Skip to main content
Erschienen in: International Tax and Public Finance 1/2017

20.06.2016

Why not fully spend a conditional block grant?

verfasst von: Riemer P. Faber, Pierre Koning

Erschienen in: International Tax and Public Finance | Ausgabe 1/2017

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper studies a conditional block grant that Dutch municipalities receive for welfare-to-work programs. Many municipalities do not fully use this grant, although programs are beneficial for them. We argue that municipalities incur expenses to use the grant. If these costs are substantial, then it is optimal not to fully use the grant. Based on municipality-specific data on grants and actual expenditures, we estimate that municipalities have to add about 90 cents from their own resources to spend 1 euro of the grant. As a result, the conditional block grant is de facto a closed-ended matching grant.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
For an overview of conditional intergovernmental grants and data on their importance see, e.g., Oates (1999), Bergvall et al. (2006), Huber and Runkel (2006), and Boadway and Shah (2007).
 
2
Others study situations in which subnational governments reject a grant because their policy goals interfere with the conditions of the grant (e.g., a grant for abstinence-only education). Another related question is whether subnational governments apply and lobby for grants. See, for example, Chernick (1979), Stein (1979, (1981), Foster (1981), Rich (1989), Schneider and Ji (1990), Knight (2002), Bickers and Stein (2004), Volden (2007), Craw (2010), and Doan and McFarlane (2012). In our setting, however, policy goals of the national and subnational government do not fundamentally differ and the subnational government automatically receives the grant.
 
3
See, e.g., Divosa (2006), Van Geuns et al. (2006), and Berkhout and Mallee (2008).
 
4
Stein (1979, (1981) mentions three types of costs that subnational governments possibly incur in case they are seeking and receiving a grant: costs of applying for the grant, costs of implementing the grant, and opportunity costs (the costs of curtailing other expenditures due to the costs of application and implementation). Stein hypothesizes that if these costs are high, subnational governments seek grants less frequently. We focus on the costs of using the grant (i.e., the costs of implementing the grant and the opportunity costs) as municipalities do not have to apply for the grant that we study.
 
5
In the case of federal funded research grants in the USA, there exists a similar distinction between direct costs (e.g., personnel and equipment during the project) and indirect costs (e.g., university libraries and building maintenance). Direct costs are easy to assign to a specific project, indirect costs of a project are difficult to measure (see, e.g., May and Sarson 1999). In spite of this, federal funded research grants (partly) cover indirect costs. However, it will always be difficult to determine what are legitimate and illegitimate indirect costs. Possibly, this is a reason that many other research grants do not cover indirect costs. In these cases, universities have to pay indirect costs from their own resources. Indirect costs are about 30 % of the total costs of research (Goldman et al. 2000).
 
6
Chernick (1979, (1981) also argues that a conditional block grant can implicitly be a matching grant. In his model, recipients apply for a conditional block grant and the donor awards grants to those recipients who are willing to finance a larger part of the project themselves. Therefore, the donor actually provides a matching grant. Chernick also empirically tests this model using the HUD Basic Water and Sewer grant and finds a positive relationship between the size of the grant that recipients receive and their own contribution. Thus, next to implicit costs of using a grant, there can also exist implicit costs of applying for a grant (see also Footnote 4). Also Stein (1979) shows the importance of costs of applying since he finds that communities that apply more often for some specific matching grants have more active and developed planning structures (e.g., a planning body and a high number of planners). For similar evidence see, for example, Collins and Gerber (2006, (2008) and Hall (2008a, (2008b), and also Okten and Weisbrod (2000), Reinhardt (2006), and Lindsay et al. (2014).
 
7
Moreover, Becker et al. (2013) show that regions that receive European grants need a certain level of institutional quality and education to absorb grants effectively.
 
8
In a similar vein, Cashel-Cordo and Craig (1990) argue that also certain forms of foreign aid and IMF programs look like conditional block grants, but in fact contain an implicit matching component because of, for example, required policy changes that generate additional expenditures for the recipient. See also McGuire (1978), Chubb (1985), Brennan and Pincus (1990), and Singhal (2008) for a discussion on explicit and implicit conditions of grants.
 
9
The Canadian government also provides a grant that complements other federal research grants by covering the indirect costs of research (Government of Canada 2010). For the situation in the USA, see, e.g., the references in Footnote 5.
 
10
To put this amount in context, in 2008, the total unconditional block grant that municipalities receive for social assistance benefits for people who are younger than 65 equals 3.7 billion euros and the Dutch GDP is 596 billion euros (source: Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment and Statistics Netherlands).
 
11
The current system exists since 2004. See, e.g., Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment (2006, (2008) for background information.
 
12
Many employees who lose their job can claim unemployment insurance first (the maximum duration of this benefit is individual-specific and varies between 3 months and 5 years during the sample period). Therefore, relatively many social assistance recipients are already unemployed for a longer period.
 
13
For an overview of the literature on evaluations of active labor market policies see, e.g., Card et al. (2010) and Kluve (2010). Wunsch (2013) and Lindsay et al. (2014) illustrate the diversity of the used methodologies.
 
14
Next to the standard grant from the national government, a municipality may receive additional conditional grants for welfare-to-work programs (e.g., via the European Social Fund). Van Geuns et al. (2006, p. 22) estimate that the size of these grants is 5–6 % of the grant a municipality receives from the national government and that 40–50 % of the municipalities receive such a grant. In our analysis, we assume that the grant of the national government is the only grant a municipality receives (since this is the only grant that we observe).
 
15
Each month, the national government transfers one-twelfth of the annual grant to a special checking account. A municipality can transfer money from this account to its regular accounts. The special checking account cannot have a negative balance. If a municipality borrows, then it has to temporarily finance this amount. In our analysis, we assume that a municipality does not receive interest on its savings and that it does not pay interest on its borrowings.
 
16
See, e.g., Kok et al. (2006, p. 17), Kuhry and Jonker (2007, p. 89), and Cebeon (2010) for a discussion and estimations of indirect costs (mostly via surveys and balance sheets of a selection of municipalities).
 
17
An alternative assumption in this section could be that the national government ignores the indirect costs. This assumption is less realistic and leads sooner to the conclusion that underspending exists. We will come back to this point in Footnote 21.
 
18
Survey evidence confirms that municipalities first focus on social assistance recipients with relatively high revenues (Divosa 2006, pp. 15 and 37).
 
19
Alternatively, we could assume that the indirect costs depend on the level of U. However, it is a priori not clear what this relation would be. In practice, it seems that some types of indirect costs are higher if a municipality already has spent a lot on actual programs (e.g., it is harder to find a new appropriate participant). Other types of indirect costs, however, may be lower in this case (e.g., civil servants have more experience in the procurement of programs). Furthermore, a more complex cost function substantially increases the required number of computations in the next section. For these reasons, we assume that indirect costs are a constant fraction of U. Another possibility is the existence of (indirect) fixed costs. These do not impact the conclusions in this section. In the empirical part of the paper, one of our estimates is robust to the existence of (indirect) fixed costs.
 
20
We could also explicitly divide the indirect costs of programs into two types: indirect costs that also exist if the municipality uses its own resources instead of the grant (e.g., costs of selecting program participants) and indirect costs that only exist if the municipality uses the grant (e.g., administrative costs of proving that money is spent on the purpose of the grant). In this section, we assume for simplicity that all indirect costs are of the first type (i.e., the indirect costs are not higher if the municipality uses the grant than if it uses its own resources). In practice, the first type seems to be much larger than the second type. In the empirical part of the paper, we implicitly include both types of costs.
 
21
If we would assume that the national government ignores the indirect costs (see Footnote 17) while these costs do exist, then the national government would underestimate the costs of programs and provide a larger grant. In that case, the municipality already would not fully use the grant at a lower level of x (\(\tilde{x}\) would be lower). Hence, the assumption that the national government ignores the indirect costs leads sooner to the conclusion that underspending exists than the assumption that its estimate of the indirect costs is correct.
 
22
The national government can compensate the crowding out of expenditures that the municipality would do if there would not be a grant (\(\left( \beta /(1+x)\right) -1\)) by decreasing the unconditional block grant for general expenditures (see Sect. 2) by this amount.
 
23
In reality, such a design might have a negative effect for the national government that does not exist in our simple model. In the model, every euro that the municipality spends on actual programs has the same indirect costs. Consequently, the municipality first chooses the euro of programs with the highest revenue (like the national government wants). However, if not every euro of programs has the same indirect costs (e.g., it requires little effort for the municipality to provide an additional, but not effective, educational program to a participant), then there is also an incentive for the municipality to choose a euro of programs with low indirect costs and gain the difference between the reimbursed indirect costs (x) and the real indirect costs.
 
24
Possibly, municipalities also spend money from their own resources on actual welfare-to-work programs. We do not observe these possible additional expenditures. However, for a municipality there seems no reason to use its own resources if it has savings or if it can still borrow. Table 1 shows that most municipalities have savings. Moreover, in Sect. 3 we show that in theory a municipality never wants to spend more than the grant. Therefore, we assume that municipalities do not spend money from their own resources on actual programs (compare this assumption with Moffitt 1984).
 
25
The annual amounts that a municipality spends, saves, and returns do not necessarily add up to the grant it receives in that year since it may have savings from the past and/or it may borrow from the national government. Hence, in a certain year, a municipality can spend more than the grant it receives. Moreover, a municipality can return more than the grant if its grant decreases compared to the previous year. In that case, it can save less than in the previous year and therefore it is possible that it returns both the new grant and a part of its savings from the past.
 
26
Most municipalities have some savings from 2003 (the final year of the previous system), but these are for most municipalities much lower than the maximum allowed amount of savings in 2004.
 
27
On the one hand, the total revenues might be higher since a municipality may also provide additional income support (e.g., local tax waivers, discounts on local services, and additional benefits for certain expenditures). We do not take this support into account since it is often for everyone with a low income and a person may still receive it after leaving social assistance. Moreover, the extent of this support is relatively small. On the other hand, the total revenues might be lower since a municipality with fewer than 40,000 inhabitants (of all ages, not only between 20 and 65) might receive in the future a lower unconditional block grant for social assistance benefits from the national government if people leave social assistance. Based on the annual outflow during 2004–2006, the national government can (partially) lower the grant after 3 years and based on the annual outflow during 2007–2008 after 2 years. The exact decrease depends on the number of inhabitants and the interplay with other rules. The national government does not lower the individual grant for a municipality with 40,000 or more inhabitants (see, e.g., Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment 2006; Toolsema and Allers 2014). For simplicity, we do not take this difference between municipalities into account. Non-monetary communal objectives, such as stimulating social inclusion or avoiding paternalism, may also impact the total revenues.
 
28
We assume that indirect costs are constant over time to limit the required number of computations. However, we allow indirect costs to vary over time in Sect. 4.4.1. The total costs do not include the costs of actual programs (see Footnote 24).
 
29
In addition to implementation costs, the estimated total indirect costs also include opportunity costs. Opportunity costs are the costs of curtailing other expenditures to pay for implementation costs.
 
30
For a municipality with a relatively short sample period, the assumption on the value of the savings in the final period is more important for determining its optimal decision.
 
31
We only interpret the average value of \(x_{i}^{e}\). Intuitively, we set the marginal costs equal to the marginal revenues for each municipality. However, the effectiveness of spending (\(\beta _{t}\)) is an average revenue over all municipalities. As a result, we underestimate revenues, and therefore indirect costs, for some municipalities, while we overestimate them for others. Therefore, we focus on the average indirect costs. Since the effectiveness of spending has to change over time to explain saving by municipalities, we cannot estimate the effectiveness of spending for individual municipalities (moreover, we have only 5 years).
 
32
If we only consider municipalities that have one optimal path that minimizes the expression in Eq. (6), then the estimated indirect costs are in general lower, but do not differ much. For example, in case of \(y=0.5\), \(\bar{x}^{e}\) equals 0.87 (this value is the average over 293 municipalities).
 
33
A back-of-the-envelope calculation shows that this estimate is in the same range as the part of the general unconditional block grant that the national government labels for the indirect costs of social assistance and welfare-to-work programs (1.5 billion euros in 2008, see Sect. 2). According to our estimation, in 2008, municipalities need in total about 1.4 billion euros to fully spend the grant of 1.6 billion euros (\(=0.9 \cdot 1.6\)).
 
34
The estimated \(x_{i,t}\) is robust to the existence of additional indirect fixed costs since these costs would not have an impact on the marginal profit of spending.
 
35
We use groups because we cannot estimate the effectiveness of spending (and thus indirect costs) for individual municipalities (see Footnote 31).
 
36
Although large municipalities spend on average 104 % of the grant in 2008, still many large municipalities do not fully use the grant in that year and 23 % even return money to the national government (see also Footnote 25).
 
37
The distribution of \(x_{i}^{e}\) shows that the set of possible values of \(x_{i}\) that we use in the main analysis is appropriate for both groups.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Allers, M. A. (2009). Rijksbegroting 2010: Gemeenten moeten bezuinigen, maar niet allemaal even veel. Tijdschrift voor Openbare Financiën, 41(5), 283–292. Allers, M. A. (2009). Rijksbegroting 2010: Gemeenten moeten bezuinigen, maar niet allemaal even veel. Tijdschrift voor Openbare Financiën, 41(5), 283–292.
Zurück zum Zitat Becker, S. O., Egger, P. H., & von Ehrlich, M. (2013). Absorptive capacity and the growth and investment effects of regional transfers: A regression discontinuity design with heterogeneous treatment effects. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 5(4), 29–77. Becker, S. O., Egger, P. H., & von Ehrlich, M. (2013). Absorptive capacity and the growth and investment effects of regional transfers: A regression discontinuity design with heterogeneous treatment effects. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 5(4), 29–77.
Zurück zum Zitat Bergvall, D., Charbit, C., Kraan, D.-J., & Merk, O. (2006). Intergovernmental transfers and decentralised public spending. OECD Journal on Budgeting, 5(4), 111–158.CrossRef Bergvall, D., Charbit, C., Kraan, D.-J., & Merk, O. (2006). Intergovernmental transfers and decentralised public spending. OECD Journal on Budgeting, 5(4), 111–158.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berkhout, B., & Mallee, L. (2008). Laat het werkbudget werken voor het zittend bestand. Sociaal Bestek, 70(7–8), 24–28. Berkhout, B., & Mallee, L. (2008). Laat het werkbudget werken voor het zittend bestand. Sociaal Bestek, 70(7–8), 24–28.
Zurück zum Zitat Bickers, K. N., & Stein, R. M. (2004). Interlocal cooperation and the distribution of federal grant awards. Journal of Politics, 66(3), 800–822.CrossRef Bickers, K. N., & Stein, R. M. (2004). Interlocal cooperation and the distribution of federal grant awards. Journal of Politics, 66(3), 800–822.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bierings, H., & Michiels, J. (2010). Herinstroom in werkloosheids- of bijstandsuitkering. CBS Sociaal-economische Trends, 2010(1), 43–50. Bierings, H., & Michiels, J. (2010). Herinstroom in werkloosheids- of bijstandsuitkering. CBS Sociaal-economische Trends, 2010(1), 43–50.
Zurück zum Zitat Boadway, R., & Shah, A. (Eds.). (2007). Intergovernmental fiscal transfers. Principles and practice. Washington DC: World Bank. Boadway, R., & Shah, A. (Eds.). (2007). Intergovernmental fiscal transfers. Principles and practice. Washington DC: World Bank.
Zurück zum Zitat Brennan, G., & Pincus, J. (1990). An implicit contract theory of intergovernmental grants. Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 20(4), 129–144. Brennan, G., & Pincus, J. (1990). An implicit contract theory of intergovernmental grants. Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 20(4), 129–144.
Zurück zum Zitat Card, D., Kluve, J., & Weber, A. (2010). Active labour market policy evaluations: A meta-analysis. Economic Journal, 120(548), F452–F477.CrossRef Card, D., Kluve, J., & Weber, A. (2010). Active labour market policy evaluations: A meta-analysis. Economic Journal, 120(548), F452–F477.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cashel-Cordo, P., & Craig, S. G. (1990). The public sector impact of international resource transfers. Journal of Development Economics, 32(1), 17–42.CrossRef Cashel-Cordo, P., & Craig, S. G. (1990). The public sector impact of international resource transfers. Journal of Development Economics, 32(1), 17–42.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cebeon. (2010). Uitvoeringskosten gemeenten en UWV. Cebeon. (2010). Uitvoeringskosten gemeenten en UWV.
Zurück zum Zitat Chernick, H. A. (1979). An economic model of the distribution of project grants. In P. Mieszkowski & W. H. Oakland (Eds.), Fiscal federalism and grants-in-aid (pp. 81–103). Washington DC: Urban Institute. Chernick, H. A. (1979). An economic model of the distribution of project grants. In P. Mieszkowski & W. H. Oakland (Eds.), Fiscal federalism and grants-in-aid (pp. 81–103). Washington DC: Urban Institute.
Zurück zum Zitat Chernick, H. A. (1981). Price discrimination and federal project grants. Public Finance Quarterly, 9(4), 371–394.CrossRef Chernick, H. A. (1981). Price discrimination and federal project grants. Public Finance Quarterly, 9(4), 371–394.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chubb, J. E. (1985). The political economy of federalism. American Political Science Review, 79(4), 994–1015.CrossRef Chubb, J. E. (1985). The political economy of federalism. American Political Science Review, 79(4), 994–1015.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Collins, B. K., & Gerber, B. J. (2006). Redistributive policy and devolution: Is state administration a road block (grant) to equitable access to federal funds? Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 16(4), 613–632.CrossRef Collins, B. K., & Gerber, B. J. (2006). Redistributive policy and devolution: Is state administration a road block (grant) to equitable access to federal funds? Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 16(4), 613–632.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Collins, B. K., & Gerber, B. J. (2008). Taken for granted? Managing for social equity in grant programs. Public Administration Review, 68(6), 1128–1141.CrossRef Collins, B. K., & Gerber, B. J. (2008). Taken for granted? Managing for social equity in grant programs. Public Administration Review, 68(6), 1128–1141.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Court of Auditors. (2004). Report on activities financed from the budget, together with the institutions’ replies. Official Journal of the European Union, 47(C293/01), 3–313. Court of Auditors. (2004). Report on activities financed from the budget, together with the institutions’ replies. Official Journal of the European Union, 47(C293/01), 3–313.
Zurück zum Zitat Court of Auditors. (2005). Annual report on the implementation of the budget, together with the institutions’ replies. Official Journal of the European Union, 48(C301/01), 3–247. Court of Auditors. (2005). Annual report on the implementation of the budget, together with the institutions’ replies. Official Journal of the European Union, 48(C301/01), 3–247.
Zurück zum Zitat CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis. (2007). De maatschappelijke kosten en baten van re-integratie. CPB Notitie. CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis. (2007). De maatschappelijke kosten en baten van re-integratie. CPB Notitie.
Zurück zum Zitat Craw, M. (2010). Deciding to provide: Local decisions on providing social welfare. American Journal of Political Science, 54(4), 906–920.CrossRef Craw, M. (2010). Deciding to provide: Local decisions on providing social welfare. American Journal of Political Science, 54(4), 906–920.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat De Mooij, A. M., & Houtkoop, W. A. (2005). Scholing op afspraak. Sectorale scholingsafspraken en stand van zaken O&O-fondsen 2004. Max Goote Kenniscentrum. De Mooij, A. M., & Houtkoop, W. A. (2005). Scholing op afspraak. Sectorale scholingsafspraken en stand van zaken O&O-fondsen 2004. Max Goote Kenniscentrum.
Zurück zum Zitat Divosa. (2006). Aan de slag met het werkdeel. Achtergronden van de besteding van het werkdeel. Divosa. (2006). Aan de slag met het werkdeel. Achtergronden van de besteding van het werkdeel.
Zurück zum Zitat Divosa. (2009). Meer dan ooit. Sociale diensten en participatiebevordering. Divosa Monitor 2009. Divosa. (2009). Meer dan ooit. Sociale diensten en participatiebevordering. Divosa Monitor 2009.
Zurück zum Zitat Doan, A. E., & McFarlane, D. R. (2012). Saying no to abstinence-only education: An analysis of state decision-making. Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 42(4), 613–635.CrossRef Doan, A. E., & McFarlane, D. R. (2012). Saying no to abstinence-only education: An analysis of state decision-making. Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 42(4), 613–635.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Estermann, T., & Pruvot, E. B. (2011). Financially sustainable universities II. European universities diversifying income streams. European University Association. Estermann, T., & Pruvot, E. B. (2011). Financially sustainable universities II. European universities diversifying income streams. European University Association.
Zurück zum Zitat European Commission. (2011a). Budget implementation as at end-2010. Information Note. European Commission. (2011a). Budget implementation as at end-2010. Information Note.
Zurück zum Zitat European Commission. (2011b). Recommendation for a council recommendation on the national reform programme 2011 of Italy and delivering a council opinion on the updated stability programme of Italy, 2011–2014. SEC(2011) 810 Final. European Commission. (2011b). Recommendation for a council recommendation on the national reform programme 2011 of Italy and delivering a council opinion on the updated stability programme of Italy, 2011–2014. SEC(2011) 810 Final.
Zurück zum Zitat Evans, W. N., & Owens, E. G. (2007). COPS and crime. Journal of Public Economics, 91(1–2), 181–201.CrossRef Evans, W. N., & Owens, E. G. (2007). COPS and crime. Journal of Public Economics, 91(1–2), 181–201.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Foster, E. (1981). Competitively awarded government grants. Journal of Public Economics, 15(1), 105–111.CrossRef Foster, E. (1981). Competitively awarded government grants. Journal of Public Economics, 15(1), 105–111.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goldman, C. A., Williams, T., Adamson, D. M., & Rosenblatt, K. (2000). Paying for university research facilities and administration. Santa Monica: RAND. Goldman, C. A., Williams, T., Adamson, D. M., & Rosenblatt, K. (2000). Paying for university research facilities and administration. Santa Monica: RAND.
Zurück zum Zitat Gordon, N. (2004). Do federal grants boost school spending? Evidence from Title I. Journal of Public Economics, 88(9–10), 1771–1792.CrossRef Gordon, N. (2004). Do federal grants boost school spending? Evidence from Title I. Journal of Public Economics, 88(9–10), 1771–1792.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Government of Canada. (2010). Indirect costs program. Progress Report for April 1, 2009 to March 31, 2010. Government of Canada. (2010). Indirect costs program. Progress Report for April 1, 2009 to March 31, 2010.
Zurück zum Zitat Hall, J. L. (2008a). Assessing local capacity for federal grant-getting. American Review of Public Administration, 38(4), 463–479.CrossRef Hall, J. L. (2008a). Assessing local capacity for federal grant-getting. American Review of Public Administration, 38(4), 463–479.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hall, J. L. (2008b). The forgotten regional organizations: Creating capacity for economic development. Public Administration Review, 68(1), 110–125.CrossRef Hall, J. L. (2008b). The forgotten regional organizations: Creating capacity for economic development. Public Administration Review, 68(1), 110–125.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hickey, A. (2001). Extent of provincial underspending of HIV/AIDS conditional grants. Idasa Budget Brief No. 85. Hickey, A. (2001). Extent of provincial underspending of HIV/AIDS conditional grants. Idasa Budget Brief No. 85.
Zurück zum Zitat Hickey, A. (2002). HIV/AIDS spending policy and intergovernmental fiscal relations. South African Journal of Economics, 70(7), 597–605.CrossRef Hickey, A. (2002). HIV/AIDS spending policy and intergovernmental fiscal relations. South African Journal of Economics, 70(7), 597–605.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hickey, A., & Ndlovu, N. (2005). Budgeting for HIV/AIDS in South Africa: An analysis of provincial health budgets. South African Journal of Economics, 73(S1), 627–640.CrossRef Hickey, A., & Ndlovu, N. (2005). Budgeting for HIV/AIDS in South Africa: An analysis of provincial health budgets. South African Journal of Economics, 73(S1), 627–640.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Huber, B., & Runkel, M. (2006). Optimal design of intergovernmental grants under asymmetric information. International Tax and Public Finance, 13(1), 25–41.CrossRef Huber, B., & Runkel, M. (2006). Optimal design of intergovernmental grants under asymmetric information. International Tax and Public Finance, 13(1), 25–41.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Inspectie der Rijksfinanciën. (2010). Op afstand van de arbeidsmarkt. Rapport brede heroverwegingen. Inspectie der Rijksfinanciën. (2010). Op afstand van de arbeidsmarkt. Rapport brede heroverwegingen.
Zurück zum Zitat Inspectie Werk en Inkomen. (2006). Verkennende studie naar terugval in WW- en WWB-uitkering. Inspectie Werk en Inkomen. (2006). Verkennende studie naar terugval in WW- en WWB-uitkering.
Zurück zum Zitat Kluve, J. (2010). The effectiveness of European active labor market programs. Labour Economics, 17(6), 904–918.CrossRef Kluve, J. (2010). The effectiveness of European active labor market programs. Labour Economics, 17(6), 904–918.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Knight, B. (2002). Endogenous federal grants and crowd-out of state government spending: Theory and evidence from the federal highway aid program. American Economic Review, 92(1), 71–92.CrossRef Knight, B. (2002). Endogenous federal grants and crowd-out of state government spending: Theory and evidence from the federal highway aid program. American Economic Review, 92(1), 71–92.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kok, L., Hollanders, D., & Hop, J. P. (2006). Kosten en baten van reïntegratie. SEO Rapport No. 928. Kok, L., Hollanders, D., & Hop, J. P. (2006). Kosten en baten van reïntegratie. SEO Rapport No. 928.
Zurück zum Zitat Koning, P. (2009). Contracting welfare-to-work services: Use and usefulness. CPB Discussion Paper No. 135. Koning, P. (2009). Contracting welfare-to-work services: Use and usefulness. CPB Discussion Paper No. 135.
Zurück zum Zitat Kuhry, B., & Jonker, J.-J. J. (2007). Maten voor gemeenten 2007. Een analyse van de prestaties van de lokale overheid. The Hague: SCP. Kuhry, B., & Jonker, J.-J. J. (2007). Maten voor gemeenten 2007. Een analyse van de prestaties van de lokale overheid. The Hague: SCP.
Zurück zum Zitat Lindsay, C., Osborne, S. P., & Bond, S. (2014). The ‘New Public Governance’ and employability services in an era of crisis: Challenges for third sector organizations in Scotland. Public Administration, 92(1), 192–207.CrossRef Lindsay, C., Osborne, S. P., & Bond, S. (2014). The ‘New Public Governance’ and employability services in an era of crisis: Challenges for third sector organizations in Scotland. Public Administration, 92(1), 192–207.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Marzinotto, B. (2011). A European fund for economic revival in crisis countries. Bruegel Policy Contribution No. 1. Marzinotto, B. (2011). A European fund for economic revival in crisis countries. Bruegel Policy Contribution No. 1.
Zurück zum Zitat May, R. M., & Sarson, S. C. (1999). Revealing the hidden costs of research. Nature, 398(6727), 457–459.CrossRef May, R. M., & Sarson, S. C. (1999). Revealing the hidden costs of research. Nature, 398(6727), 457–459.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McGuire, M. C. (1978). A method for estimating the effect of a subsidy on the receiver’s resource constraint: With an application to U.S. local governments 1964–1971. Journal of Public Economics, 10(1), 25–44.CrossRef McGuire, M. C. (1978). A method for estimating the effect of a subsidy on the receiver’s resource constraint: With an application to U.S. local governments 1964–1971. Journal of Public Economics, 10(1), 25–44.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Milio, S. (2007). Can administrative capacity explain differences in regional performances? Evidence from structural funds implementation in southern Italy. Regional Studies, 41(4), 429–442.CrossRef Milio, S. (2007). Can administrative capacity explain differences in regional performances? Evidence from structural funds implementation in southern Italy. Regional Studies, 41(4), 429–442.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment. (2006). Besluit WWB 2007. Staatsblad van het Koninkrijk der Nederlanden, 2006(379), 1–27. Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment. (2006). Besluit WWB 2007. Staatsblad van het Koninkrijk der Nederlanden, 2006(379), 1–27.
Zurück zum Zitat Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment. (2008). Beleidsdoorlichting re-integratie. Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment. (2008). Beleidsdoorlichting re-integratie.
Zurück zum Zitat Moffitt, R. A. (1984). The effects of grants-in-aid on state and local expenditures. The case of AFDC. Journal of Public Economics, 23(3), 279–305.CrossRef Moffitt, R. A. (1984). The effects of grants-in-aid on state and local expenditures. The case of AFDC. Journal of Public Economics, 23(3), 279–305.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Oates, W. E. (1999). An essay on fiscal federalism. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(3), 1120–1149.CrossRef Oates, W. E. (1999). An essay on fiscal federalism. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(3), 1120–1149.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Okten, C., & Weisbrod, B. A. (2000). Determinants of donations in private nonprofit markets. Journal of Public Economics, 75(2), 255–272.CrossRef Okten, C., & Weisbrod, B. A. (2000). Determinants of donations in private nonprofit markets. Journal of Public Economics, 75(2), 255–272.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Reinhardt, G. Y. (2006). Shortcuts and signals: An analysis of the micro-level determinants of aid allocation, with case study evidence from Brazil. Review of Development Economics, 10(2), 297–312.CrossRef Reinhardt, G. Y. (2006). Shortcuts and signals: An analysis of the micro-level determinants of aid allocation, with case study evidence from Brazil. Review of Development Economics, 10(2), 297–312.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rich, M. J. (1989). Distributive politics and the allocation of federal grants. American Political Science Review, 83(1), 193–213.CrossRef Rich, M. J. (1989). Distributive politics and the allocation of federal grants. American Political Science Review, 83(1), 193–213.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schneider, M., & Ji, B. M. (1990). The political economy of intergovernmental grant seeking: Targeting and suburbs, 1977 and 1982. American Journal of Political Science, 34(2), 408–420.CrossRef Schneider, M., & Ji, B. M. (1990). The political economy of intergovernmental grant seeking: Targeting and suburbs, 1977 and 1982. American Journal of Political Science, 34(2), 408–420.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Silva, E. C. D. (2015). Efficient earmarking under decentralized fiscal commitments. International Tax and Public Finance, 22(4), 683–701.CrossRef Silva, E. C. D. (2015). Efficient earmarking under decentralized fiscal commitments. International Tax and Public Finance, 22(4), 683–701.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Singhal, M. (2008). Special interest groups and the allocation of public funds. Journal of Public Economics, 92(3–4), 548–564.CrossRef Singhal, M. (2008). Special interest groups and the allocation of public funds. Journal of Public Economics, 92(3–4), 548–564.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Smart, M., & Bird, R. (2009). Earmarked grants and accountability in government. Working Paper. Smart, M., & Bird, R. (2009). Earmarked grants and accountability in government. Working Paper.
Zurück zum Zitat Stein, R. M. (1979). Federal categorical aid: Equalization and the application process. Western Political Quarterly, 32(4), 396–408.CrossRef Stein, R. M. (1979). Federal categorical aid: Equalization and the application process. Western Political Quarterly, 32(4), 396–408.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stein, R. M. (1981). The allocation of federal aid monies: The synthesis of demand-side and supply-side explanations. American Political Science Review, 75(2), 334–343.CrossRef Stein, R. M. (1981). The allocation of federal aid monies: The synthesis of demand-side and supply-side explanations. American Political Science Review, 75(2), 334–343.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stein, R. M. (1984). Municipal public employment: An examination of intergovernmental influences. American Journal of Political Science, 28(4), 636–653.CrossRef Stein, R. M. (1984). Municipal public employment: An examination of intergovernmental influences. American Journal of Political Science, 28(4), 636–653.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Toolsema, L. A., & Allers, M. A. (2014). Welfare financing: Grant allocation and efficiency. De Economist, 162(2), 147–166.CrossRef Toolsema, L. A., & Allers, M. A. (2014). Welfare financing: Grant allocation and efficiency. De Economist, 162(2), 147–166.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Van Geuns, R. C., Mallee, L., Soethout, J. E., van Waveren, B. C., & Wissink, C. (2006). Onderbenutting W-deel. Regioplan Publicatie No. 1459. Van Geuns, R. C., Mallee, L., Soethout, J. E., van Waveren, B. C., & Wissink, C. (2006). Onderbenutting W-deel. Regioplan Publicatie No. 1459.
Zurück zum Zitat Van Ours, J. C. (2004). The locking-in effect of subsidized jobs. Journal of Comparative Economics, 32(1), 37–55. Van Ours, J. C. (2004). The locking-in effect of subsidized jobs. Journal of Comparative Economics, 32(1), 37–55.
Zurück zum Zitat Verheijen, T. (2007). Administrative capacity in the new EU member states. The limits of innovation? World Bank Working Paper No. 115. Verheijen, T. (2007). Administrative capacity in the new EU member states. The limits of innovation? World Bank Working Paper No. 115.
Zurück zum Zitat Volden, C. (2007). Intergovernmental grants: A formal model of interrelated national and subnational political decisions. Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 37(2), 209–243.CrossRef Volden, C. (2007). Intergovernmental grants: A formal model of interrelated national and subnational political decisions. Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 37(2), 209–243.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Waterreus, I. M. (2002). O&O-fondsen op herhaling. Stand van zaken scholingsfondsen 2002. Max Goote Kenniscentrum. Waterreus, I. M. (2002). O&O-fondsen op herhaling. Stand van zaken scholingsfondsen 2002. Max Goote Kenniscentrum.
Zurück zum Zitat Wunsch, C. (2013). Optimal use of labor market policies: The role of job search assistance. Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(3), 1030–1045.CrossRef Wunsch, C. (2013). Optimal use of labor market policies: The role of job search assistance. Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(3), 1030–1045.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Zampelli, E. M. (1986). Resource fungibility, the flypaper effect, and the expenditure impact of grants-in-aid. Review of Economics and Statistics, 68(1), 33–40.CrossRef Zampelli, E. M. (1986). Resource fungibility, the flypaper effect, and the expenditure impact of grants-in-aid. Review of Economics and Statistics, 68(1), 33–40.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Why not fully spend a conditional block grant?
verfasst von
Riemer P. Faber
Pierre Koning
Publikationsdatum
20.06.2016
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
International Tax and Public Finance / Ausgabe 1/2017
Print ISSN: 0927-5940
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-6970
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-016-9397-0

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1/2017

International Tax and Public Finance 1/2017 Zur Ausgabe