Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 3-4/2015

01.03.2015 | Literature survey

Olson’s Logic of Collective Action at fifty

verfasst von: Paul Pecorino

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 3-4/2015

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In the 50 years since its publication, Mancur Olson’s Logic of Collective Action has had an enormous impact on the academic literature in both economics and political science. In this review essay, I discuss Olson’s work in light of the ensuing research, particularly developments in the theoretical literature. Much of the discussion focuses on the group-size paradox as applied to politics, i.e., the extent to which the group-size paradox can explain why the interests of some groups are better represented in the political process than others. I also discuss selective incentives with an emphasis on the byproduct mechanism under which a firm sells a private good and uses the resulting profits to provide a public good.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
The exploitation of the great by the small result is the basis for the literature on burden-sharing in international alliances (Olson and Zeckhauser 1966). I will not be discussing this literature in this paper. See Sandler and Hartley (2001) for a survey.
 
2
For example, see George F. Will, “Congress Needs to Stop Subsidies to Sugar Farmers”, Washington Post June 7, 2013. In writing about a US Senate vote that left the sugar program intact, Will refers to the “law of disbursed costs but concentrated benefits”.
 
3
A major exception to this is the literature on rent seeking in groups in which two or more groups seek a rent. This literature is discussed in Sect. 2.4.
 
4
If a good is excludable, then there is a presumption that it can be provided privately. If it is excludable, but has some degree of nonrivalry, then it may be a club good, as in Buchanan (1965). Olson (1965, p. 14, footnote 21) and Ostrom (2003) both argue that nonexcludablilty is an essential aspect of the collective action problem, but that nonrivalry is not an essential aspect of the problem.
 
5
One weakness of the book is that the discussion shifts between continuous and discrete public goods without warning. This hurts the clarity of the exposition.
 
6
Some alternatives to the summation technology include best-shot and weakest link (Hirshleifer 1983). Cornes (1993) provides a model in which best shot, weakest link and summation are all special cases.
 
7
The modern literature on public goods derives from Lindahl (1967) and Samuelson (1954). In addition to the work of Chamberlin (1974) and McGuire (1974), which is discussed below, other key works contributing to the development of the standard model of public good provision include Sugden (1982), Warr (1983), Cornes and Sandler (1984, 1985), Bergstrom, Blume and Varian (1986) and Andreoni (1988). An extended analysis of public goods may be found in Cornes and Sandler (1996).
 
8
It should be noted, however, that the widening gap between the equilibrium level of provision and the optimal level of provision might not be observed for alternative aggregation technologies. See, for example, Sandler’s (1992, pp. 52–54) discussion of this relationship for the weakest link technology.
 
9
The marginal utility of income is the opportunity cost of contributing towards the public good. Assume for simplicity that group members are identical. The per-person contribution goes to 0 as group size increases, so that asymptotically all spending is on the private good. This sets the lower bound on the marginal utility of income and, in turn, determines the level of the public good’s provision as group size grows large.
 
10
An absence of income effects is associated with quasi-linear preferences or situations in which the contribution towards the public good affects profits. Examples of the latter would include a common-pool resource, such as a fishery (Sandler 1992, pp. 117–123), and tariff lobbying.
 
11
When two groups are included in the model, a natural interpretation is a political example wherein one group lobbies in favor of and one lobbies against a particular policy.
 
12
Esteban and Ray (2001, p. 663) cite a passage from Pareto that gives an example along the lines presented here.
 
13
Olson uses the example of firms in an industry attempting to raise the price of the good they produce by restricting supply. If the group contains all of an industry’s firms, then clearly each firm would like the group to be smaller. If the group comprises a set of firms colluding to reduce output, then (conditional on the size of the industry) each firm would like the group to be larger. In Olson’s discussion, the group is defined as the number of firms in the industry. For a recent treatment of this issue, see Van Essen (2013), who analyzes Cournot oligopoly from the perspective of the theory of public goods. He considers both firms that produce substitute goods and firms that produce perfect complements.
 
14
In footnote 61 on page 40, Olson argues that if the good is not a pure public good, but nevertheless is sufficiently non-rival, the group in question would welcome new members. As discussed later, however, even a small degree of rivalry can make a significant difference in the ability of a large group to provide itself with a public good.
 
15
This is true in the sense that the benefit received by each individual from the contribution is independent of how many others belong to the group, if the good is a pure public good. Also, it does no good to appeal to the idea that if many others are contributing, a single individual’s contribution would appear to make only a trivial difference and therefore will not be made. This presumes that many others are contributing and, if this is so, the group has, to some degree, overcome the free-rider problem. It is self-contradictory to argue that a single individual will not contribute because so many others already are contributing, and then conclude that the group will be unable to provide itself with any of the public good.
 
16
Olson does not use the term nonrival. Rather he states that the large group could provide the good if the cost of doing so did not change even as millions entered the group. If the cost of providing members a given amount of the good does not change when millions enter the group, the good must be nonrival.
 
17
Utility is assumed to be increasing in both arguments. It is also assumed that the marginal rate of substitution between x and g is finite when x is finite and g > 0.
 
18
Chamberlin (1974) uses reaction functions to show that rivalry can lead to a strong from of the group-size paradox. This occurs when the reaction function converges toward the origin, as group size grows large. He does not provide a measure of the degree of rivalry in his analysis, but the discussion above suggests that the reaction functions converge towards the origin for all β > 0. It will prove useful for later discussions in the paper to be able to use β as a measure of the degree of rivalry.
 
19
Pecorino (2009a) also shows that above some critical value of n, dg/dn < 0. Based on his simulations with a CES utility function, the critical value of n does not appear to be very large even for values of β close to 0.
 
20
For example, in the Grossman and Helpman (1994) model of tariff lobbying, when all sectors are politically organized, the outcome is free trade. .
 
21
They consider both Cobb-Douglas and quasi-linear utility functions.
 
22
Other recent work is also supportive of Olson. Konishi and Shinohara (2014) consider voluntary participation in a process that will provide a public good. They find that public good provision goes to 0 as group size grows large.
 
23
This might not be true if there are fairness concerns. If the five feel exploited by the non-contributors, then they might not be willing to reach the same agreement in the presence of other members of the group. Fairness concerns might be thought of as a way in which groups could at least partially overcome the free-rider problem if they lead individuals to contribute when they are otherwise predicted to free ride. As the example presented here suggests, however, this could cut the other way and lead to a failure to provide goods that might otherwise have been predicted to be provided. .
 
24
An exception is Pecorino (2009b), but the model in that paper is not relevant to the political application of the group-size paradox; also see Mondal (2013).
 
25
Kolmar and Wagener (2012) extend Morgan’s work by considering a more general class of contests of which the lottery is a special case.
 
26
A noncooperative outcome is always a possible equilibrium of the model regardless of the value of the discount parameter.
 
27
This contrasts with earlier work by Lambson (1984, 1987), who analyzes cooperation in a repeated game between oligopolists. He found that unless certain stringent conditions are met, cooperation would break-down, as the number of firms in the industry grows large. This occurs because the critical value of the discount parameter generally approaches 1 as the number of firms in the industry approaches infinity. Also see the discussion in Shapiro (1989). For more recent work on public good provision in a repeated game setting, see Haag and Lagunoff (2007) and Cheikbossian (2012).
 
28
Ostrom’s (1990, 1998) work suggests that repeated interactions are important if a group is to effectively manage a common-pool resource.
 
29
The work of Borcherding and Deacon (1972) and Bergstrom and Goodman (1973) indicates that many publically provided goods exhibit a high degree of rivalry consistent with values of β near 1.
 
30
Esteban and Ray also assume that an agent currently making a zero contribution (s i  = 0) has a zero marginal cost of making a contribution.
 
31
Also see McGinty (2014), who shows that the free-rider problem in team production depends on the relationship between returns to scale and the substitution elasticity between effort levels of team members.
 
32
Even making a contribution online requires incurring some fixed costs of participation.
 
33
Pecorino and Temimi (2008) model rivalry by defining g = S/n β , as in our discussion here. This differs from the approach of Esteban and Ray (2001), and this difference plays a key role in the result they find. Also, while Esteban and Ray analyze a rent-seeking contest, Pecorino and Temimi apply the Esteban and Ray technology to a traditional public goods problem. However, Pecorino and Temimi show that their argument also applies to the rent-seeking contest analyzed Esteban and Ray.
 
34
Of the papers discussed so far, Esteban and Ray (2001) is an exception. In their model two groups compete for a rent.
 
35
If individual valuations of the rent are drawn from a distribution, larger groups will have an advantage. The larger the group, the larger is the expected value of highest valuation of the rent.
 
36
Other papers of note on the topic of rent seeking in groups include Cheikbossian (2008), Gradstein (1993), Baik and Lee (2007), Nitzan and Ueda (2009, 2011) and Kolmar and Rommeswinkel (2013).
 
37
See “Alabama Senate Approves Education Budget, Raise”, Bloomberg Businessweek, May 8, 2013.
 
38
Olson talks a fair bit about non-economic motives and social pressures that might lead someone to contribute to a public good (e.g., pp. 60–61). He argues that these motives are less likely to apply to political lobbying and that they are more likely to apply in a small group rather than in a large group. These motives thus serve as another source of advantage for small groups over large groups.
 
39
Stigler is referring to a situation in which the public good and private good are not technologically linked, as in the joint products model of Cornes and Sandler (1984).
 
40
An alternative approach is taken by Bagnoli and Watts (2003) who model consumers as experiencing a warm glow when they make purchases from byproduct firms.
 
41
See, among others, Teisl et al. (2002), Landry and Price (2007), Casadesus-Masanell et al. (2009), Elfenbein and McManus (2010) and Hiscox and Smyth (2011).
 
42
See Mayer (2002) for an analysis of the pricing problem faced by a byproduct firm when it acts as a monopolist.
 
43
See Okrent’s (2010) discussion of the success of the Anti-Saloon League in getting “dry” candidates elected even though the overall public sentiment in favor of Prohibition was not very strong.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Andreoni, J. (1988). Privately provided public goods in a large economy: The limits to altruism. Journal of Public Economics, 35, 57–73.CrossRef Andreoni, J. (1988). Privately provided public goods in a large economy: The limits to altruism. Journal of Public Economics, 35, 57–73.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Andreoni, J. (1989). Giving with impure altruism: Applications to charity and Ricardian equivalence. Journal of Political Economy, 97, 1447–1458.CrossRef Andreoni, J. (1989). Giving with impure altruism: Applications to charity and Ricardian equivalence. Journal of Political Economy, 97, 1447–1458.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm glow giving. Economic Journal, 100, 464–477.CrossRef Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm glow giving. Economic Journal, 100, 464–477.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bagnoli, M., & Watts, S. G. (2003). Selling to socially responsible consumers: Competition, and the private provision of public goods. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 12, 419–445.CrossRef Bagnoli, M., & Watts, S. G. (2003). Selling to socially responsible consumers: Competition, and the private provision of public goods. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 12, 419–445.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Baik, K. H. (1993). Effort levels in contests: The public good prize case. Economics Letters, 41, 363–367.CrossRef Baik, K. H. (1993). Effort levels in contests: The public good prize case. Economics Letters, 41, 363–367.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Baik, K. H., & Lee, S. (2007). Collective rent seeking when sharing rules are private information. European Journal of Political Economy, 23, 768–776.CrossRef Baik, K. H., & Lee, S. (2007). Collective rent seeking when sharing rules are private information. European Journal of Political Economy, 23, 768–776.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bergstrom, T., Blume, L., & Varian, H. (1986). On the private provision of public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 29, 25–49.CrossRef Bergstrom, T., Blume, L., & Varian, H. (1986). On the private provision of public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 29, 25–49.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bergstrom, T. C., & Goodman, R. P. (1973). Private demand for public goods. American Economic Review, 63, 280–296. Bergstrom, T. C., & Goodman, R. P. (1973). Private demand for public goods. American Economic Review, 63, 280–296.
Zurück zum Zitat Besley, T., & Ghatak, M. (2007). Retailing public goods: The economics of corporate social responsibility. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 1645–1663.CrossRef Besley, T., & Ghatak, M. (2007). Retailing public goods: The economics of corporate social responsibility. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 1645–1663.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Borcherding, T. E., & Deacon, R. T. (1972). The demand for services of non-federal governments. American Economic Review, 62, 891–901. Borcherding, T. E., & Deacon, R. T. (1972). The demand for services of non-federal governments. American Economic Review, 62, 891–901.
Zurück zum Zitat Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32, 1–14.CrossRef Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32, 1–14.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Casadesus-Masanell, R., Crooke, M., Reinhardt, F., & Vasishth, V. (2009). Households’ willingness to pay for ‘green’ goods: Evidence from Patagonia’s introduction of organic cotton sportswear. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 18, 203–233.CrossRef Casadesus-Masanell, R., Crooke, M., Reinhardt, F., & Vasishth, V. (2009). Households’ willingness to pay for ‘green’ goods: Evidence from Patagonia’s introduction of organic cotton sportswear. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 18, 203–233.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chamberlin, J. (1974). Provision of public goods as a function of group size. American Political Science Review, 68, 707–716.CrossRef Chamberlin, J. (1974). Provision of public goods as a function of group size. American Political Science Review, 68, 707–716.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cheikbossian, G. (2008). Heterogeneous groups and rent-seeking for public goods. European Journal of Political Economy, 24, 133–150.CrossRef Cheikbossian, G. (2008). Heterogeneous groups and rent-seeking for public goods. European Journal of Political Economy, 24, 133–150.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cheikbossian, G. (2012). The collective action problem: Within group cooperation and between group competition in a repeated rent-seeking game. Games and Economic Behavior, 74, 68–82.CrossRef Cheikbossian, G. (2012). The collective action problem: Within group cooperation and between group competition in a repeated rent-seeking game. Games and Economic Behavior, 74, 68–82.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cornes, R. (1993). Dyke maintenance and other stories: Some neglected types of public goods. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 259–271.CrossRef Cornes, R. (1993). Dyke maintenance and other stories: Some neglected types of public goods. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 259–271.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1984). Easy riders, joint production, and public goods. Economic Journal, 94, 580–598.CrossRef Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1984). Easy riders, joint production, and public goods. Economic Journal, 94, 580–598.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1985). The simple analytics of pure public good provision. Economica, 52, 103–116.CrossRef Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1985). The simple analytics of pure public good provision. Economica, 52, 103–116.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1994). The comparative static properties of the impure public good model. Journal of Public Economics, 54, 403–421.CrossRef Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1994). The comparative static properties of the impure public good model. Journal of Public Economics, 54, 403–421.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1996). The theory of externalities, public goods, and club goods (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1996). The theory of externalities, public goods, and club goods (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dixit, A., & Olson, M. (2000). Does voluntary participation undermine the Coase theorem? Journal of Public Economics, 76, 309–335.CrossRef Dixit, A., & Olson, M. (2000). Does voluntary participation undermine the Coase theorem? Journal of Public Economics, 76, 309–335.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Elfenbein, D. W., & McManus, B. (2010). Greater price for a greater good? Evidence that consumers pay more for charity linked products. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 2, 28–60. Elfenbein, D. W., & McManus, B. (2010). Greater price for a greater good? Evidence that consumers pay more for charity linked products. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 2, 28–60.
Zurück zum Zitat Esteban, J., & Ray, D. (2001). Collective action and the group-size paradox. American Political Science Review, 95, 663–672.CrossRef Esteban, J., & Ray, D. (2001). Collective action and the group-size paradox. American Political Science Review, 95, 663–672.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gradstein, M. (1993). Rent seeking and the provision of public goods. Economic Journal, 103, 1236–1243.CrossRef Gradstein, M. (1993). Rent seeking and the provision of public goods. Economic Journal, 103, 1236–1243.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84, 833–850. Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84, 833–850.
Zurück zum Zitat Haag, M., & Lagunoff, R. (2007). On the size and structure of group cooperation. Journal of Economic Theory, 135, 68–89.CrossRef Haag, M., & Lagunoff, R. (2007). On the size and structure of group cooperation. Journal of Economic Theory, 135, 68–89.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hirshleifer, J. (1983). From weakest link to best shot: The voluntary provision of public goods. Public Choice, 41, 371–386.CrossRef Hirshleifer, J. (1983). From weakest link to best shot: The voluntary provision of public goods. Public Choice, 41, 371–386.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Katz, E., Nitzan, S., & Rosenberg, J. (1990). Rent seeking for pure public goods. Public Choice, 65, 49–60.CrossRef Katz, E., Nitzan, S., & Rosenberg, J. (1990). Rent seeking for pure public goods. Public Choice, 65, 49–60.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kolmar, M., & Rommeswinkel, H. (2013). Contests with group specific public goods and complementarities in efforts. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 89, 9–22.CrossRef Kolmar, M., & Rommeswinkel, H. (2013). Contests with group specific public goods and complementarities in efforts. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 89, 9–22.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kolmar, M., & Wagener, A. (2012). Contests and the private provision of public goods. Southern Economic Journal, 79, 161–179.CrossRef Kolmar, M., & Wagener, A. (2012). Contests and the private provision of public goods. Southern Economic Journal, 79, 161–179.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Konishi, H., & Shinohara, R. (2014). Voluntary participation and provision of public goods in large finite economies. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 16, 173–195.CrossRef Konishi, H., & Shinohara, R. (2014). Voluntary participation and provision of public goods in large finite economies. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 16, 173–195.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kotchen, M. J. (2006). Green markets and the private provision of public goods. Journal of Political Economy, 114, 816–834.CrossRef Kotchen, M. J. (2006). Green markets and the private provision of public goods. Journal of Political Economy, 114, 816–834.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lambson, V. E. (1984). Self-enforcing collusion in large dynamic markets. Journal of Economic Theory, 34, 282–291.CrossRef Lambson, V. E. (1984). Self-enforcing collusion in large dynamic markets. Journal of Economic Theory, 34, 282–291.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lambson, V. E. (1987). Dynamic behaviour in large markets for differentiated products. Review of Economic Studies, 54, 293–300.CrossRef Lambson, V. E. (1987). Dynamic behaviour in large markets for differentiated products. Review of Economic Studies, 54, 293–300.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Landry, C. E., & Price, M. K. (2007). Earmarking lottery proceeds for public goods: Empirical evidence from U.S. lotto expenditures. Economics Letters, 95, 451–455.CrossRef Landry, C. E., & Price, M. K. (2007). Earmarking lottery proceeds for public goods: Empirical evidence from U.S. lotto expenditures. Economics Letters, 95, 451–455.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lindahl, E. (1967). Just taxation—A positive solution. In R. A. Musgrave & A. T. Peacock (Eds.), Classics in the theory of public finance (pp. 168–176). New York: St. Martin’s Press. Lindahl, E. (1967). Just taxation—A positive solution. In R. A. Musgrave & A. T. Peacock (Eds.), Classics in the theory of public finance (pp. 168–176). New York: St. Martin’s Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Mayer, W. (2002). On the efficiency of by-product lobbying. Public Choice, 112, 275–292.CrossRef Mayer, W. (2002). On the efficiency of by-product lobbying. Public Choice, 112, 275–292.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McGinty, M. (2014). Strategic incentives in teams: Implications of returns to scale. Southern Economic Journal, 81(2). McGinty, M. (2014). Strategic incentives in teams: Implications of returns to scale. Southern Economic Journal, 81(2).
Zurück zum Zitat McGuire, M. C. (1974). Group size, group homogeneity, and the aggregate provision of a pure public good under Cournot behavior. Public Choice, 18, 107–126.CrossRef McGuire, M. C. (1974). Group size, group homogeneity, and the aggregate provision of a pure public good under Cournot behavior. Public Choice, 18, 107–126.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mondal, D. (2013). Public good provision under monopolistic competition. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 15, 378–396.CrossRef Mondal, D. (2013). Public good provision under monopolistic competition. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 15, 378–396.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Morgan, J. (2000). Financing public goods by means of lotteries. Review of Economic Studies, 67, 761–784.CrossRef Morgan, J. (2000). Financing public goods by means of lotteries. Review of Economic Studies, 67, 761–784.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nitzan, S. (1991). Collective rent dissipation. Economic Journal, 101, 1522–1534.CrossRef Nitzan, S. (1991). Collective rent dissipation. Economic Journal, 101, 1522–1534.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nitzan, S., & Ueda, K. (2009). Collective contests for commons and club goods. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 48–55.CrossRef Nitzan, S., & Ueda, K. (2009). Collective contests for commons and club goods. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 48–55.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nitzan, S., & Ueda, K. (2011). Prize sharing in collective contests. European Economic Review, 55, 678–687.CrossRef Nitzan, S., & Ueda, K. (2011). Prize sharing in collective contests. European Economic Review, 55, 678–687.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Okrent, D. (2010). Last call: The rise and fall of prohibition. New York: N.Y., Scribner. Okrent, D. (2010). Last call: The rise and fall of prohibition. New York: N.Y., Scribner.
Zurück zum Zitat Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Olson, M., & Zeckhauser, R. (1966). An economic theory of alliances. Review of Economics and Statistics, 48, 266–279.CrossRef Olson, M., & Zeckhauser, R. (1966). An economic theory of alliances. Review of Economics and Statistics, 48, 266–279.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ostrom, E. (1998). A behavioral approach to the rational choice theory of collective action. American Political Science Review, 92, 1–22.CrossRef Ostrom, E. (1998). A behavioral approach to the rational choice theory of collective action. American Political Science Review, 92, 1–22.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ostrom, E. (2003). How types of goods and property rights jointly affect collective action. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 15, 239–270.CrossRef Ostrom, E. (2003). How types of goods and property rights jointly affect collective action. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 15, 239–270.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Palfrey, T. R., & Rosenthal, H. (1984). Participation and the provision of discrete public goods: A strategic analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 24, 171–193.CrossRef Palfrey, T. R., & Rosenthal, H. (1984). Participation and the provision of discrete public goods: A strategic analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 24, 171–193.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pecorino, P. (1999). The effect of group size on public good provision in a repeated game setting. Journal of Public Economics, 72, 121–134.CrossRef Pecorino, P. (1999). The effect of group size on public good provision in a repeated game setting. Journal of Public Economics, 72, 121–134.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pecorino, P. (2001). Can by-product lobbying firms compete? Journal of Public Economics, 82, 377–397.CrossRef Pecorino, P. (2001). Can by-product lobbying firms compete? Journal of Public Economics, 82, 377–397.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pecorino, P. (2009a). Public goods, group size and the degree of rivalry. Public Choice, 138, 161–169.CrossRef Pecorino, P. (2009a). Public goods, group size and the degree of rivalry. Public Choice, 138, 161–169.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pecorino, P. (2009b). Monopolistic competition, group size and public good provision. Economic Journal, 119, 298–307.CrossRef Pecorino, P. (2009b). Monopolistic competition, group size and public good provision. Economic Journal, 119, 298–307.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pecorino, P. (2010). By-product lobbying with rival public goods. European Journal of Political Economy, 26, 114–124.CrossRef Pecorino, P. (2010). By-product lobbying with rival public goods. European Journal of Political Economy, 26, 114–124.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pecorino, P. (2013). Monopolistic competition and public good provision with by-product firms. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 22, 875–893.CrossRef Pecorino, P. (2013). Monopolistic competition and public good provision with by-product firms. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 22, 875–893.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pecorino, P., & Temimi, A. (2007). Lotteries, group size and public good provision. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 9, 451–465.CrossRef Pecorino, P., & Temimi, A. (2007). Lotteries, group size and public good provision. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 9, 451–465.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pecorino, P., & Temimi, A. (2008). The group-size paradox revisited. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 10, 785–799.CrossRef Pecorino, P., & Temimi, A. (2008). The group-size paradox revisited. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 10, 785–799.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pecorino, P., & Temimi, A. (2012). Lotteries, public good provision and the degree of rivalry. International Tax and Public Finance, 19, 195–202.CrossRef Pecorino, P., & Temimi, A. (2012). Lotteries, public good provision and the degree of rivalry. International Tax and Public Finance, 19, 195–202.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Posnett, J., & Sandler, T. (1986). Joint supply and the finance of charitable activity. Public Finance Quarterly, 14, 209–222.CrossRef Posnett, J., & Sandler, T. (1986). Joint supply and the finance of charitable activity. Public Finance Quarterly, 14, 209–222.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Riaz, K., Shogren, J. F., & Johnson, S. R. (1995). A general model of rent seeking for public goods. Public Choice, 82, 243–259.CrossRef Riaz, K., Shogren, J. F., & Johnson, S. R. (1995). A general model of rent seeking for public goods. Public Choice, 82, 243–259.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rodrik, D. (1986). Tariffs, subsidies, and welfare with endogenous policy. Journal of International Economics, 21, 285–299.CrossRef Rodrik, D. (1986). Tariffs, subsidies, and welfare with endogenous policy. Journal of International Economics, 21, 285–299.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Saijo, T., & Yamato, T. (1999). A voluntary participation game with a non-excludable public good. Journal of Economic Theory, 84, 227–242.CrossRef Saijo, T., & Yamato, T. (1999). A voluntary participation game with a non-excludable public good. Journal of Economic Theory, 84, 227–242.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Saijo, T., & Yamato, T. (2010). Fundamental impossibility theorems on voluntary participation in the provision of non-excludable public goods. Review of Economic Design, 14, 51–73.CrossRef Saijo, T., & Yamato, T. (2010). Fundamental impossibility theorems on voluntary participation in the provision of non-excludable public goods. Review of Economic Design, 14, 51–73.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Samuelson, P. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. Review of Economic Statistics, 36, 387–389.CrossRef Samuelson, P. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. Review of Economic Statistics, 36, 387–389.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sandler, T. (1992). Collective action. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Sandler, T. (1992). Collective action. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Sandler, T., & Hartley, K. (2001). Economics of alliances: The lessons for collective action. Journal of Economic Literature, 39, 869–896.CrossRef Sandler, T., & Hartley, K. (2001). Economics of alliances: The lessons for collective action. Journal of Economic Literature, 39, 869–896.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shapiro, C. (1989). Theories of oligopoly behavior. In R. Schmalensee & R. D. Willig (Eds.), Handbook of industrial organization v. 1. Amsterdam: North Holland. Shapiro, C. (1989). Theories of oligopoly behavior. In R. Schmalensee & R. D. Willig (Eds.), Handbook of industrial organization v. 1. Amsterdam: North Holland.
Zurück zum Zitat Stigler, G. J. (1974). Free riders and collective action: An appendix to theories of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5, 359–365.CrossRef Stigler, G. J. (1974). Free riders and collective action: An appendix to theories of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5, 359–365.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sugden, R. (1982). On the economics of philanthropy. Economic Journal, 92, 341–350.CrossRef Sugden, R. (1982). On the economics of philanthropy. Economic Journal, 92, 341–350.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Teisl, M. F., Roe, B., & Hicks, R. L. (2002). Can eco-labels tune a market? Evidence from dolphin-safe labeling. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43, 339–359.CrossRef Teisl, M. F., Roe, B., & Hicks, R. L. (2002). Can eco-labels tune a market? Evidence from dolphin-safe labeling. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43, 339–359.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Van Essen, M. (2013). Regulating the anticommons: Insights from public expenditure theory. Southern Economic Journal, 80, 523–539. Van Essen, M. (2013). Regulating the anticommons: Insights from public expenditure theory. Southern Economic Journal, 80, 523–539.
Zurück zum Zitat Warr, P. G. (1983). The private provision of a public good is independent of the distribution of income. Economics Letters, 13, 207–211.CrossRef Warr, P. G. (1983). The private provision of a public good is independent of the distribution of income. Economics Letters, 13, 207–211.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Olson’s Logic of Collective Action at fifty
verfasst von
Paul Pecorino
Publikationsdatum
01.03.2015
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 3-4/2015
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-014-0186-y

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3-4/2015

Public Choice 3-4/2015 Zur Ausgabe

Editorial announcement

Editorial announcement

Commisioned Editorial Commentary

Remembering Gordon Tullock

Commissioned Editorial Commentary

Thanks to Gordon Tullock