. Center for Systemic Peace. (2012). Polity IV project: Political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2012. Vienna: Center for Systemic Peace.
Zurück zum Zitat Cerra, V., & Saxena, S. C. (2008). Growth dynamics: The myth of economic recovery. American Economic Review, 98, 439–457.CrossRef Cerra, V., & Saxena, S. C. (2008). Growth dynamics: The myth of economic recovery. American Economic Review, 98, 439–457.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cervellati, M., Fortunato, P., & Sunde, U. (2008). Hobbes to Rousseau: Inequality, institutions and development. Economic Journal, 118, 1354–1384.CrossRef Cervellati, M., Fortunato, P., & Sunde, U. (2008). Hobbes to Rousseau: Inequality, institutions and development. Economic Journal, 118, 1354–1384.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cheibub, J. A., Gandhi, J., & Vreeland, J. R. (2010). Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice, 143, 67–101.CrossRef Cheibub, J. A., Gandhi, J., & Vreeland, J. R. (2010). Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice, 143, 67–101.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cheng, T. J. (1989). Democratizing the quasi-Leninist regime in Taiwan. World Politics, 41, 471–499.CrossRef Cheng, T. J. (1989). Democratizing the quasi-Leninist regime in Taiwan. World Politics, 41, 471–499.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chong, A., & Gradstein, M. (2007). Inequality and institutions. Review of Economics and Statistics, 89, 454–465.CrossRef Chong, A., & Gradstein, M. (2007). Inequality and institutions. Review of Economics and Statistics, 89, 454–465.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Congleton, R. D. (2011). Perfecting parliament: Constitutional reform, liberalism, and the rise of Western democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press. Congleton, R. D. (2011). Perfecting parliament: Constitutional reform, liberalism, and the rise of Western democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Dalgic, E., & Long, N. V. (2006). Corrupt local governments as resource farmers: The helping hand and the grabbing hand. European Journal of Political Economy, 22, 115–138.CrossRef Dalgic, E., & Long, N. V. (2006). Corrupt local governments as resource farmers: The helping hand and the grabbing hand. European Journal of Political Economy, 22, 115–138.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat de la Croix, D., & Delavallade, C. (2009). Growth, public investment and corruption with failing institutions. Economics of Governance, 10, 187–219.CrossRef de la Croix, D., & Delavallade, C. (2009). Growth, public investment and corruption with failing institutions. Economics of Governance, 10, 187–219.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Deininger, K., & Squire, L. (1996). A new data set measuring income inequality. World Bank Economic Review, 10, 565–591.CrossRef Deininger, K., & Squire, L. (1996). A new data set measuring income inequality. World Bank Economic Review, 10, 565–591.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Deininger, K., & Squire, L. (1998). New ways of looking at old issues: Inequality and growth. Journal of Development Economics, 57, 259–287.CrossRef Deininger, K., & Squire, L. (1998). New ways of looking at old issues: Inequality and growth. Journal of Development Economics, 57, 259–287.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dixit, A., & Londregan, J. (1996). The determinants of success of special interests in redistributive politics. Journal of Politics, 58, 1132–1155.CrossRef Dixit, A., & Londregan, J. (1996). The determinants of success of special interests in redistributive politics. Journal of Politics, 58, 1132–1155.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Easterly, W. (2007). Inequality does cause underdevelopment: Insights from a new instrument. Journal of Development Economics, 84, 755–776.CrossRef Easterly, W. (2007). Inequality does cause underdevelopment: Insights from a new instrument. Journal of Development Economics, 84, 755–776.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ehrlich, I., & Lui, F. T. (1999). Bureaucratic corruption and endogenous economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 107, S270–S293.CrossRef Ehrlich, I., & Lui, F. T. (1999). Bureaucratic corruption and endogenous economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 107, S270–S293.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Eicher, T., García-Peñalosa, C., & van Ypersele, T. (2009). Education, corruption, and the distribution of income. Journal of Economic Growth, 14, 205–231.CrossRef Eicher, T., García-Peñalosa, C., & van Ypersele, T. (2009). Education, corruption, and the distribution of income. Journal of Economic Growth, 14, 205–231.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Engerman, S., & Sokoloff, K. (1997). Factor endowments, institutions, and differential paths of growth among new world economies. In S. Haber (Ed.), How Latin America fell behind (pp. 260–304). Stanford: Stanford University Press. Engerman, S., & Sokoloff, K. (1997). Factor endowments, institutions, and differential paths of growth among new world economies. In S. Haber (Ed.), How Latin America fell behind (pp. 260–304). Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Feenstra, R.C., Inklaar, R., & Timmer, M.P. (2015). The next generation of the Penn World Table. American Economic Review, 105, 3150–3182. Retrieved from www.ggdc.net/pwt Feenstra, R.C., Inklaar, R., & Timmer, M.P. (2015). The next generation of the Penn World Table. American Economic Review, 105, 3150–3182. Retrieved from www.​ggdc.​net/​pwt
Zurück zum Zitat Forbes, K. J. (2000). A reassesment of the relationship between inequality and growth. American Economic Review, 90, 869–887.CrossRef Forbes, K. J. (2000). A reassesment of the relationship between inequality and growth. American Economic Review, 90, 869–887.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Freedom House (2016). Freedom in the world 2016. Freedom House, Washington D.C. Freedom House (2016). Freedom in the world 2016. Freedom House, Washington D.C.
Zurück zum Zitat Galor, O., Moav, O., & Vollrath, D. (2009). Inequality in landownership, the emergence of human-capital promoting institutions, and the great divergence. Review of Economic Studies, 76, 143–179.CrossRef Galor, O., Moav, O., & Vollrath, D. (2009). Inequality in landownership, the emergence of human-capital promoting institutions, and the great divergence. Review of Economic Studies, 76, 143–179.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Galor, O., & Zeira, J. (1993). Income distribution and macroeconomics. Review of Economic Studies, 60, 35–52.CrossRef Galor, O., & Zeira, J. (1993). Income distribution and macroeconomics. Review of Economic Studies, 60, 35–52.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gandhi, J., & Przeworski, A. (2006). Cooperation, cooptation, and rebellion under dictatorships. Economics and Politics, 18, 1–26.CrossRef Gandhi, J., & Przeworski, A. (2006). Cooperation, cooptation, and rebellion under dictatorships. Economics and Politics, 18, 1–26.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gehlbach, S., & Keefer, P. (2011). Investment without democracy: Ruling-party institutionalization and credible commitment in autocracies. Journal of Comparative Economics, 39, 123–139.CrossRef Gehlbach, S., & Keefer, P. (2011). Investment without democracy: Ruling-party institutionalization and credible commitment in autocracies. Journal of Comparative Economics, 39, 123–139.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Glaeser, E. L., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2004). Do institutions cause growth? Journal of Economic Growth, 9, 271–303.CrossRef Glaeser, E. L., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2004). Do institutions cause growth? Journal of Economic Growth, 9, 271–303.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Glaeser, E., Scheinkman, J., & Shleifer, A. (2003). The injustice of inequality. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50, 199–222.CrossRef Glaeser, E., Scheinkman, J., & Shleifer, A. (2003). The injustice of inequality. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50, 199–222.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gradstein, M. (2007). Inequality, democracy, and the protection of property rights. Economic Journal, 117, 252–269.CrossRef Gradstein, M. (2007). Inequality, democracy, and the protection of property rights. Economic Journal, 117, 252–269.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman, H. I., & Noh, S. J. (1994). Proprietary public finance and economic welfare. Journal of Public Economics, 53, 187–204.CrossRef Grossman, H. I., & Noh, S. J. (1994). Proprietary public finance and economic welfare. Journal of Public Economics, 53, 187–204.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hall, R. E., & Jones, C. I. (1999). Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 83–116.CrossRef Hall, R. E., & Jones, C. I. (1999). Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 83–116.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hill, C. (1969). Reformation to industrial revolution. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books. Hill, C. (1969). Reformation to industrial revolution. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books.
Zurück zum Zitat Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2011). Worldwide governance indicators, 2011 update. Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2011). Worldwide governance indicators, 2011 update.
Zurück zum Zitat Keefer, P., & Knack, S. (2002). Polarization, politics and property rights: Links between inequality and growth. Public Choice, 111, 127–154.CrossRef Keefer, P., & Knack, S. (2002). Polarization, politics and property rights: Links between inequality and growth. Public Choice, 111, 127–154.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1995). Institutions and economic performance: Cross-country tests using alternative institutional measures. Economics and Politics, 7, 207–227.CrossRef Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1995). Institutions and economic performance: Cross-country tests using alternative institutional measures. Economics and Politics, 7, 207–227.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Koh, B. C. (1985). The 1985 parliamentary election in South Korea. Asian Survey, 25, 883–897.CrossRef Koh, B. C. (1985). The 1985 parliamentary election in South Korea. Asian Survey, 25, 883–897.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kuran, T. (1989). Sparks and prairie fires: A theory of unanticipated political revolution. Public Choice, 61, 41–74.CrossRef Kuran, T. (1989). Sparks and prairie fires: A theory of unanticipated political revolution. Public Choice, 61, 41–74.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Liddle, R. W. (1985). Soeharto’s Indonesia: Personal rule and political institutions. Pacific Affairs, 58, 68–90.CrossRef Liddle, R. W. (1985). Soeharto’s Indonesia: Personal rule and political institutions. Pacific Affairs, 58, 68–90.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lindbeck, A., & Weibull, J. (1987). Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition. Public Choice, 52, 273–297.CrossRef Lindbeck, A., & Weibull, J. (1987). Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition. Public Choice, 52, 273–297.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Long, N. V., & Sorger, G. (2006). Insecure property rights and growth: The role of appropriation costs, wealth effects, and heterogeneity. Economic Theory, 28, 513–529.CrossRef Long, N. V., & Sorger, G. (2006). Insecure property rights and growth: The role of appropriation costs, wealth effects, and heterogeneity. Economic Theory, 28, 513–529.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 681–712.CrossRef Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 681–712.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mauzy, D. K., & Milne, R. S. (2002). Singapore politics under the People’s Action Party. London and New York: Routledge.CrossRef Mauzy, D. K., & Milne, R. S. (2002). Singapore politics under the People’s Action Party. London and New York: Routledge.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McGuire, M. C., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule: The invisible hand and the use of force. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 72–96. McGuire, M. C., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule: The invisible hand and the use of force. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 72–96.
Zurück zum Zitat Mohtadi, H., & Roe, T. L. (2003). Democracy, rent seeking, public spending and growth. Journal of Public Economics, 87, 445–466.CrossRef Mohtadi, H., & Roe, T. L. (2003). Democracy, rent seeking, public spending and growth. Journal of Public Economics, 87, 445–466.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutional governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, 49, 803–832.CrossRef North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutional governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, 49, 803–832.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ooi, G.L., Tan, E.S., & Koh, G. (1998). Survey of state-society relations social indicators research project executive summary report. IPS Working Papers, No.5. Ooi, G.L., Tan, E.S., & Koh, G. (1998). Survey of state-society relations social indicators research project executive summary report. IPS Working Papers, No.5.
Zurück zum Zitat Overland, J., Simons, K. L., & Spagat, M. (2005). Political instability and growth in dictatorships. Public Choice, 125, 445–470.CrossRef Overland, J., Simons, K. L., & Spagat, M. (2005). Political instability and growth in dictatorships. Public Choice, 125, 445–470.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Padró i Miquel, G. (2007). The control of politicians in divided societies: The politics of fear. Review of Economic Studies, 74, 1259–1274.CrossRef Padró i Miquel, G. (2007). The control of politicians in divided societies: The politics of fear. Review of Economic Studies, 74, 1259–1274.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Perotti, R. (1996). Growth, income distribution, and democracy: What the data say. Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 149–187.CrossRef Perotti, R. (1996). Growth, income distribution, and democracy: What the data say. Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 149–187.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1994). Is inequality harmful for growth? American Economic Review, 84, 600–621. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1994). Is inequality harmful for growth? American Economic Review, 84, 600–621.
Zurück zum Zitat Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics: Explaining economic policy. Cambridge: MIT Press. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics: Explaining economic policy. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2009). Democratic capital: The nexus of political and economic change. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1, 88–126. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2009). Democratic capital: The nexus of political and economic change. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1, 88–126.
Zurück zum Zitat Pincus, S. (2009). 1688: The first modern revolution. London: Yale University Press. Pincus, S. (2009). 1688: The first modern revolution. London: Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Robinson, J.A. & Torvik, R. (2005). White elephants. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 197–210.CrossRef Robinson, J.A. & Torvik, R. (2005). White elephants. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 197–210.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Robinson, J. A., Torvik, R., & Verdier, T. (2006). Political foundations of the resource curse. Journal of Development Economics, 79, 447–468.CrossRef Robinson, J. A., Torvik, R., & Verdier, T. (2006). Political foundations of the resource curse. Journal of Development Economics, 79, 447–468.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth, 9, 131–165.CrossRef Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth, 9, 131–165.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shen, L. (2007). When will a dictator be good? Economic Theory, 31, 343–366.CrossRef Shen, L. (2007). When will a dictator be good? Economic Theory, 31, 343–366.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sokoloff, K. L., & Engerman, S. L. (2000). Institutions, factor endowments, and paths of development in the new world. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14, 217–232.CrossRef Sokoloff, K. L., & Engerman, S. L. (2000). Institutions, factor endowments, and paths of development in the new world. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14, 217–232.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sonin, K. (2003). Why the rich may favor poor protection of property rights. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31, 715–731.CrossRef Sonin, K. (2003). Why the rich may favor poor protection of property rights. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31, 715–731.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stone, L. (1964). The educational revolution in England, 1560-1640. Past and Present, 28, 41–80.CrossRef Stone, L. (1964). The educational revolution in England, 1560-1640. Past and Present, 28, 41–80.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stone, L. (1965). The crisis of the aristocracy, 1558–1641. London: Oxford University Press. Stone, L. (1965). The crisis of the aristocracy, 1558–1641. London: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Stone, L. (1966). Social mobility in England, 1500–1700. Past and Present, 33, 16–55.CrossRef Stone, L. (1966). Social mobility in England, 1500–1700. Past and Present, 33, 16–55.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Suh, D. S. (1982). South Korea in 1981: The first year of the fifth republic. Asian Survey, 22, 107–115.CrossRef Suh, D. S. (1982). South Korea in 1981: The first year of the fifth republic. Asian Survey, 22, 107–115.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tanzi, V., & Zee, H. H. (2000). Tax policy for emerging markets: Developing countries. National Tax Journal, 53, 299–322.CrossRef Tanzi, V., & Zee, H. H. (2000). Tax policy for emerging markets: Developing countries. National Tax Journal, 53, 299–322.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tawney, R. H. (1941). The rise of the gentry, 1558–1640. Economic History Review, 11, 1–38.CrossRef Tawney, R. H. (1941). The rise of the gentry, 1558–1640. Economic History Review, 11, 1–38.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tien, H. M. (1989). The great transition: Political and social change in the Republic of China. Stanford: Hoover Institution Press. Tien, H. M. (1989). The great transition: Political and social change in the Republic of China. Stanford: Hoover Institution Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1974). The social dilemma: The economics of war and revolution. Blacksburg: University Publications. Tullock, G. (1974). The social dilemma: The economics of war and revolution. Blacksburg: University Publications.
Zurück zum Zitat UNU-WIDER (2008). World income inequality database, version 2.0c. UNU-WIDER, Helsinki. UNU-WIDER (2008). World income inequality database, version 2.0c. UNU-WIDER, Helsinki.
Zurück zum Zitat Wintrobe, R. (1990). The tinpot and the totalitarian: An economic theory of dictatorship. American Political Science Review, 84, 849–872.CrossRef Wintrobe, R. (1990). The tinpot and the totalitarian: An economic theory of dictatorship. American Political Science Review, 84, 849–872.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wright, J. (2008). Do authoritarian institutions constrain? How legislatures affect economic growth and investment. American Journal of Political Science, 52, 322–343.CrossRef Wright, J. (2008). Do authoritarian institutions constrain? How legislatures affect economic growth and investment. American Journal of Political Science, 52, 322–343.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat You, J.-S., & Khagram, S. (2005). A comparative study of inequality and corruption. American Sociological Review, 70, 136–157.CrossRef You, J.-S., & Khagram, S. (2005). A comparative study of inequality and corruption. American Sociological Review, 70, 136–157.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Inequality, extractive institutions, and growth in nondemocratic regimes
verfasst von
Nobuhiro Mizuno
Katsuyuki Naito
Ryosuke Okazawa
Publikationsdatum
07.11.2016
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 1-2/2017
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-016-0387-7

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1-2/2017

Public Choice 1-2/2017 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner