Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 1-2/2014

01.04.2014

Voters, dictators, and peons: expressive voting and pivotality

verfasst von: Emir Kamenica, Louisa Egan Brad

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 1-2/2014

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Why do the poor vote against redistribution? We examine one explanation experimentally, namely that individuals gain direct expressive utility from voting in accordance with their ideology and understand that they are unlikely to be pivotal; hence, their expressive utility, even if arbitrarily small, determines their voting behavior. In contrast with a basic prediction of this model, we find that the probability of being pivotal does not affect the impact of monetary interest on whether a subject votes for redistribution.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
The possibility that individuals vote in accordance with their individual notions of justice would also account for the fact that many wealthy people vote for redistributive policies.
 
2
Parameter p still may influence behavior under the social preferences model, depending on how one models the noise in voters’ behavior. For example, it could be that a higher p leads to fewer “errors” and thus makes behavior more sensitive to both ideology and monetary interests.
 
3
There is also a small literature that examines correlations between voting and other expressive behaviors, finding that voters are not only more likely to wear political buttons and place political signs in front of their houses (Copeland and Laband 2002), but also more likely to post signs supporting their local football team (Laband et al. 2008).
 
4
Under a simple modification of a model from Mueller (1989), Sobel and Wagner (2004) derive this probability to be \(\frac {3}{\sqrt{2 ( 2\pi( n-1 ) ) }}\) where n is the number of voters.
 
5
In addition, Fischer (1996) incorrectly computes the probabilities of being pivotal; in the condition where a subject’s name is drawn at random and then his or her decision is implemented for certain, his analysis codes the probability of being pivotal as equal to 1 even though subjects make their decisions before names are drawn.
 
6
Haab et al. (1999), however, argue that this result might reflect only a difference in the variance of responses across the conditions rather than a difference in the average willingness to give.
 
7
Feddersen et al.’s results on turnout, i.e., on whether the subjects choose to abstain, are also consistent with expressive voting models.
 
8
The recruiting ad said “Participate in an experiment; earn up to $30 an hour”, with a footnote that added “you will get between $5 and $15 for a half-hour experiment”.
 
9
Rock-paper-scissors is a game with two players. The players simultaneously choose one of three actions: rock (a clenched fist), paper (an open hand with all fingers extended) or scissors (a hand with index and middle fingers extended and separated). A rock beats scissors; scissors beat paper; paper beats rock. If both players choose the same action, the round is counted as a draw.
 
10
In each of the five rounds, the experimenter played the same action (rock, scissors, or paper) against all nine subjects. Consequently, subjects who played similar strategies had similar performance. Our statistical analyses are conducted under the assumption that any common component in subjects’ strategies is orthogonal to their redistributive preferences.
 
11
Many subjects, however, especially those who had done well, said they believe that skill played a part in determining performance. We explain below how this belief was elicited.
 
12
An alternative design that generates variation in pivotality is to fix a decision-making procedure, but vary the group size. A problem with such a design, however, is that if social preferences depend on the group size, the direct effect of pivotality cannot be established.
 
13
Subjects signed up for particular time slots that were randomized to a referendum procedure or a dictatorship procedure. If subject characteristics exist that affect preferences for both time slots and for redistribution, this would lower the true precision of our estimates of the effect of being a voter. This issue does not affect our comparison of dictators and peons, however.
 
14
We did not ask this question of the first group of subjects. Hence, data on this question is missing for 9 out of the 459 subjects.
 
15
Even countries that impose compulsory voting allow the voters to cast blank ballots.
 
16
The correlation between the answers to the two questions is also significant (p<0.001). When answers to both questions are included in the same regression, each has a significant and independent effect (both p-values <0.02).
 
17
This relationship is significant (p<0.001). Once we control for views on the motivation of the poor and views on redistributive taxation, however, the impact of the views on the death penalty becomes only marginally significant (p=0.07).
 
18
Some readers might object that, since peons were asked what they would do if they were a dictator, they might behave as if they were indeed pivotal. We interpret our results under the assumption that only actual pivotality matters, but readers who disagree are invited to disregard the data on peons; excluding peons from the empirical analysis does not substantively change the conclusions of the paper.
 
19
The 95 % confidence interval excludes the possibility that the effect of monetary interest on dictators’ choices is more than 3.2 percentage points greater than on peons’ choices or more than 2.7 percentage points greater than on voters’ choices.
 
20
All of the papers above focus on turnout. They are relevant to our setting under the assumption that voters are likely to condition how to vote on the probability that they are pivotal if they condition whether to vote on that probability.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Benabou, R., & Ok, E. A. (2001). Social mobility and the demand for redistribution: the POUM hypothesis. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(2), 447–487. CrossRef Benabou, R., & Ok, E. A. (2001). Social mobility and the demand for redistribution: the POUM hypothesis. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(2), 447–487. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blais, A., Young, R., & Lapp, M. (2000). The calculus of voting: an empirical test. European Journal of Political Research, 37(2), 181–201. Blais, A., Young, R., & Lapp, M. (2000). The calculus of voting: an empirical test. European Journal of Political Research, 37(2), 181–201.
Zurück zum Zitat Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. (1984). Voter choice: evaluating political alternatives. American Behavioral Scientist, 28, 185–201. CrossRef Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. (1984). Voter choice: evaluating political alternatives. American Behavioral Scientist, 28, 185–201. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brennan, G., & Hamlin, A. (1988). Expressive voting and electoral equilibrium. Public Choice, 95, 149–175. CrossRef Brennan, G., & Hamlin, A. (1988). Expressive voting and electoral equilibrium. Public Choice, 95, 149–175. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brennan, G., & Lomasky, L. (1993). Democracy and decision: the pure theory of electoral preference. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. CrossRef Brennan, G., & Lomasky, L. (1993). Democracy and decision: the pure theory of electoral preference. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carter, J. R., & Guerette, S. D. (1992). An experimental study of expressive voting. Public Choice, 73(3), 251–260. CrossRef Carter, J. R., & Guerette, S. D. (1992). An experimental study of expressive voting. Public Choice, 73(3), 251–260. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Copeland, C., & Laband, D. N. (2002). Expressiveness and voting. Public Choice, 110, 351–363. CrossRef Copeland, C., & Laband, D. N. (2002). Expressiveness and voting. Public Choice, 110, 351–363. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cummings, R. G., Elliott, S., Harrison, G. W., & Murphy, J. (1997). Are hypothetical referenda incentive compatible? Journal of Political Economy, 105(3), 609–621. CrossRef Cummings, R. G., Elliott, S., Harrison, G. W., & Murphy, J. (1997). Are hypothetical referenda incentive compatible? Journal of Political Economy, 105(3), 609–621. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dittmann, I., Kubler, D., Maug, E., & Mechtenberg, L. (2009). Why votes have a value. Working Paper. Dittmann, I., Kubler, D., Maug, E., & Mechtenberg, L. (2009). Why votes have a value. Working Paper.
Zurück zum Zitat Duffy, J., & Tavits, M. (2008). Beliefs and voting decisions: a test of the pivotal voter model. American Journal of Political Science, 52(3), 603–618. CrossRef Duffy, J., & Tavits, M. (2008). Beliefs and voting decisions: a test of the pivotal voter model. American Journal of Political Science, 52(3), 603–618. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Durante, R., & Putterman, L. (2009). Preferences for redistribution and perception of fairness: an experimental study. SSRN Working Paper 1004573. Durante, R., & Putterman, L. (2009). Preferences for redistribution and perception of fairness: an experimental study. SSRN Working Paper 1004573.
Zurück zum Zitat Edlin, A. S., Gelman, A., & Kaplan, N. (2007). Voting as a rational choice: why and how people vote to improve the well-being of others. Rationality and Society, 19(3), 293–314. CrossRef Edlin, A. S., Gelman, A., & Kaplan, N. (2007). Voting as a rational choice: why and how people vote to improve the well-being of others. Rationality and Society, 19(3), 293–314. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Farber, H. S. (2009). Rational choice and voter turnout: evidence from union representation elections. Princeton University Industrial Relations Section Working Paper 552. Farber, H. S. (2009). Rational choice and voter turnout: evidence from union representation elections. Princeton University Industrial Relations Section Working Paper 552.
Zurück zum Zitat Feddersen, T., Gailmard, S., & Sandroni, A. (2009). Moral bias in large elections: theory and experimental evidence. American Political Science Review, 103, 175–192. CrossRef Feddersen, T., Gailmard, S., & Sandroni, A. (2009). Moral bias in large elections: theory and experimental evidence. American Political Science Review, 103, 175–192. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fischer, A. J. (1996). A further experimental study of expressive voting. Public Choice, 88(1–2), 171–184. CrossRef Fischer, A. J. (1996). A further experimental study of expressive voting. Public Choice, 88(1–2), 171–184. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fong, C. (2001). Social preferences, self-interest, and the demand for redistribution. Journal of Public Economics, 82(2), 225–246. CrossRef Fong, C. (2001). Social preferences, self-interest, and the demand for redistribution. Journal of Public Economics, 82(2), 225–246. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gelman, A., Silver, N., & Edlin A. S. (forthcoming). What is the probability your vote will make a difference. Economic Inquiry. Gelman, A., Silver, N., & Edlin A. S. (forthcoming). What is the probability your vote will make a difference. Economic Inquiry.
Zurück zum Zitat Haab, T. C., Huang, J.-C., & Whitehead, J. C. (1999). Are hypothetical referenda incentive compatible? A comment. Journal of Political Economy, 107(1), 186–196. CrossRef Haab, T. C., Huang, J.-C., & Whitehead, J. C. (1999). Are hypothetical referenda incentive compatible? A comment. Journal of Political Economy, 107(1), 186–196. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Houser, D., & Stratmann, T. (2008). Selling favors in the lab: experiments on campaign finance reform. Public Choice, 136, 215–239. CrossRef Houser, D., & Stratmann, T. (2008). Selling favors in the lab: experiments on campaign finance reform. Public Choice, 136, 215–239. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Houser, D., Morton, R., & Stratmann, T. (2011). Turned on or turned out? Campaign advertising, information and voting. European Journal of Political Economy, 27, 708–727. CrossRef Houser, D., Morton, R., & Stratmann, T. (2011). Turned on or turned out? Campaign advertising, information and voting. European Journal of Political Economy, 27, 708–727. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Krupnikov, Y., Levine, A. S., Lupia, A., & Prior, M. (2006). Public ignorance and estate tax repeal: the effect of partisan differences and survey incentives. National Tax Journal, 59(3), 425–437. Krupnikov, Y., Levine, A. S., Lupia, A., & Prior, M. (2006). Public ignorance and estate tax repeal: the effect of partisan differences and survey incentives. National Tax Journal, 59(3), 425–437.
Zurück zum Zitat Laband, D. N., Pandit, R., Laband, A. M., & Sophocleus, J. P. (2008). Pigskins and politics: linking expressive behavior and voting. Journal of Sports Economics, 9(5), 553–560. CrossRef Laband, D. N., Pandit, R., Laband, A. M., & Sophocleus, J. P. (2008). Pigskins and politics: linking expressive behavior and voting. Journal of Sports Economics, 9(5), 553–560. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Levine, D. K., & Palfrey, T. R. (2007). The paradox of voter participation? A laboratory study. American Political Science Review, 101(1), 143–158. CrossRef Levine, D. K., & Palfrey, T. R. (2007). The paradox of voter participation? A laboratory study. American Political Science Review, 101(1), 143–158. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mueller, D. C. (1989). Public choice II: a revised edition of public choice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Mueller, D. C. (1989). Public choice II: a revised edition of public choice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Putterman, L. (1997). Property relations, incentives, and welfare. In J. E. Roemer (Ed.) Why have the rabble not redistributed the wealth? On the stability of democracy and unequal property (pp. 359–389). London: Macmillan. Putterman, L. (1997). Property relations, incentives, and welfare. In J. E. Roemer (Ed.) Why have the rabble not redistributed the wealth? On the stability of democracy and unequal property (pp. 359–389). London: Macmillan.
Zurück zum Zitat Roemer, J. E. (1998). Why the poor do not expropriate the rich: an old argument in new garb. Journal of Public Economics, 70(3), 399–424. CrossRef Roemer, J. E. (1998). Why the poor do not expropriate the rich: an old argument in new garb. Journal of Public Economics, 70(3), 399–424. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shayo, M., & Harel, A. (2010). Non-consequentialist voting. Working Paper. Shayo, M., & Harel, A. (2010). Non-consequentialist voting. Working Paper.
Zurück zum Zitat Sobel, R. S., & Wagner, G. A. (2004). Expressive voting and government redistribution: testing Tullock’s ‘Charity of the uncharitable’. Public Choice, 119(1–2), 143–159. CrossRef Sobel, R. S., & Wagner, G. A. (2004). Expressive voting and government redistribution: testing Tullock’s ‘Charity of the uncharitable’. Public Choice, 119(1–2), 143–159. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1971). The charity of the uncharitable. Western Economic Journal, 9(4), 379–392. Tullock, G. (1971). The charity of the uncharitable. Western Economic Journal, 9(4), 379–392.
Zurück zum Zitat Tyran, J.-R. (2004). Voting when money and morals conflict: an experimental test of expressive voting. Journal of Public Economics, 88(7–8), 1645–1664. CrossRef Tyran, J.-R. (2004). Voting when money and morals conflict: an experimental test of expressive voting. Journal of Public Economics, 88(7–8), 1645–1664. CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Voters, dictators, and peons: expressive voting and pivotality
verfasst von
Emir Kamenica
Louisa Egan Brad
Publikationsdatum
01.04.2014
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 1-2/2014
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-0035-9

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1-2/2014

Public Choice 1-2/2014 Zur Ausgabe