Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Organization Review 2/2016

22.01.2015

On the Inefficiency of Political Exchange

verfasst von: Claudio Balestri

Erschienen in: Public Organization Review | Ausgabe 2/2016

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

A classic argument in economic theory is that in a world of zero transaction costs the free bargaining among parties spontaneously leads to an efficient allocation of resources. Attempts have been made by many economists to apply such an argument to the field of politics. In contrast to market exchanges, political exchanges have been widely criticized on ethical grounds. Going beyond the well-known moral criticism regarding the exchange of votes, the paper attempts to demonstrate how in politics, ethics and economics can go hand in hand. Specifically, it proposes an unusual perspective on transaction costs, by arguing that the enhancement of such costs can be required to achieve efficient results in specific circumstances, where the free bargaining among parties conflicts with the public issue to be addressed. This suggests the basic idea that, while in markets transaction costs should be reduced, in politics, they may require to be enhanced.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
The principal characteristic of the “public choice theory” is to apply economic tools to deal with traditional problems in political science (Tullock 2008). Its basic assumption is that political agents, including voters and elected officials, are mainly self-interested. For a complete overview of this strand of literature see, among others, Mueller (2003).
 
2
Buchanan and Tullock introduce logrolling in a simple model of direct democracy. Hence, in this case, the pareto-efficient results refer to the direct participants in the collective choices. However, as the authors specify, the results of the model remain valid in large part, even in the case of representative democracy, where interests representative of different groups are exchanged.
 
3
The cases proposed by Sandel are of particular interest, for example, in relation to the market to attend the meetings of congressional committees.
 
4
Bowles’ translation of “…è necessaria a chi dispone una repubblica e ordina le leggi in quella, presupporre tutti gli uomini rei” (Machiavelli 1513–1517).
 
5
He specifically refers to Adam Smith’s Theory of Moral Sentiments.
 
6
Obviously, Rawls’ arguments are used here in a very simplified way, despite their relevance and complexity on philosophical grounds.
 
7
For a more general insight about the economic theory of collective action see Olson (1965), Hardin (1982) and Sandler (1992).
 
8
Many theoretical and empirical models exist which analyze the trade off between the provision of private and public goods at a governmental level. See, for example, McGuire and Olson (1996) and Deacon (2009).
 
9
“a” represents the individual payoff when belonging to a special interest group or, also, the personal gains originating from a “corruptive” price paid by such a group.
 
10
During the legislative process cases occur in which logrolling activities are easier because transaction costs are lower. This is just the case, for instance, in the approval of the “financial stability law” in Italy, by which thousands of amendments of very limited interest are approved every year. In this case, the enforcement of reciprocal agreements is easier because all the proposals are approved in the same bill. It is difficult to assert that many of them have efficiency enhancing effects.
 
11
The efficiency property of such results is justified by the fact that the institutional aim of State intervention is exactly to correct the under-provision of public goods achieved by market bargaining.
 
12
In particular, see the section entitled “Che li signori Nove stieno in luogo publico et aperto ogne giovedì” (That the Nine lords be in a public and open place every Thursday) in the “Sesta Distintione” of the “Costituto” (1309–1310).
 
13
See also the condition of “publicity” in Rawls (1971) as a formal constraint of the concept of right.
 
14
Moving from examples from the past to the contemporary, even new technologies offer efficient instruments for monitoring private agreements and the public integrity of elected officials. See, for instance, the valuable activities of many civil society organizations engaged in tracing the influence of money (especially so-called “dark money”) over public policies, by financing the electoral campaigns of parties or single candidates.
 
15
Nowadays the value of privacy tends to be highly overestimated in respect of other much more important issues for citizens. In this sense it is necessary to take into account the existing trade off between the protection of privacy and the prevention of corruption, which would often require to be rebalanced in favor of the latter for the sake of efficiency. This is just the case of the huge amount of anonymous money deposited in the so called “tax havens”, which are often used to feed corruptive activities in other countries.
 
16
Since electoral campaigns are very expensive, candidates need to compete with each other in the market for financial support. For this reason, an increasing concentration of wealth, among and within countries, can strongly influence public policies towards private interests, which conflict with more general ones. Also, the growing influence of global corporations represents an effective threat to the correct functioning of democracies worldwide. In this field, an effective antitrust regulation can be an institutional device to protect the efficient functioning, not only of the market, but also of democracy itself.
 
17
Balestri (2014) develops a model of representative democracy where political organizations are intended to maximize a residual quantum consisting in the public authority that can actually be exercised after all the electoral commitments with voters and interests groups have been fulfilled. This residual right—which can be seen also as the degree of discretion necessary for ruling parties to deal with unforeseen contingencies—is based on the “reputational” capital (goodwill) accumulated over time by political organizations and represents the intangible asset that secures voter loyalty and, consequently, the legitimacy to exercise public authority in the long run.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Allen, D. (1999). Transaction costs. In Encyclopedia of law and economics, volume I: The history and methodology of law and economics (pp. 894–926). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Allen, D. (1999). Transaction costs. In Encyclopedia of law and economics, volume I: The history and methodology of law and economics (pp. 894–926). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Zurück zum Zitat Backer, G. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. A The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3), 371–400.CrossRef Backer, G. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. A The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3), 371–400.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Balestri, C. (2014). Political organizations, interest groups and citizens engagement: an integrated model of democracy. Public Organization Review, 14(4), 533-543. doi:10.1007/s11115-013-0243-x. Balestri, C. (2014). Political organizations, interest groups and citizens engagement: an integrated model of democracy. Public Organization Review, 14(4), 533-543. doi:10.​1007/​s11115-013-0243-x.
Zurück zum Zitat Bowles, S. (2015). Machiavelli’s mistake: Why good laws are no substitute for good citizens. New Haven: Yale University Press. Bowles, S. (2015). Machiavelli’s mistake: Why good laws are no substitute for good citizens. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Bowles, S. (2008). Policies designed for self-interested citizens may undermine “the moral sentiments”: evidence from economic experiments. Science, 320, 1605–1609.CrossRef Bowles, S. (2008). Policies designed for self-interested citizens may undermine “the moral sentiments”: evidence from economic experiments. Science, 320, 1605–1609.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brennan, G. (2012). Politics-as-exchange and the calculus of consent. Public Choice, 152(3–4), 351–358.CrossRef Brennan, G. (2012). Politics-as-exchange and the calculus of consent. Public Choice, 152(3–4), 351–358.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Buchanan, J., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef Buchanan, J., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Coase, R. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405.CrossRef Coase, R. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.CrossRef Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Deacon, R. T. (2009). Public good provision under dictatorship and democracy. Public Choice, 139(1–2), 241–262.CrossRef Deacon, R. T. (2009). Public good provision under dictatorship and democracy. Public Choice, 139(1–2), 241–262.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Elster, J. (1986), The market and the forum. in J Elster and A Hylland (eds.), Foundations of Social Choice Theory, Cambridge University Press. Elster, J. (1986), The market and the forum. in J Elster and A Hylland (eds.), Foundations of Social Choice Theory, Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Gwartney, J. D., & Holcombe, R. G. (2014). Politics as exchange: the classical liberal economics and politics of James M. Buchanan. Constitutional Political Economy. doi:10.1007/s10602-014-9165-z. Gwartney, J. D., & Holcombe, R. G. (2014). Politics as exchange: the classical liberal economics and politics of James M. Buchanan. Constitutional Political Economy. doi:10.​1007/​s10602-014-9165-z.
Zurück zum Zitat Hardin, R. (1982). Collective action. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Hardin, R. (1982). Collective action. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Holcombe, R. G. (2006). Public sector economics: The role of government in the american economy. New Jersey: Prentice Hall. Holcombe, R. G. (2006). Public sector economics: The role of government in the american economy. New Jersey: Prentice Hall.
Zurück zum Zitat Macey, J. R. (1988). Transaction costs and the normative elements of the public choice model: an application to constitutional theory. Virginia Law Review, 74, 471–518.CrossRef Macey, J. R. (1988). Transaction costs and the normative elements of the public choice model: an application to constitutional theory. Virginia Law Review, 74, 471–518.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McGuire, M. C., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule: the invisible hand and the Use of force. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 72–96. McGuire, M. C., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule: the invisible hand and the Use of force. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 72–96.
Zurück zum Zitat Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Musgrave, R. A. (1999). The nature of the fiscal state: the roots of my thinking. In J. M. Buchanan & R. A. Musgrave (Eds.), Public finance and public choice (pp. 29–50). Cambridge MA: The MIT Press. Musgrave, R. A. (1999). The nature of the fiscal state: the roots of my thinking. In J. M. Buchanan & R. A. Musgrave (Eds.), Public finance and public choice (pp. 29–50). Cambridge MA: The MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat North, D. C. (1990). A transaction cost theory of politics. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 2(4), 355–367.CrossRef North, D. C. (1990). A transaction cost theory of politics. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 2(4), 355–367.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press. Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Parisi, F. (2003). Political coase theorem. Public Choice, 115, 1–36.CrossRef Parisi, F. (2003). Political coase theorem. Public Choice, 115, 1–36.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rawls, J. (1971). A theory of justice. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Revised Edition (1999). Rawls, J. (1971). A theory of justice. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Revised Edition (1999).
Zurück zum Zitat Samuelson, P. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), 387–389.CrossRef Samuelson, P. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), 387–389.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Samuelson, P. (1955). Diagrammatic exposition of a theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 37(4), 350–356.CrossRef Samuelson, P. (1955). Diagrammatic exposition of a theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 37(4), 350–356.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sandel, M. (2012). What money can’t buy: The moral limits of markets. Farrar, Straus and Giroux. Sandel, M. (2012). What money can’t buy: The moral limits of markets. Farrar, Straus and Giroux.
Zurück zum Zitat Sandler, T. (1992). Collective action: Theory and applications. University of Michigan Press. Sandler, T. (1992). Collective action: Theory and applications. University of Michigan Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Satz, D. (2010). Why some things should not be for sale: The moral limits of markets. Oxford University Press. Satz, D. (2010). Why some things should not be for sale: The moral limits of markets. Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Stigler, G. (1966). The theory of price. New York: Macmillan. Stigler, G. (1966). The theory of price. New York: Macmillan.
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (2008). Public choice. The new palgrave dictionary of economics, Palgrave Macmillan. Tullock, G. (2008). Public choice. The new palgrave dictionary of economics, Palgrave Macmillan.
Zurück zum Zitat Wittman, D. (1989). Why democracies produce efficient results. Journal of Political Economy, 97(6), 1395–1424.CrossRef Wittman, D. (1989). Why democracies produce efficient results. Journal of Political Economy, 97(6), 1395–1424.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
On the Inefficiency of Political Exchange
verfasst von
Claudio Balestri
Publikationsdatum
22.01.2015
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Organization Review / Ausgabe 2/2016
Print ISSN: 1566-7170
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7098
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11115-014-0301-z

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 2/2016

Public Organization Review 2/2016 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner