Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Small Business Economics 2/2018

Open Access 06.03.2018

Habitual entrepreneurs in the making: how labour market rigidity and employment affects entrepreneurial re-entry

verfasst von: Kun Fu, Anne-Sophie Larsson, Karl Wennberg

Erschienen in: Small Business Economics | Ausgabe 2/2018

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We investigate the impact of country-level labour market regulations on the re-entry decision of experienced entrepreneurs, whereby they become habitual entrepreneurs. Multilevel logit models on entry decisions among 15,709 individuals in 29 European countries show that labour market regulations have a positive influence on the decision to re-enter into entrepreneurship. This positive impact is stronger among individuals holding wage jobs at the time of re-entry compared to those that do not. Our results indicate that novice and habitual entrepreneurs may respond very differently to labour market rigidity. We discuss and provide tentative explanations for these differences and outline potential policy implications.
Begleitmaterial
Hinweise

Electronic supplementary material

The online version of this article (https://​doi.​org/​10.​1007/​s11187-018-0011-y) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

1 Introduction

Entrepreneurship is not necessarily a one-off activity. An important group of entrepreneurs is those that have some form of prior start-up experience. These are often called ‘habitual entrepreneurs’, defined as those who have established at least one other business prior to the current one (Birley and Westhead 1993). Within this category, further classifications such as ‘portfolio’ and ‘serial’ entrepreneurs have been used to describe entrepreneurs managing one or multiple businesses at a time (Parker 2013).1 Habitual entrepreneurship is a sizeable and pervasive phenomenon, suggested by Ucbasaran et al. (2008) to comprise about 12 to 52% of entrepreneurial endeavours in the UK, about 51 to 64% in the USA, 49% in Australia, 40 to 50% in the Nordic countries, and 39% in Malaysia. Looking at the sub-group of serial entrepreneurship, studies have revealed that it accounts for 18 to 30% of the entrepreneurial activity in Europe (Westhead and Wright 1998; Westhead et al. 2005; Plehn-Dujowich 2010).2 These entrepreneurs are of particular importance since they have been found to be more likely to identify valuable opportunities (Shane 2003; Ucbasaran et al. 2003), demonstrate higher growth expectations (Westhead et al. 2005), and generate better economic returns (Toft-Kehler et al. 2014) than novice entrepreneurs. Economic and managerial studies alike suggest that these advantages accrue due to ‘learning by doing’ (Toft-Kehler et al. 2014; Lafontaine and Shaw 2016) since entrepreneurial skills are difficult to learn before to entry.
Although many differences have been identified between novice and experienced entrepreneurs in terms of their demographics (Westhead and Wright 1998), attitudes (McGrath and MacMillan 2000), and behaviours (e.g. Wiklund and Shepherd 2008), there are few systematic studies on how the institutional context affects the re-entry decision of experienced entrepreneurs. This is an important gap in the literature since habitual entrepreneurs are often heralded as the ones most likely to attract external equity and scale their ventures into fast-growing companies (Toft-Kehler et al. 2014; Lafontaine and Shaw 2016). The lack of attention to external contingencies such as prevailing institutions and regulations in studies of habitual entrepreneurship is problematic since they are arguably more generalizable than more heterogeneous individual-specific factors. Further, institutional determinants of habitual entrepreneurship ought to be of particular interest to policy makers seeking to enhance not only the quantity but also the quality of entrepreneurial endeavours in the economy (Henrekson and Johansson 2008; Shane 2009).
Departing from a career choice perspective on entrepreneurship, we model habitual entrepreneurship as an occupational choice embedded within the context of prevailing labour market regulations at the country level (Kim et al. 2016). Such regulations can, at least in the short term,3 have great impact on the rate of job creation and unemployment of an economy, labour productivity and social protection of employees, and costs and profits of employers (Betcherman et al. 2001). Whilst earlier empirical evidence on the relationship between labour market regulation and entrepreneurship is somewhat dispersed (Román et al. 2011),4 several recent studies have shown that stringent labour market regulations decrease individuals’ likelihood of becoming entrepreneurs (Van Stel et al. 2007; Bosma 2009; Bosma and Schutjens 2009; Ardagna and Lusardi 2010).
Under this framework, we ask how is the re-entry decision into entrepreneurship of an individual with prior start-up experience affected by the rigidity of labour market regulations at the country level? We further explore whether this effect has a consistent pattern across different employment statuses, as a significant amount of individuals choose to become entrepreneurs whilst retaining their wage jobs (Folta et al. 2010). We argue that labour market rigidity influence the re-entry of experienced entrepreneurs and, furthermore, that the magnitude of this influence depends on the work status of an individual at the moment of re-entry. Employed individuals will respond differently to regulatory rigidity primarily because the costs and benefits from occupational changes differ from those that are not employed (Amit et al. 1995). Whilst being employed results in higher opportunity costs than not being employed when re-entering into entrepreneurship, having a job upon entry may also serve to alleviate liquidity constraints (Petrova 2012) and may signal ability since foregoing paid employment under strict labour market regulations is a decision likely to be well thought through (Bublitz et al. 2015). We suggest that these factors make employed ex-entrepreneurs more likely to become habitual entrepreneurs. Supportive of these arguments, we find the effect of stringent labour market regulations to be stronger among those who hold a salaried job upon re-entry. The more rigid the regulations, the larger the difference in re-entry likelihood of employed and non-employed individuals is.
We employ multilevel modelling to test our hypotheses drawing upon several large-scale datasets from national surveys on entrepreneurship. We use the GEM Adult Population Survey (APS) for individual-level data and the World Bank’s Ease of Doing Business (WBEDB) dataset on employment rigidity for national-level data on labour market regulation. Both samples cover the period from 2006 to 2010. From the GEM survey, we focus on all individuals with prior entrepreneurial experience, in a total of 15,709 observations from 29 European countries.
Our study contributes to the entrepreneurship research in the following ways. First, we explore the nuances by which institutional constraints such as labour market regulations may affect various types of entrepreneurship in differing ways, explicitly focusing on individuals with prior entrepreneurial experience—frequently depicted as high-potential entrepreneurs. Second, we show that the effects of such contextual barriers on the macro level may be contingent on individuals’ work status, in this case, whether ex-entrepreneurs enter from paid employment or not. Third, our study provides nuance to the occupational choice literature, which, by and large, has viewed wage work and self-employment as discrete choices, overlooking the importance of individuals who enter into entrepreneurship whilst concurrently in employment (Burke et al. 2008; Folta et al. 2010; Petrova 2012). We contribute to this stream of literature by demonstrating how these ‘hybrid entrepreneurs’ may be differently affected by the prevailing labour market regulations in their society (Schulza et al. 2016).

2 Theory and hypotheses

2.1 Entrepreneurship as a career choice

Economists, sociologists, and management scholars alike have for long modelled individuals’ entrepreneurship from the perspective of their occupational choice (Lucas Jr 1978; Douglas and Shepherd 2002; Plehn-Dujowich 2010; Burton et al. 2016). This perspective can be understood as “the vocational decision process in terms of the individual’s decision to enter an occupation as a wage or salaried individual or a self-employed one” (Katz 1992, p. 30).
Studies rooted in the economic literature regard career choices as based on the trade-off between relative costs and benefits associated with different career options. When faced with several occupational options, individuals tend to choose a job (e.g. employment or self-employment) that can maximize their economic and non-economic utility. Individuals will choose entrepreneurship if the expected utility of self-employment exceeds that of other options (Douglas and Shepherd 2000, 2002; Plehn-Dujowich 2010). This decision has also been shown to be affected by factors such as individuals’ psychological attributes and skills (Lazear 2004; Parker 2009; Åstebro and Thompson 2011), social networks (Katz 1992), and human capital (Shane 2003). The movement between entrepreneurship and paid employment has, furthermore, been proven quite common. Instead of being treated as an end state (Earle and Sakova 2000), entrepreneurial career choice has increasingly been investigated from a transition and mobility angle (Douglas and Shepherd 2002; Sørensen and Fassiotto 2011), where individuals can switch between different occupational options. For example, a potential entrepreneur may decide to take on a salaried job following a utility-maximising strategy and switch to self-employment once it emerges as the best option at a given time (e.g. a good opportunity appears, funding key partners or personnel becomes available) (Douglas and Shepherd 2002). If entrepreneurship becomes less beneficial and rewarding, the entrepreneur may consider leaving the current venture and seek employment at an established firm (Burton et al. 2016). Habitual entrepreneurship can, in part, be viewed as an outcome of this process.
To date, few studies have explicitly modelled the occupational choice of habitual entrepreneurs. In a formal model, Plehn-Dujowich (2010) argues that entrepreneurial skills and business quality are complementary to each other. High-skilled entrepreneurs become serial entrepreneurs through constantly looking for high-quality ventures that generate a high expected value (profit), whilst low-skilled ones will not become serial entrepreneurs. However, such a formal model does not square very well with the existing evidence where low-skilled individuals often seem to be driven out of the labour market and therefore engage in multiple or serial necessity-driven entrepreneurial activities (Gottschalk et al. 2017). Parker (2014) developed a more comprehensive career choice model that allowed for the possibility that individuals may explore multiple entrepreneurial opportunities at the same time. The current study builds upon and extends this line of discussion by including the situation where employment and entrepreneurial opportunities are pursued simultaneously.

2.2 Labour market regulation and entrepreneurial career choice

Institutional economics depicts labour market institutions as parts of the ‘rules of the game’ for conducting business, regulating the costs and benefits of certain economic activities. Entrepreneurs as economic actors are embedded within this context. Research has shown that economic, political, or sociocultural conditions at the national level influence individuals’ decisions of whether and how to pursue entrepreneurial opportunities (Levie and Autio 2011; Urbano and Alvarez 2014) and that a favourable institutional context increases the incidence of high-quality entrepreneurship that has great potential of contributing to the society (Baumol 1990; Henrekson and Johansson 2008, 2010; Autio and Fu 2015).
Labour market regulations cover a wide range of rights and responsibilities of the parties involved in the labour market for the purpose of efficiency or equity. Such regulations can have great impact on the rate of job creation and unemployment of an economy, labour productivity and social protection of employees, as well as cost and profits of employers (Betcherman et al. 2001).
The economic literature on the effects of labour market regulations,5 especially on hiring and firing and (un)employment, is vast. Stringent employment protection has been argued to stabilize employment, perhaps especially through reducing firings in recessions. Empirical studies have shown that regulatory stringency tends to be associated with less turnover and job reallocation (Von Below and Thoursie 2010; Bassanini and Garnero 2013).
Stringent labour market regulations have also been argued to deter firm growth and job creation (Pierre and Scarpetta 2004; Henrekson et al. 2010), and empirical findings show that increased regulatory flexibility, at least in the short term, can have a job-creating effect (Boeri and Garibaldi 2007) and increase productivity (Autor et al. 2007; Bassanini et al. 2009). The empirical evidence on the relationship between labour market regulation and entrepreneurship is, however, relatively sparse. We conducted a literature review by keyword searches and summarize the recent studies using comparable data in Table 1.
Table 1
Prior study on labour market rigidity and entrepreneurial activities that utilize the GEM data
Study
Sample
Level of analysis
Measures of labour market rigidity
Measure(s) of entrepreneurship
Findings
LMR
Employment status
Ardagna and Lusardi (2010)
GEM data at the individual level (116,978 observations over 37 [predominantly high-income] countries) in 2001–2002
Individual
Self-constructed synthetic labour indicator composed of hiring and firing indices + firing costs and rigidity of labour contracts (all 4 for 2003 from the WBDB database) and union density for 1997
3 measures: total entrepreneurial activity, opportunity entrepreneurial activity, and remedial (necessity) entrepreneurial activity
A negative interaction effect on individual characteristics such that regulation plays a critical role in the individual decision to start a new business, particularly for opportunity entrepreneurs
Unemployed individuals, students, and retired and disabled individuals are less likely to become entrepreneurs than individuals who work (the effect is stronger on opportunity than remedial entrepreneurs)
Bosma (2009)
GEM data at the individual level (359,469 observations over 131 regions in 16 European countries) during 2001–2006
Individual
OECD employment protection index (version 2) 2003
2 measures: low- and high-growth-oriented early-stage entrepreneurial activity
A strong negative relationship between employment protection and growth-oriented entrepreneurship
No significant effects on low-growth-oriented entrepreneurship
Unemployed individuals, students, and retired people are less inclined than those employed to become involved in entrepreneurship (both high- and low-growth oriented)
Bosma and Schutjens (2009)
GEM data for 16 European countries during the years 2001–2006 (121 observations at the regional level for all regressions)
Region, NUTS-1 (19 of the observations are NUTS-2, NUTS-3, or RORa)
OECD employment protection index (version 2) 2003
4 early-stage entrepreneurial activity rates [3 growth orientations (low, modest, and high growth) as well as 1 innovation oriented]
Some evidence of negative impact of employment protection on growth- and innovation-oriented entrepreneurships
No significant effects on low- and medium-oriented entrepreneurships
n/a
Van Stel et al. (2007)
GEM data for 39 developed and developing countries during the years 2002–2005 (109–112 country-level observations across model specifications)
Country
Employment rigidity index from the World Bank + variable ‘firing costs’ supplementary analysis of the nascent entrepreneurship
3 entrepreneurial activity rates: necessity-driven nascent entrepreneurs, opportunity-driven nascent entrepreneurs, and young businesses to total businesses
Strong negative effects on opportunity and young entrepreneurial rates of ‘rigidity of employment’, and a strong negative effect of ‘rigidity of hours’ on necessity entrepreneurs
However, there is also a somewhat counter-intuitive finding that firing costs have a positive effect on necessity rates
n/a
aROR (Raumordnungsregionen) is a German regional classification that indicates labour market areas; the RORs lie between NUTS-2 and NUTS-3 level (Bosma 2009, appendix 1).
Table 1 shows that, with somewhat varying results, all of the recent studies that utilize the GEM data indicate that stringent labour market regulations can have negative effects on entrepreneurial activity. Using the GEM data for 39 countries during the years 2002–2005, Van Stel et al. (2007) found a strong negative effect of stringent labour market regulations—in terms of rigidity of employment and rigidity of hours—on entrepreneurship rates. A study by Bosma and Schutjens (2009) on Dutch regions found that labour protection has strong adverse effects on the level of growth-oriented entrepreneurship but found no effect on ‘low growth-oriented early-stage entrepreneurship activity’.6 In another study, Bosma (2009) found a strong negative relationship between employment protection and growth-oriented entrepreneurship, but no significant effects on low-growth-oriented entrepreneurship, using a similar multilevel methodology as in the current paper. Ardagna and Lusardi (2010) used the GEM data for 37 predominantly high-income countries in 2001–2002 and found that labour market regulations curtail the otherwise strong and positive effects of social networks, especially for opportunity entrepreneurs.
These results are in line with earlier findings that have shown that stringent labour market regulation can decrease individuals’ likelihood of becoming entrepreneurs as the earning risk in self-employment is much higher than that in paid employment (Parker 1997). All of the studies that we have surveyed have studied either novice or nascent and, sometimes, young, entrepreneurial activity.7 Distinctions based on motivation (opportunity or necessity) and growth aspirations (high or low) are frequent, but to the best of our knowledge, no previous study has singled out the effects of labour market regulations on habitual entrepreneurs.
Given the sparsity of empirical literature on the potential effects of labour market rigidity on individuals’ likelihood of re-entering into entrepreneurship, we turn to the general economic literature on the effects of employment protection as guidance for theorising. This literature suggests that higher labour market rigidity may lead to increased hiring costs and more complex recruitment processes: increasing the requirements for employment and dampening the demand for labour (Autor et al. 2007), effectively raising the thresholds for, and decreasing the probability of, attaining paid employment (Lindbeck and Snower 1986).
Individuals with entrepreneurial experiences often have career breaks due to having taken time off to develop their own business (Hyytinen and Rouvinen 2008). The relevance and consistency of their work experiences can therefore sometimes be called into question when they try to make a shift from self-employed to wage earners. Entrepreneurs tend to be characterised as ‘jacks-of-all-trades’ with a balanced skill set (Lazear 2004), a feature that potential employers may, however, equate with a lack of specialisation and expertise (Åstebro and Thompson 2011). Employers may also shun individuals with entrepreneurial experiences as potentially difficult to retain, effectively deterring them from hiring ex-entrepreneurs in the first place. Consequently, the search costs of a wage employment for individuals with entrepreneurial experience increase substantially.
These theoretical mechanisms are likely to be exacerbated by rigid regulations that make employers ‘err on the side of caution’. The stricter the labour market regulations, the more likely former entrepreneurs are to be excluded from employment opportunities, increasing their likelihood to enter self-employment again, effectively becoming habitual entrepreneurs. We thus propose
  • Hypothesis 1: Among individuals with entrepreneurial experiences, high country-level labour market rigidity increases individuals’ likelihood of entrepreneurial re-entry.

2.3 Entrepreneurship and concurrent employment status

Occupational choices are, however, not mutually exclusive. Occupational choice theory tends to assume that individuals will choose between paid employment, self-employment, or unemployment one at a time depending on the cost and benefit associated with each occupational option (i.e. Douglas and Shepherd 2002). However, people have been shown to often start a new business whilst retaining a wage-earning job. When possible, retaining a salaried job whilst engaging in an entrepreneurial activity provides people with complementary income and offers the possibility to learn more about the new venture and the personal fit with the new business whilst minimising sunk cost (Folta et al. 2010; Raffiee and Feng 2014). Stable income from employment allows individuals to have a transition stage from part-time to full-time entrepreneurship and may serve to alleviate liquidity constraints in the early stage of the new venture (Colombo and Grilli 2007; Petrova 2012; Frid et al. 2016). Furthermore, having paid employment sends signals of ability which is important for potential stakeholders when launching a new venture (Bublitz et al. 2015). Empirical findings by Bosma and Schutjens (2009) and Ardagna and Lusardi (2010) support the notion that employment status plays a role in the decision of becoming an entrepreneur: unemployed individuals, students, and retired individuals are overall less likely to become entrepreneurs than employed individuals are. This rationale should be especially relevant for individuals with prior entrepreneurial experiences who have learned about the time necessary to start a new venture and the financial costs this may incur (Kim et al. 2006). We therefore propose
  • Hypothesis 2: Among individuals with entrepreneurial experiences, being employed, either part-time or full-time, increases individuals’ likelihood of entrepreneurial re-entry.
It is also possible that employed and non-employed individuals will respond differently to the rigidity of labour market regulations when considering a potential re-entry into entrepreneurship.
Higher labour market rigidity not only increases the cost of firms hiring people but also implies increased costs for dismissals, sometimes equated to a tax on firing (Autor et al. 2007). Faced with such costs, dismissals tend to become less frequent and the demand for labour dampened, at least in the short run. As such, stringent employment protection is often associated with lower productivity, especially when it comes to the regulatory rigidity of regular contracts (Bassanini et al. 2009). Strict employment protection could thus offer employed individuals the opportunity to, at least temporarily, decrease their job effort without great risk of being laid off, fostering a beneficial situation for early-stage hybrid entrepreneurship. This effect is also likely to be exacerbated when coupled with strong restrictions on the maximum length of working days and hours, night and weekend work, and vacation days as this will grant employees more flexibility to allocate their time. When overwork is restricted, people’s earnings are also limited. They will try to find other ways to gain supplemental income. The more rigid the labour market regulation, the more flexibility and security the employees will gain, whilst increasing the need for supplemental income. Based on the above analyses, we propose that
  • Hypothesis 3: Among individuals with entrepreneurial experiences, the effect of labour market rigidity on individuals’ likelihood of becoming habitual entrepreneurs depends on their employment status, such that the positive effect of regulatory rigidity is stronger for individuals holding a wage job upon entrepreneurial re-entry.

3 Methods

3.1 Data and sample

We use the GEM APS for individual-level data on entrepreneurship. The GEM is an annual survey collecting micro-individual-level data on entrepreneurial attitudes, activities, and aspirations (Reynolds et al. 2005). This database covers a yearly random sample of working-age adults (18–64 years old) in all 29 countries under investigation over the periods 2006 to 2010. We draw the sample from the population that has indicated that they have prior entrepreneurial experience. The GEM questionnaire captures this information by asking: “Have you alone or with other, started business in the past that you owned and managed?” There are, in total, 15,709 observations included in the sample. We use the WBEDB dataset for the same time period, which records three elements of employment rigidity index: difficulty of hiring index, rigidity of hours index, and difficulty of firing index that reflect the rigidity in the regulation of employment in a given country (Botero et al. 2004).

3.2 Variables and measures

3.2.1 Dependent variable

Entrepreneurial re-entry
Our dependent variable of focus is the re-entry into entrepreneurship by an individual with prior entrepreneurial experience (Birley and Westhead 1993), measured by a dummy variable taking the value 1 for re-entry and 0 otherwise.

3.2.2 Independent variables

Labour market rigidity
Labour market rigidity captures the flexibility in the regulations of employment in a given country. It is measured by the employment rigidity index from the WBEDB, which is based on the average value of three sub-indices: a difficulty of hiring index, a rigidity of hours index, and a difficulty of firing index, with higher values indicating more rigid labour market regulation. Similarly to Van Stel et al. (2007), who used similar variables for their country-level analysis, we rely solely on the employment rigidity index and not the three separate indices from the WBEDB since these are highly collinear.
Employment status
Current main employment status or current working situation for each individual was coded into seven categories: full-time work, part-time work, unemployed, retired or disabled, student, homemaker, or other (Bosma et al. 2012). Based on the above information, individuals with prior entrepreneurial experience are grouped into one of two broader categories: those who are employed (i.e. those currently engaged in part- or full-time work) and those who are not employed (i.e. all others).

3.2.3 Control variables

Individual-level control variables
We control for a set of individual-level variables related with one’s propensity of participating in entrepreneurial activities. Age of an individual is measured in years. Gender takes the value 1 for females and 0 for males. Education takes the values of 1, 2, 3, 4, and 5 for individuals that have received the following: no education, primary education, secondary education, post-secondary, and graduate education, respectively. Household income takes the values of 1, 2, and 3 for the lowest-, middle-, and highest-income tiers in the population, respectively. Fear of failure indicates whether fear of failure would prevent the individual from setting up a business (1 = yes, 0 = otherwise). Entrepreneurial knowledge and skills indicates if the individual perceived himself or herself as having the required skills and knowledge to start a new business (1 = yes, 0 = otherwise).
Country-level control variables
We control for the TEA rate—the prevalence rate of total early-stage entrepreneurial activities in a country—as the relative presence of entrepreneurs likely affects individuals’ likelihood of engaging in entrepreneurship (Bird and Wennberg 2014). Several macro-economic factors associated with entrepreneurial activities have been introduced into the models as control variables as they have been shown to have a significant impact on the nature of entrepreneurial activity (Autio and Fu 2015). Since a country’s wealth has been shown to influence the prevalence of entrepreneurial activity, we control for GDP per capita (USD) adjusted for purchasing power parity (PPP), and annual GDP growth rate (Levie and Autio 2011). Population growth captures the growth of potential market, measured as the annual percentage population growth rate in a country. Finally, we control for the institutional effect of ease of starting a business as well as current unemployment rate, both from the World Bank datasets.

3.3 Data analyses

We employ multilevel regressions for testing the hypotheses due to the hierarchical structure of the dataset where individual-level observations are unevenly nested in countries (Hofmann et al. 2000). A two-level model with random intercept is specified to assess the variation in the probability of becoming a habitual entrepreneur by factoring in both the impact of labour market regulations at the country level and the influence of work status at the individual level. The model is specified as
Level 1 equation:
$$ {Y}_{ij}={\beta}_{0j}+{\beta}_{1j}{X}_{ij}+{e}_{ij} $$
Level 2 equation:
$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{\beta}_{0j}={\gamma}_{00}+{\gamma}_{01}{W}_j+{u}_{0j}\\ {}{\beta}_{1j}={\gamma}_{10}+{u}_{1j}\end{array}} $$
The level 1 equation predicts the direct effects (i.e. betas) of level 1 predictors on level 1 outcomes, where Yij is the dependent variable for an individual observation at level 1. Xij is the individual-level (level 1) predictor where i refers to the individual and j to the country of residence. β0j is the intercept of the dependent variable in country j (level 2). β1j is the slope for the relationship in country j between the individual-level predictor and the dependent variable. eij is the individual-level residual. The level 2 equations predict the effects (i.e. gammas) of level 2 predictors on level 1 betas as well as on the level 1 intercept, where γ00 is the overall intercept, which is the mean of the intercepts across countries. Wj is the country-level predictor. γ01 is the slope or main effect of country-level predictor. γ10 is the slope or main effect of individual-level predictor. u0j and u1j are country-level residuals.
Multilevel equation of the current study
$$ {Y}_{ij}={\gamma}_{00+}{\gamma}_{01}\mathrm{Labor}\ \mathrm{market}\ {\mathrm{rigidity}}_j+{\gamma}_{02}\mathrm{GDP}\ \mathrm{per}\ {\mathrm{capita}}_j+{\gamma}_{03}\mathrm{GDP}\ {\mathrm{growth}}_j+{\gamma}_{04}\mathrm{Population}\ {\mathrm{growth}}_j+{\gamma}_{05}\mathrm{Ease}\ \mathrm{of}\ \mathrm{starting}\ \mathrm{a}\ {\mathrm{business}}_j+{\gamma}_{06}\mathrm{Unemployment}\ {\mathrm{rate}}_j+{\gamma}_{07}\mathrm{TEA}\ {\mathrm{rate}}_j+{\gamma}_{10}\mathrm{Employment}\ {\mathrm{status}}_{ij}+{\gamma}_{20}{\mathrm{Gender}}_{ij}+{\gamma}_{30}{\mathrm{Age}}_{ij}+{\gamma}_{40}{\mathrm{Income}}_{ij}+{\gamma}_{50}{\mathrm{Education}}_{ij}+{\gamma}_{60}\mathrm{Fear}\ \mathrm{of}\ {\mathrm{failure}}_{ij}+{\gamma}_{70}\mathrm{Entrepreneurial}\ {\mathrm{skills}}_{ij}+{u}_{0j}+{e}_{ij} $$
To facilitate the interpretation of meaningful effects, we computed average marginal effects (AMEs) for all independent variables. For continuous variables such as labour market rigidity, AMEs represent the instantaneous rate of change for the variable of interest. Since it is more informative to show the predictive margins over a set of values of variables of interest (Brambor et al. 2006), we calculated the predicted probability of the habitual entrepreneurship over a set of observed values of labour market rigidity and present the results graphically.

4 Results

Before zooming into our analyses, some overall trends are noteworthy to report. Descriptive statistics based on the GEM data over the periods 2001 to 2010 (overlapping our period of analysis) indicates that throughout Europe, the prevalence rate of opportunity-driven entrepreneurship (12.12%) is nearly three times higher among individuals with prior entrepreneurial experience than the rate among those who have not started any business before (3.55%). Among those currently owning and managing a business, habitual entrepreneurs are more likely to have a business with a product innovation (46.61 vs. 40.66%) and a higher growth expectation (15.66 vs. 10.03%) than the novice entrepreneurs.
Table 2 shows the average value of labour market rigidity measured across 5 years in the 29 European countries of our sample, with higher values indicating more rigid labour market regulation. In our data, France is the most rigid country in terms of labour market regulation and Denmark the most flexible.
Table 2
Descriptive data on country-level labour market rigidity and entrepreneurial activities
Country
Habitual entrepreneurship (%)
Total early-stage entrepreneurship (%)
Labour market rigidity (mean)
Denmark
0.13
0.05
3.33
UK
0.18
0.04
4.04
Switzerland
0.17
0.06
5.14
Belgium
0.12
0.03
10.33
Ireland
0.22
0.07
10.33
Hungary
0.18
0.06
13.27
Montenegro
0.22
0.15
13.33
Czech Republic
0.15
0.06
14.44
Iceland
0.25
0.11
14.98
Austria
0.13
0.04
20.33
Russia
0.20
0.04
27.78
Germany
0.18
0.05
27.78
Sweden
0.21
0.03
29.50
Bosnia and Herzegovina
0.17
0.06
31.31
Serbia
0.18
0.05
32.22
Turkey
0.16
0.06
35.17
Macedonia
0.22
0.09
35.40
Finland
0.22
0.05
37.61
Latvia
0.27
0.07
37.62
Portugal
0.26
0.06
38.96
Italy
0.12
0.04
40.04
Romania
0.26
0.03
40.18
Netherlands
0.19
0.04
42.22
Slovenia
0.14
0.04
42.90
Norway
0.22
0.06
43.01
Croatia
0.23
0.05
43.67
Greece
0.18
0.07
44.25
Spain
0.25
0.06
49.48
France
0.12
0.03
55.14
We plotted ‘caterpillar’ graphs to show the country-level variances in habitual entrepreneurial activity (Fig. 1), finding that the levels of habitual entrepreneurship vary significantly across the European countries. There are five countries with confidence intervals distinctly lower than 0, in particular for Denmark, France, and Belgium, and five countries with confidence intervals distinctly higher than 0, Spain and Latvia being the most prominent ones.
Table 3 provides descriptive statistics for all the explanatory and control variables in the current study. Table 4 shows the correlation matrix for the individual-level variables and country-level controls and predictors. Variance inflation factors (VIFs) for all variables were between 1.05 and 2.57, indicating a low risk of multicollinearity.
Table 3
Descriptive statistics
Variable
Mean
Std. Dev.
Min
Max
Entrepreneurial re-entry
0.20
0.40
0
1
Employed
0.74
0.44
0
1
Labour market rigidity
27.49
18.82
0
55.56
Gender (female = 1)
0.40
0.49
0
1
Age
44.67
11.32
18
64
Income 1 (middle tier)
0.36
0.48
0
1
Income 2 (top tier)
0.35
0.48
0
1
Education
3.43
1.07
1
5
Fear of failure
0.31
0.46
0
1
Entrepreneurial knowledge and skills
0.83
0.38
0
1
TEA rate
0.06
0.02
0.02
0.15
Log-transformed GDP per capita
10.29
0.40
9.06
11.02
GDP growth
1.87
3.20
− 17.95
12.23
Population growth
0.75
0.67
− 0.55
2.53
Ease of starting a business
81.97
9.42
58.19
94.08
Unemployment rate
8.60
5.61
2.25
33.80
All descriptive statistics based on N = 15,709
Table 4
Correlation matrix
 
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
1
Entrepreneurial re-entry
               
2
Employed
0.18
              
3
Labour market rigidity
0.05
− 0.04
             
4
Gender
− 0.10
− 0.13
0.001
            
5
Age
− 0.14
− 0.15
− 0.08
− 0.002
           
6
Income 1 (middle tier)
− 0.02
0.06
− 0.03
− 0.005
− 0.01
          
7
Income 2 (top tier)
0.09
0.16
0.02
− 0.10
− 0.03
− 0.55
         
8
Education
0.07
0.14
− 0.07
− 0.01
− 0.05
− 0.04
0.18
        
9
Fear of failure
− 0.09
− 0.05
0.10
0.09
− 0.06
0.02
− 0.08
− 0.05
       
10
Entrepreneurial knowledge and skills
0.13
0.10
0.00
− 0.13
0.00
− 0.02
0.10
0.09
− 0.17
      
11
TEA rate
0.08
0.05
0.18
0.00
− 0.06
0.00
0.05
− 0.04
0.03
0.02
     
12
Log-transformed GDP per capita
0.00
0.18
− 0.23
0.02
0.13
− 0.01
− 0.01
0.06
− 0.02
− 0.002
− 0.21
    
13
GDP growth
0.01
0.05
− 0.04
0.01
− 0.004
0.03
− 0.05
− 0.002
− 0.05
− 0.005
0.08
− 0.18
   
14
Population growth
0.06
0.14
0.11
0.02
− 0.01
0.01
− 0.04
0.01
0.01
− 0.001
0.28
0.42
0.08
  
15
Ease of starting a business
− 0.04
0.04
− 0.64
− 0.03
0.06
0.01
0.02
0.08
− 0.12
− 0.03
− 0.18
0.28
0.01
− 0.03
 
16
Unemployment rate
0.00
− 0.18
0.40
0.00
− 0.11
0.02
0.00
− 0.08
0.07
0.03
0.27
− 0.67
− 0.11
− 0.24
− 0.46
N = 15,709
Table 5 shows results from the multilevel logit model. Model 1 in Table 5 is the baseline model including control variables only. Model 2 shows the main effects with key explanatory variables, and model 3 shows the cross-level interaction results.
Table 5
Results of multilevel logistic regressions: habitual entrepreneurship
Outcome: entrepreneurial re-entry
Model 1
Average marginal effect
Model 2
Average marginal effect
Model 3
Average marginal effect
Employed
  
2.766*** (0.184)
0.140*** (0.010)
2.740*** (0.182)
0.139*** (0.010)
Labour market rigidity
  
1.173* (0.081)
0.022* (0.009)
0.979 (0.089)
− 0.003 (0.013)
Employed × labour market rigidity
    
1.227** (0.083)
0.028** (0.009)
Gender
0.617*** (0.033)
− 0.069*** (0.007)
0.680*** (0.031)
− 0.053*** (0.006)
0.682*** (0.031)
− 0.053*** (0.006)
Age
0.693*** (0.017)
− 0.052*** (0.004)
0.719*** (0.016)
− 0.045*** (0.003)
0.719*** (0.016)
− 0.045*** (0.003)
Income 1 (middle tier)
1.255 (0.187)
0.032 (0.021)
1.020 (0.058)
0.003 (0.008)
1.025 (0.058)
0.003 (0.008)
Income 2 (top tier)
1.559** (0.212)
0.063** (0.020)
1.257*** (0.072)
0.031*** (0.008)
1.263*** (0.072)
0.032*** (0.008)
Education
1.109*** (0.026)
0.015*** (0.003)
1.085*** (0.023)
0.011*** (0.003)
1.082*** (0.023)
0.011*** (0.003)
Fear of failure
0.681*** (0.049)
− 0.055*** (0.010)
0.641*** (0.032)
− 0.061*** (0.007)
0.642*** (0.032)
− 0.061*** (0.007)
Entrepreneurial knowledge and skills
2.342*** (0.195)
0.121*** (0.011)
2.438*** (0.183)
0.123*** (0.011)
2.439*** (0.183)
0.123*** (0.011)
TEA rate
1.332*** (0.098)
0.041*** (0.011)
1.249*** (0.050)
0.031*** (0.005)
1.244*** (0.049)
0.030*** (0.005)
GDP per capita (log-transformed)
0.797** (0.070)
− 0.032* (0.013)
0.829** (0.053)
− 0.026** (0.009)
0.833** (0.053)
− 0.025** (0.009)
GDP growth
0.968 (0.031)
− 0.005 (0.005)
0.963 (0.024)
− 0.005 (0.003)
0.963 (0.024)
− 0.005 (0.003)
Population growth
1.045 (0.097)
0.006 (0.013)
1.045 (0.052)
0.006 (0.007)
1.044 (0.052)
0.006 (0.007)
Ease of starting a business
0.928 (0.090)
− 0.011 (0.014)
0.972 (0.056)
− 0.004 (0.008)
0.972 (0.055)
− 0.004 (0.008)
Unemployment rate
0.680** (0.088)
− 0.055** (0.018)
0.792*** (0.046)
− 0.032*** (0.008)
0.799*** (0.046)
− 0.031*** (0.008)
Constant
0.161*** (0.027)
 
0.073*** (0.010)
 
0.073*** (0.010)
 
Level 2 variance (SD)
1.109+ (0.069)
 
1.058* (0.024)
 
1.057* (0.023)
 
Individual observations
15,709
15,709
15,709
15,709
15,709
15,709
Number of countries
29
29
29
29
29
29
Standard errors clustered on the country level are enclosed in parentheses. All continuous variables are standardised in the regressions
***p < 0.001; **p < 0.01; *p < 0.05; +p < 0.1
For the main effects we find, as expected, that labour market rigidity is positively related to the probability of entrepreneurial re-entry among experienced entrepreneurs, i.e. becoming habitual entrepreneurs (odds ratios (ORs) = 1.173, p < 0.05; AME = 0.022, p < 0.05). This confirms hypothesis 1 in that rigid labour market regulations increase individuals’ likelihood of re-engaging in entrepreneurial activity. Holding all other variables constant at their observed values, the average marginal effects of labour market rigidity increase the likelihood that experienced entrepreneurs will re-enter by 2.2%.
Turning to the variable ‘employment status’, we find this to be positively related to the probability of entrepreneurial re-entry (OR = 2.766, p < 0.001), supportive of hypothesis 2. Individuals holding wage jobs, either part-time or full-time, are thus more likely of becoming habitual entrepreneurs. The average marginal effects of employment status increase the likelihood that an experienced individual will again engage in entrepreneurship by 14% (AME = 0.14, p < 0.001).
The cross-level interaction effect between country-level labour market rigidity and individual-level employment status is shown in model 3. This model shows that the effect of labour market rigidity on the probability of entrepreneurial re-entry depends on one’s employment status (OR = 1.227, p < 0.01), meaning that under stringent labour market regulations, individuals that hold wage jobs are more likely to re-enter into entrepreneurship than those who are not employed. We present the interaction effect graphically since it varies with the values of the two interacted variables, as well as with the values of other covariates (Brambor et al. 2006). Figure 2 shows plotted predictive marginal effects of labour market rigidity at a set of observed values for individuals with or without current employment with a 95% confidence interval, revealing that the impact of labour market rigidity on entrepreneurial re-entry is constantly stronger for employed individuals. Figure 3 shows that the differences in the predicted probability over the observed values of labour market rigidity are statistically significant between individuals with or without current employment, supporting hypothesis 3.

4.1 Robustness tests

We conducted a series of robustness tests, available in the Appendix (Online Resource). We specifically examined alternative measures for labour market rigidity, split the sample into necessity and opportunity-driven habitual entrepreneurship, and examined whether entrepreneurial re-entry is dependent on previous entrepreneurial failure or success. We, furthermore, ran our models on all entrepreneurs without start-up experience in the GEM data for the same time period to accommodate an assessment of differing responses to regulatory rigidity among novice and habitual entrepreneurs, as well as to make sure that our results for novice entrepreneurs were in line with previous findings.

5 Discussion

Our study is among the first to focus on institutional factors shaping the entrepreneurial re-entry decisions. The results of our multilevel logit models on entry decisions among 15,709 individuals in 29 European countries show that labour market rigidity is positively associated with re-entry into entrepreneurship. Moreover, employed individuals are more likely to make the re-entry decision under stringent labour market regulation, whilst those who are not employed at the time of re-entry are less likely to do so.
This study is, to the best of our knowledge, the first one to explicitly analyse the effects of labour market regulations on the re-entry decision of individuals’ with previous entrepreneurial experience, frequently depicted as a high-potential group of entrepreneurs. We show that contextual barriers on the macro level—such as labour market regulations—can exert direct impact, as well as indirect impact via the labour status, on individuals’ entrepreneurial re-entry decision. In doing so, the study furthers research on entrepreneurship in general and that of habitual entrepreneurs in particular, highlighting that institutional conditions may need to be incorporated in studies of entrepreneurial occupational choice. Our findings regarding the interaction between labour market regulations and employment status for ex-entrepreneurs’ prospective re-entry into habitual entrepreneurship shed valuable insights on hybrid entrepreneurship and the potential importance of concurrent employment in the early stages of new firm formation (Burke et al. 2008; Folta et al. 2010; Petrova 2012). We demonstrate how these hybrid entrepreneurs may be differently affected by the prevailing labour market regulations in their society (Schulza et al. 2016).
Contrary to previous studies that have found a negative association between rigidity of labour market regulation and individuals’ entrepreneurial activity, we demonstrate that there exists a positive effect of labour market rigidity on the decision to re-enter into entrepreneurship. When dividing the sample based on entrepreneurial motivations in the robustness tests, we found similar statistically significant positive effects of labour market rigidity and employment on both necessity-driven and opportunity-driven habitual entrepreneurship. Our robustness tests of the impact of labour market rigidity on the entry of novice entrepreneurs rendered quite different results: more rigid regulations have a statistically significant negative effect on opportunity-driven entrepreneurship, but no significant effect on necessity-driven entrepreneurship (although the sign was positive). The results in our robustness tests of novice entrepreneurs thus seem to be largely in line with other relatively recent findings of the effects of labour market regulations on entrepreneurship. A likely explanation for the distinct patterns of the effects of labour market regulation on novice and habitual entrepreneurship may be that opportunity-seeking individuals with prior entrepreneurial experience are equipped with greater knowledge, skills, and confidence in identifying potential opportunities and making the re-entry decision, compared to those pursuing their very first ventures. Still, among those with prior experience, there is also a sizeable body of necessity-driven entrepreneurs who may be forced to re-enter into entrepreneurship due to the high thresholds for obtaining paid employment in labour markets with rigid regulations.

5.1 Policy implications

Our results come with both theoretical and policy implications: in economies with rigid labour market regulations, ex-entrepreneurs could be ‘punished’ and thus forced to engage in necessity-driven entrepreneurship due to higher barriers re-entering into employment. Such a pattern would be consistent with other European evidence suggestive of entrepreneurial experience not being seen favorable by employees (Hyytinen and Rouvinen 2008).
In contrast with the negative impacts of labour market regulations on high-potential or high-quality entrepreneurship found by other studies, our study has shown that labour market regulations play a surprisingly positive role in driving ex-entrepreneurs to explore good opportunities again, becoming opportunity-driven habitual entrepreneurs. Knowledge and skills acquired through prior entrepreneurial experiences may help them to more effectively identify emerging opportunities for high-potential businesses (Westhead et al. 2015), as well as foresee and more thoroughly understand the potential risks and costs associated with creating a new venture (Sarasvathy et al. 2013). Holding a salaried job upon entry is a way to reduce opportunity cost and alleviate potential liquidity constraints when launching a new venture (Folta et al. 2010; Raffiee and Feng 2014). The relative importance of having a job upon entry is, however, likely to depend both on the rigidity of labour market regulations and on the capital market available for entrepreneurs (Delmar et al. 2011).
There is also the possibility that (mis)perceptions of regulatory stringency, rather than actual regulatory stringency, may affect novice and habitual entrepreneurs differently. By analysing survey data from 5000 German university students, Moog and Backes-Gellner (2009) showed that the students tend to be overconfident in their knowledge of labour market regulations and that their perceptions often deviate from the actual regulations. These misperceptions greatly affected students’ willingness to become self-employed. The widespread instance of small business exemptions could potentially also be a factor here. A study by Venn (2009), which covered small business exemptions in many of the countries in our sample, showed that the exemptions can be quite far reaching. For instance, in Germany, firms with ten or fewer employees are exempt from regular employment protection legislation; in Italy, firms with less than 15 employees are not required to pay back pay or reinstate employees that have been unfairly dismissed, and the same goes for Turkey, but the cut-off is at 30 employees. Experienced entrepreneurs ought to have greater knowledge of the actual effects of the regulations (e.g. have fewer misperceptions and a better understanding of potential exemptions) and may as such to greater extent discount for, for their intents and purposes, superfluous regulations when making their re-entry decision. Novices, on the other hand, may, due to their inexperience, be more wary of regulatory rigidity, which offers an explanation for why our results differ from previous empirical findings on the effects of labour market regulations on entrepreneurship.
Our study further reveals employment as a key external driver of the re-entry into entrepreneurship. The positive influences of rigid labour market regulations become stronger for those employed upon entry, meaning that non-employed individuals—‘outsiders’ in Lindbeck and Snower’s (1986) terminology—are less likely to re-enter into entrepreneurship when labour market regulations are stringent. Also, this finding comes with policy implications. First, policies that aim to increase employment, in general, may be the most beneficial policy measure for increasing entrepreneurial activity in European countries. Second, many European countries have one-sidedly eased the employment protection for temporary contracts during the last decades, keeping the level of protection for permanent contracts largely intact. An occurrence that may have created more flexibility, yet, at same time, increased the labour market segmentation and deepened the insider-outsider divide (Blanchard and Landier 2002; Cahuc and Postel-Vinay 2002). This type of dualism can have a strong negative impact on already marginalised groups, especially younger individuals, who may be pushed into involuntary temporary employment (Skedinger 2011). Future research may want to pose the question to what extent this type of regulatory dualism also pushes individuals into involuntary entrepreneurship.

5.2 Future research

Future research may also seek to model the effects of labour market rigidity on new ventures that have reached various stages of growth. It is well known that ‘entrepreneurs’ is a heterogeneous group, with most of the entrepreneurs having no or very few employees (Davidsson and Henrekson 2002; Davidsson et al. 2006). Whilst stringent labour market regulations may discourage novice individuals with high growth expectations from engaging in entrepreneurial activities as they may hamper the growth of their firms, there is still limited evidence in regard to how labour market regulations affect entrepreneurial team formation (Held et al. 2018) and start-up growth (Bornhall et al. 2017).
Another interesting pathway for future research is to study other contingencies by which institutional conditions such as labour market regulations affect entrepreneurship. In addition to the conditional effects found for current employment status, other individual-level contingencies such as fear of failure (Ardagna and Lusardi 2010) or perceptions of entrepreneurial status (Autio et al. 2013) may shape the impact of country-level institutions on individuals’ likelihood of entering into, as well as succeeding in, entrepreneurship. Incorporating other institutional contingencies in future research on habitual entrepreneurs holds promise for theoretical advancements and for more successful public policy design.
Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.
Anhänge

Electronic supplementary material

Fußnoten
1
In the academic literature, ‘serial entrepreneurs’ are sometimes defined analogously to habitual entrepreneurs.
 
2
The shares range from 12 to 27% in our sample of European countries based on Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM) data (see Table 2). As GEM does not provide information on whether individuals are simultaneously running multiple firms, we cannot distinguish serial and portfolio entrepreneurs. Our sample is comprised of founders with prior entrepreneurial experience, and as such, it largely covers serial entrepreneurship. However, since we cannot effectively exclude ‘portfolio entrepreneurship’, we use the term ‘habitual entrepreneurship’.
 
3
Economic literature, referenced later on in this paper, shows that labour market regulations tend to affect firing, hiring, and job reallocation and that regulatory changes can affect productivity, job creation, as well as (un)employment rates. These effects may, however, not be persistent over time.
 
4
See, for instance, Román et al. (2011) for a review of earlier findings on the effects of employment protection legislation and Nyström (2014) for a review of studies that have more widely studied the effects of regulations on entrepreneurship.
 
5
Often measured in terms of ‘employment protection legislation’
 
6
Mostly European NUTS-1, and in some instances NUTS-2, NUTS-3, or RORs (Germany), was also included.
 
7
A study by Bjørnskov and Foss (2008) used the 2001 wave of GEM data to investigate the relationship between regulations and entrepreneurship and found no statistically significant effects using a compounded ‘regulatory quality’ variable composed of three sub-indices of the Economic Freedom of the World index. It should be noted that the 2001 GEM data is known to be rather unreliable compared to subsequent years.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Ardagna, S., & Lusardi, A. (2010). Explaining international differences in entrepreneurship: the role of individual characteristics and regulatory constraints. In J. Lerner & A. Schoar (Eds.), International differences in entrepreneurship (pp. 17–62). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRef Ardagna, S., & Lusardi, A. (2010). Explaining international differences in entrepreneurship: the role of individual characteristics and regulatory constraints. In J. Lerner & A. Schoar (Eds.), International differences in entrepreneurship (pp. 17–62). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Autor, D. H., Kerr, W. R., & Kugler, A. D. (2007). Does employment protection reduce productivity? Evidence from US states. The Economic Journal, 117(521), 189–217.CrossRef Autor, D. H., Kerr, W. R., & Kugler, A. D. (2007). Does employment protection reduce productivity? Evidence from US states. The Economic Journal, 117(521), 189–217.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Betcherman, G., Luinstra, A., & Ogawa, M. (2001). Labor market regulation: international experience in promoting employment and social protection. World Bank, Social Protection Discussion Paper Series 128. Betcherman, G., Luinstra, A., & Ogawa, M. (2001). Labor market regulation: international experience in promoting employment and social protection. World Bank, Social Protection Discussion Paper Series 128.
Zurück zum Zitat Blanchard, O., & Landier, A. (2002). The perverse effects of partial labour market reform: fixed-term contracts in France. The Economic Journal, 112(480), F214–F244.CrossRef Blanchard, O., & Landier, A. (2002). The perverse effects of partial labour market reform: fixed-term contracts in France. The Economic Journal, 112(480), F214–F244.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Boeri, T., & Garibaldi, P. (2007). Two tier reforms of employment protection: a honeymoon effect? The Economic Journal, 117(521), F357–F385.CrossRef Boeri, T., & Garibaldi, P. (2007). Two tier reforms of employment protection: a honeymoon effect? The Economic Journal, 117(521), F357–F385.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bosma, N. S. (2009). The geography of entrepreneurial activity and regional economic development: multilevel analyses for Dutch and European regions, Utrecht University. Bosma, N. S. (2009). The geography of entrepreneurial activity and regional economic development: multilevel analyses for Dutch and European regions, Utrecht University.
Zurück zum Zitat Bosma, N., & Schutjens, V. (2009). Determinants of early-stage entrepreneurial activity in European regions; distinguishing low and high ambition entrepreneurship, making the difference in local, regional and national economies: Frontiers in European Entrepreneurship Research, pp. 49–80. Bosma, N., & Schutjens, V. (2009). Determinants of early-stage entrepreneurial activity in European regions; distinguishing low and high ambition entrepreneurship, making the difference in local, regional and national economies: Frontiers in European Entrepreneurship Research, pp. 49–80.
Zurück zum Zitat Bosma, N., Coduras, A., Litovsky, Y., & Seaman, J. (2012). GEM manual: a report on the design, data and quality control of the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor. Bosma, N., Coduras, A., Litovsky, Y., & Seaman, J. (2012). GEM manual: a report on the design, data and quality control of the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor.
Zurück zum Zitat Brambor, T., Clark, T. W., & Golder, M. (2006). Understanding interaction models: improving empirical analysis. Political Analysis, 14(1), 63–82.CrossRef Brambor, T., Clark, T. W., & Golder, M. (2006). Understanding interaction models: improving empirical analysis. Political Analysis, 14(1), 63–82.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Burton, M. D., Sørensen, J. B., & Dobrev, S. D. (2016). A careers perspective on entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 40(2), 237–247.CrossRef Burton, M. D., Sørensen, J. B., & Dobrev, S. D. (2016). A careers perspective on entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 40(2), 237–247.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Davidsson, P., Delmar, F., & Wiklund, J. (2006). Entrepreneurship and the growth of firms. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRef Davidsson, P., Delmar, F., & Wiklund, J. (2006). Entrepreneurship and the growth of firms. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Delmar, F., Wennberg, K., & Hellerstedt, K. (2011). Endogenous growth through knowledge spillovers in entrepreneurship: an empirical test. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, 6(3), 199–226.CrossRef Delmar, F., Wennberg, K., & Hellerstedt, K. (2011). Endogenous growth through knowledge spillovers in entrepreneurship: an empirical test. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, 6(3), 199–226.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Douglas, E., J. & Shepherd, D. A. (2000). Entrepreneurship as a utility maximizing response. Journal of Business Venturing 15(3), 231–251. Douglas, E., J. & Shepherd, D. A. (2000). Entrepreneurship as a utility maximizing response. Journal of Business Venturing 15(3), 231–251.
Zurück zum Zitat Douglas, E. J., & Shepherd, D. A. (2002). Self-employment as a career choice: Attitudes, entrepreneurial intentions, and utility maximization. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 26(3), 81–90.CrossRef Douglas, E. J., & Shepherd, D. A. (2002). Self-employment as a career choice: Attitudes, entrepreneurial intentions, and utility maximization. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 26(3), 81–90.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hofmann, D. A., Griffin, M. A., & Gavin, M. B. (2000). The application of hierarchical linear modeling to organizational research. In K. J. Klein & S. W. J. Kozlowski (Eds.), Multilevel theory, research, and methods in organizations: foundations, extensions, and new directions (pp. 467–511). San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. Hofmann, D. A., Griffin, M. A., & Gavin, M. B. (2000). The application of hierarchical linear modeling to organizational research. In K. J. Klein & S. W. J. Kozlowski (Eds.), Multilevel theory, research, and methods in organizations: foundations, extensions, and new directions (pp. 467–511). San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Zurück zum Zitat Katz, J. (1992). A psychosocial cognitive model of employment status choice. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 17(1), 29–36.CrossRef Katz, J. (1992). A psychosocial cognitive model of employment status choice. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 17(1), 29–36.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lafontaine, F., & Shaw, K. (2016). Serial entrepreneurship: learning by doing? Journal of Labor Economics, 34(2), 217–254.CrossRef Lafontaine, F., & Shaw, K. (2016). Serial entrepreneurship: learning by doing? Journal of Labor Economics, 34(2), 217–254.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Levie, J., & Autio, E. (2011). Regulatory burden, rule of law, and entry of strategic entrepreneurs: an international panel study. Journal of Management Studies, 48(6), 1392–1419.CrossRef Levie, J., & Autio, E. (2011). Regulatory burden, rule of law, and entry of strategic entrepreneurs: an international panel study. Journal of Management Studies, 48(6), 1392–1419.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McGrath, R. G., & MacMillan, I. C. (2000). The entrepreneurial mindset. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. McGrath, R. G., & MacMillan, I. C. (2000). The entrepreneurial mindset. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Nyström, K. (2014). Business regulation and red tape in the entrepreneurial economy. In C. Karlsson, B. Johansson, & R. Stough (Eds.), Agglomeration, clusters and entrepreneurship (pp. 283–300). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Nyström, K. (2014). Business regulation and red tape in the entrepreneurial economy. In C. Karlsson, B. Johansson, & R. Stough (Eds.), Agglomeration, clusters and entrepreneurship (pp. 283–300). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Zurück zum Zitat Parker, S. C. (2009). The economics of entrepreneurship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Parker, S. C. (2009). The economics of entrepreneurship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pierre, G., & Scarpetta, S. (2004). Employment regulations through the eyes of employers: do they matter and how do firms respond to them? IZA Discussion Paper 1424. Pierre, G., & Scarpetta, S. (2004). Employment regulations through the eyes of employers: do they matter and how do firms respond to them? IZA Discussion Paper 1424.
Zurück zum Zitat Shane, S. (2003). A general theory of entrepreneurship: the individual-opportunity nexus. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRef Shane, S. (2003). A general theory of entrepreneurship: the individual-opportunity nexus. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Skedinger, P. (2011). Employment consequences of employment protection legislation. IFN Working Paper No. 865. Skedinger, P. (2011). Employment consequences of employment protection legislation. IFN Working Paper No. 865.
Zurück zum Zitat Ucbasaran, D., Westhead, P., Wright, M., & Binks, M. (2003). Does entrepreneurial experience influence opportunity identification? The Journal of Private Equity, 7(1), 7–14.CrossRef Ucbasaran, D., Westhead, P., Wright, M., & Binks, M. (2003). Does entrepreneurial experience influence opportunity identification? The Journal of Private Equity, 7(1), 7–14.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Venn, D. (2009). Legislation, collective bargaining and enforcement. OECD Social, Employment, and Migration Working Papers 89. Venn, D. (2009). Legislation, collective bargaining and enforcement. OECD Social, Employment, and Migration Working Papers 89.
Zurück zum Zitat Westhead, P. & Wright, M. (2015). The habitual entrepreneur phenomenon. International Small Business Journal, Virtual Special Issue. 1–16. Westhead, P. & Wright, M. (2015). The habitual entrepreneur phenomenon. International Small Business Journal, Virtual Special Issue. 1–16.
Metadaten
Titel
Habitual entrepreneurs in the making: how labour market rigidity and employment affects entrepreneurial re-entry
verfasst von
Kun Fu
Anne-Sophie Larsson
Karl Wennberg
Publikationsdatum
06.03.2018
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Small Business Economics / Ausgabe 2/2018
Print ISSN: 0921-898X
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-0913
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-018-0011-y

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 2/2018

Small Business Economics 2/2018 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner